Consumer-Friendly and Environmentally-Sound Electricity

Similar documents
Marginal Cost Electricity Pricing and Greenhouse Gas Reduc7ons By Lee S. Friedman

How to Submit Your Question

Rate Design: Basics and What s Possible

MA Perspectives on Building Priorities for Climate and Energy Policy

The Future of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading in North America

Indiana Energy Status

Risk Mitigation Benefits of Energy Efficiency

PUBLIC POWER = + + LOCAL CONTROL LOW RATES HIGH RELIABILITY

The Future of Coal-fired Generation: Challenging the EPA

Transportation Worker Identification Credential (TWIC) Program. American Association of Port Authorities 2013 Security Seminar July 17, 2013

Indiana Energy Landscape

Update on Energy Efficiency Opportunities in the Commonwealth

Developing a Framework for Integrated Energy Network Planning

A Comparison of In-Service Statistical Test Programs

QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR SHRP2 R06C TECHNOLOGIES

Building Energy Codes Update NGA Energy Working Group

Sarah Doll, Safer States BizNGO December 2014

Educating and Training Tomorrow s Workforce

Analysis of NBI Data for California Bridges

Discussion on the Threat of Electrification to Residential Natural Gas Demand

2011 State Average Electricity Prices (cents/kwh)

Sierra Club National Survey on Coal, Climate and Carbon Pollution Key Findings

The Changing Landscape and Business Case for Water Loss Control

Laws are like. better not to see. made.

IPNI North American Soil Test Summaries. Tom Jensen, Director in North America Program Cell:

Destination for Education? Your Facility. Bring Us to You!

Non-Ambulatory Cattle and Calves

Farm Computer Usage and Ownership

FHWA SHRP2 Overview & National Perspective. Steve Cooper SHRP2 Renewal Pavement Engineer

Net metering and rate reforms for distributed solar

OF PIPEDREAMS AND PIPELINES

Energy and Water: Emerging Issues and Challenges. Mike Hightower Water for Energy Project Lead Sandia National Laboratories

HOW CAN WE MAKE MORE JOBS GOOD JOBS?

The Smart Grid Lunch and Learn

Renewable Energy Buyers Alliance (REBA): Accelerating GHG reductions through a buyer-led movement

REGIONAL ENERGY BASELINES AND MEASUREMENT AND VERIFICATION PROTOCOLS

Infrared Technology: Its Application and Benefit

CONTEXT AROUND RGGI DISCUSSIONS

Goal Setting: Nutrient Pollution Standards and Technology. October 29, Ephraim King OST

State of the Network. EN2014 February 25, 2014

Mary. E. Torrence DVM, Ph.D., DACVPM National Program Leader, Food Safety

Watershed Plan Implementation in Oklahoma: What We Do and What We ve Learned

Agricultural Land Values

EPA Carbon Regulations Stakeholder Meeting

Bridge Management Questionnaire Report

The Component Model of Infrastructure (CMI): An Infrastructure Model for Evaluating Tobacco Control Programs

Construction & Materials Outlook. March 9, 2009 Ken Simonson, Chief Economist AGC of America USA

Labor Market Equilibrium

Farms and Land in Farms

Today s Propane. National Propane Gas Association

Cost-effectiveness Tests Current Practice

Voluntary Renewable Energy Markets 101. Noah Bucon Senior Analyst, Policy & Certification Programs Center for Resource Solutions

US Energy What's next... and beyond? September 2013

NUCLEAR BY THE NUMBERS A PRIL

U.S. Voluntary Approaches to Reduce Emissions of Greenhouse Gases

Special Update: Salary Budget Survey

Milk Production, Disposition, and Income

CPAs Making Sense of a Changing and Complex World. October 24, 2011 NASBA 104 th Annual Meeting Gregory J. Anton, CPA AICPA Chairman

Energy Efficiency as a Resource Time for Action

ISO s Data Management Roadmap. October 13, 2015

Loyalty Discounts and Pharmaceutical Competition

The Bee Informed Partnership Management Survey Results (2011) Respondent Profile. BeeInformed.org

Bank of the Sierra stays in the black with the help of Eaton UPS and service plan

Potential Damage from Asian Longhorned Beetle

Webinar: PG&E and Solar

U.S. Wind Industry Fourth Quarter 2014 U.S. Wind Industry First Quarter 2016 Market Report Market Report

Land Values and Cash Rents: 2008 Summary

NCHRP 20 68A U.S. Domestic Scan Program. Domestic Scan 13 03

Tack Coat Best Practices

Capacity of Refrigerated Warehouses

Eaton CSE never misses a beat for Charter Communications uptime requirements

United States Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC)

A New Market for Energy Regulation: Advancing the Clean Energy Revolution

Manufactured Housing In the United States

Assessing the Potential Economic and Distributional Impacts of a Tighter Ozone NAAQS

Iowa Farm Outlook. June 2015 Ames, Iowa Econ. Info Regional Hay-Pasture Situation and Outlook. Percent of National All Hay Stocks

Sierra Club National Survey on Coal, Climate and Carbon Pollution Key Findings

Presidential Commission on Election Administration & Voter Registration. Future of California Elections Los Angeles, CA February 25,2016

FHWA Cooperative Agreement Subtask. Longitudinal Joints Intelligent Compaction

IDEM Update. ACEC Indiana Environmental Business and Funding Conference September 15, 2016 The Willows, Indianapolis

CAPITAL SPENDING SURVEY MACHINE TOOLS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY PRESENTED ANNUALLY BY.

Assessment of Achievable Potential from Energy Efficiency and Demand Response Programs in the U.S. ( ) Executive Summary

ERP States Produce Results

Issues and Challenges for Transportation Fuels. Mike Hightower Sandia National Laboratories

Voluntary & Compliance Markets. Renewable Energy Markets 2010

Topics. Examination of Time Lags in Automatic Refills Kolmogorov Smirnov Statistical Test

Election Day Command Centers: The Vortex 2016 STATE CERTIFICATION TESTING OF VOTING SYSTEMS NATIONAL CONFERENCE MIT JUNE 20, 2016

Advanced Fuel Cycles?

Dallas Integrated Corridor Management

Regional REC and RPS Best Practices. Jennifer Alvarado, Exec. Dir. Great Lakes Renewable Energy Association

Today s Energy Landscape:

SALARY SNAPSHOT: HIM PROFESSIONALS IN 2016

Adding Thermal Energy to State Renewable Energy Standards: Opportunity, Status, and Challenges

EPOXY INTEREST GROUP EPOXY-COATED REINFORCING STEEL IN PARKING GARAGES

The Role of the Regulator in the Promotion and Development of Renewable Energy

Organic Agriculture Funding & Priorities in the U.S.

LNG Industry Update Erik Neandross

NMCI Services and Delivery. June 17, 2003 Bill Richard EDS NMCI Enterprise Client Executive

1. Audited Media Platforms. Print Publication: Average Net Circulation: 15,536 (Print Edition)

Future of the US Federal Highway Program

Transcription:

Consumer-Friendly and Environmentally-Sound Electricity Rates for the Twenty-First Century By Lee S. Friedman Goldman School of Public Policy 2607 Hearst Avenue University of California, Berkeley Berkeley, CA 94720-7320 lfried@berkeley.edu Paper available for download now on my personal homepage at the Goldman School: http://gsppi.berkeley.edu/faculty/lfriedman/lee-s-friedman This paper builds on Lee S. Friedman, "The Importance of Marginal Cost Electricity Pricing to the Success of Greenhouse Gas Reduction Programs" Energy Policy, 39, No. 11, November 2011, pp. 7347-7360.

Overview The Importance of Marginal Cost Electricity Pricing (off-peak emphasis, e.g. vehicle electrification) Time-varying residential electricity rates have been unpopular Are there efficient, fair and practical time-varying rate designs that would be popular (suitable for widespread use, like as a default plan)? Designs that I call HOOP (Household On and Off Peak) plans are efficient and have the potential to be fair and practical. HOOP plans (1) utilize marginal-cost based time-varying rates, and (2) assign fixed infrastructure charges that vary by customer group in accordance with commonly used equity principles I test these plans on a statewide representative sample of 331 California residences for which usage data is available every 15 minutes for one year. Simple HOOP plans applied to the statewide sample can result in bills that replicate reasonably closely the bills from the far more complex rate plans of the three independent utilities that serve California Conclusion: It seems promising that utilities and utility commissions can utilize HOOP designs to create default and optional time-varying rate plans with widespread acceptance

Electricity Rates are 2x-6x higher than Off-peak Marginal Costs in the U.S. 24.000 22.000 20.000 18.000 16.000 14.000 12.000 10.000 8.000 6.000 4.000 2.000 0.000 MI MN ND OH SD WI AR KS LA MS MO NE NM OK CA IA MT AZ CO ID NV OR UT WA TX AL GA SC ME WY NH VT CT DE IL IN KY MD NJ NC PA TN VA DC WV MA RI AK HI NY FL Off-peak MC (April-June 2009) Average Residential Price (June 2009) U.S. average= 2.8 U.S. average= 11.9

The Unpopularity of Time-Varying Rates Time-Varying Rates became of substantial interest during 1970s following OPEC oil embargo concern for energy security and energy conservation. U.S. DOE sponsored 15 residential TOU projects starting with Vermont 1975 Attention was on how responsive residences would be, not how attractive the plans would be. Used volunteers, not representative of residential populations Many utilities began and have continued to offer optional time-varying programs Federal Energy Regulatory Commission survey 2010: Only 1% of U.S. Residential population on time-varying rates. Renewed interest among policy-makers with concerns about GHGs and energy security. Technological advance makes demand responsiveness much easier--smart grid, smart meters, smart appliances (e.g. automatically work less hard during the peak). CT and CA initiated efforts to make time-varying rates either mandatory (CT) or the default rate (CA). But some consumer groups strenuously resist efforts, fear high bills, worry about effects on vulnerable populations, the less educated. Both CA & CT PUCs have had to delay their attempted transitions to time-varying rates. The open question: is it possible to design time-varying rates that are practical, fair and efficient for substantial portions of the residential population?

California sample Statewide Pricing Pilot 2003-04 Designed to test critical peak pricing Collected 16 month of continuous usage data measured in 15 minute increments. Control group designed to be representative of state as whole (stratified sample). N=331 Mean monthly kwh usage = 543.29, bill = $71.72 Mean monthly peak usage (2-7PM) = 95.20 (17.5%), off-peak usage 448.09 (82.5%)

Figure 2: The System Load is Declining before the Residential Load has Reached its Peak 7.00 California System & Residential Load Profiles 6.00 5.00 Percent of 4.00 Daily Load 3.00 System Load Profile (July 2009) Residential Load Profile (July 2003) 2.00 1.00 0.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 101112131415161718192021222324 Hour of the Day

Table 3: No Law of One Price in Existing California Electric Rates (price incentives at identical usage vary by more than 100% because of complex rate structures) Monthly Usage (kwh) Baseline Quantity Classification Bill Marginal Price per kwh 700 714 CARE, All-electric, $58.21 $.092 Bakersfield 700 561 CARE, Basic, Bakersfield $59.95 $.106 700 312 CARE, All-electric, $63.05 $.106 Santa Cruz 700 219 CARE, Basic, $64.21 $.106 northeast CA 700 714 All-electric, $79.31 $.126 Bakersfield 700 561 Basic, Bakersfield $81.48 $.143 700 312 All-electric, Santa $96.94 $.210 Cruz 700 219 Basic, northeast CA $107.43 $.210

Figure 3: Despite Complex Rate Variations across Customers, Annual Usage Predicts Annual Bills 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 0 10000 20000 30000 40000 annual_usage PG&E_annual_bill_difference SCE_annual_bill_difference SDG&E_annual_bill_difference Fitted values Annual Bill = -184.7551 +.1654821*Annual Usage R 2 =.98 (33.26) (.005)

Table 4: HOOP Fixed Fees (revenue-neutral compared to status quo, average annual fixed fee of $249.12) Group (Annual kwh) Proportional Fixed Fees (Annual Non- CARE) Proportional Fixed Fees (Annual CARE)* Status Quo Equity Fees (Annual Non- CARE) Status Quo Equity Fees (Annual CARE)* 0-2000 62.85-2.78 38.10 20.83 2000-4000 133.09-5.88 96.46-5.40 4000-6000 209.70-9.27 152.84-28.60 6000-8000 294.19-13.01 263.72-33.67 8000-10,000 385.85-17.06 358.78 81.12 10,000-12,000 469.57-20.76 533.35-15.95 12,000-14,000 557.87-24.67 677.82 8.32 14,000-16,000 647.13-28.61 965.57 259.81 16,000-18,000 732.24-32.37 1149.97 12.74 18,000-20,000 810.28 -------- 1202.96 ------- * Based on small CARE sample size (n=54, 16.3% of sample, 14.9% of population), may not be representative. Status quo equity fees can be skewed because of very few CARE residences in a group.

TOU 2-7PM Peak Plan ($.30/kWh peak, $.05/kWh off-peak) Applied to Representative California Residential Population Regressive TOU27 Bill Differences with Standard Two-Part Tariff Fixed Fee $249.12 annually or $20.76 monthly (Bill difference is positive if TOU27 Bill > Original Bill) -1000 0 1000 Losers Gainers -3000-2000 Average Bill $861/year 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 annual_calendar_bill annual_bill_difference Fitted values Difference = 366.0315 -.4252*Bill R 2 =.86 (10.49) (.01)

Figure 6: Graph of Absolute Bill Differences caused by Proportional Fee -1000-500 0 500 Losers Gainers Average Bill $861/year 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 annual_calendar_bill PG&E_annual_bill_difference SCE_annual_bill_difference SDG&E_annual_bill_difference Fitted values Y = 102.1494 -.1186939 X R 2 =.32 (10.40) (.01)

TOU 2-7PM Peak Plan ($.30/kWh peak, $.05/kWh off-peak) Applied to Representative California Residential Population The Status Quo Equity Rule is neutral with respect to small and large users in terms of bill differences caused by a switch to a TOU27 plan -500 0 500 Losers Gainers Average Bill $861/year 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 annual_calendar_bill PG&E_annual_bill_difference SCE_annual_bill_difference SDG&E_annual_bill_difference Fitted values Difference = 14.5227 -.0159069Bill R 2 =.01 (9.42) (.01)

Table 3: Annual Bill Differences Caused by Alternative HOOP Rate Designs are Reasonably Small Bill Difference =Time-Varying Bill Time-Invariant Bill (Negative Numbers Gainers, Positive Numbers Losers) Percentile Uniform Fixed Fee HOOP Proportional Fixed Fee Percent Bill Change at Decile Median HOOP Status Quo Equity Fee Percent Bill Change at Decile Median 0-10 -748.17-349.43-16.99-214.85-13.93 10-20 -215.37-78.77-7.91-67.61-8.94 20-30 -64.27-18.29-2.51-37.11-6.47 30-40 13.90 6.11 1.45-16.31-3.60 40-50 75.33 23.66 5.73-2.86 -.14 50-60 107.98 39.09 8.91 10.37 2.77 60-70 142.27 52.01 9.98 26.49 4.33 70-80 175.72 70.82 12.26 45.46 7.91 80-90 216.82 93.78 11.47 78.19 9.15 90-95 264.84 131.86 17.03 133.42 11.07 95-99 311.32 173.80 17.87 209.76 16.73 99-100 377.03 249.12 15.98 353.59 19.30

Other issues in the design of HOOP rates How dynamic? Illustrations are for simple peak and off-peak plans, but same logic applies to a more dynamic plan like critical peak pricing a version that might be preferable as the default option. How historical should the baseline be for assigning individuals to groups? Three-year moving average good for avoiding using an unusual weather year as a baseline. How complex should the criteria be for group assignments, apart from usage levels? California utilities divide their service territories into climate zones (SCE has 9, PG&E 10, SDG&E 4) and baseline quantities are set separately for each zone. If this categorization is an accepted equity norm, then HOOP fee structures should also be made specific to each climate zone. (Utilities can do this easily, sample size of this study is too small to simulate this) How do these apply in restructured areas with retail electricity competition? Needs further investigation, but restructured areas divide charges into a nonbypassable component used to collect non-energy charges, and then competitively set energy charges. The HOOP infrastructure charges would apply to the nonbypassable charge, and then the energy charges would be time-varying but competitively set. The standard offer should be one with time-varying rates.

Conclusions Workable, fair and efficient time-varying residential rates need to replace outmoded time-invariant rates. Huge disconnect between off-peak rates and off-peak marginal costs wrongly discourages vehicle electrification The smart grid makes demand responsiveness much easier and more automated, but need right price signals Residences have avoided time-varying rates in part due to fear of high bills. HOOP plans utilize marginal-cost based time-varying rates and a set of infrastructure fees designed to be equitable across a broad population. Using a representative sample of California residences, I find that simple statewide HOOP designs are able to replicate reasonably closely the bills from the time-invariant system. The utilities can tailor these to each climate zone to get a much closer fit. can be neutral in the sense of not systematically favoring either low or high usage customers can also be neutral by income level, illustrated here by neutrality with respect to CARE (low-income) customers and non-care customers. HOOP designs are promising as a method for making rates that are attractive to large numbers of customers address important environmental issues by bringing off-peak rates down to marginal costs take advantage of the smartening grid by providing the right signals for demand responsiveness