Lecture 4: Will profits in reality be higher or lower than under Cournot? Tom Holden

Similar documents
Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

Oligopoly Theory (11) Collusion

Collusion and Cartels

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

Industrial Organization ( st term)

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Imperfect Competition

Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy. Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Price-Fixing and. Repeated Games. Collusion and cartels. Recent events. Collusion and cartels 2. Cartels. Recent cartel violations 2

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Lecture 3 OLIGOPOLY (CONTINUED) 13-1 Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Collusion. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Collusion February / 31

3. Cartels and Collusion

Part III: Market Structure 12. Monopoly 13. Game Theory and Strategic Play 14. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

OLIGOPOLY AND DUOPOLY. Asst.. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN

Finance 510 Midterm #2 Practice Questions

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Econ8500_Game_Theory. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Analytic Preliminaries for Social Acceptability of Legal Norms &

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

Industrial Organization Lecture 6: Dynamic Oligopoly and Collusion

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2

Collusion with secret price cuts: an experimental investigation. Abstract

Oligopoly C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

CMSC 474, Introduction to Game Theory Analyzing Normal-Form Games

Noncooperative Collusion

Game Theory Exam, June 2015

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Collusion and horizontal agreements

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition. The Dynamics of Pricing Rivalry

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

CH short answer study questions Answer Section

Spontaneous Cooperation under Anarchy

ECONS 101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS QUIZ #6 Week 04/19/09 to 04/25/09

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

Chapter 6. Game Theory One

How to simulate the coordinated effect of a merger

How do we know the market structure?

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Solutions to Final Exam

AGEC 3333 Practice Questions for Exam 3 Fall Semester, 2009 Set A: Material From Chapter 10, Pages ,

AQA Economics A-level

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

4 Effects of a change in marginal cost (Extra) α β q * 1. The reason is that this is the first-order condition for the firm's choice of quantity.

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

Lecture 6: Profit reducing price discrimination, and product differentiation Tom Holden

Games in Extensive Form and Repeated Games Benjamin E. Hermalin University of California, Berkeley

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS (EC201)

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 33 Oligopoly (Contd )

Overview 11/6/2014. Herfindahl Hirshman index of market concentration ...

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

AP Microeconomics: Test 5 Study Guide

Firm Supply. Market demand. Demand curve facing firm

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set #8 July 5, 2016

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Unit 13 AP Economics - Practice

Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Duopoly Monopoly. The further right on the scale, the greater the degree of monopoly power exercised by the firm.

Imperfect Competition

Final exam and review informa0on

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

ECO 610: Lecture 9. Oligopoly, Rivalry, and Strategic Behavior

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Market Structure. Monopolistic Oligopoly. By Asst. Prof. Kessara Thanyalakpark, Ph.D.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Oligopolies Part III

Transcription:

Lecture 4: Will profits in reality be higher or lower than under Cournot? Tom Holden http://io.tholden.org/

Q p = 1 p. Two firms both with zero marginal costs. Proportional rationing: Residual demand facing firm 2 if they price above firm 1 is: Q p 2 Q p 1 q 1 Q p 1. Claim to prove: p = 1 q 1 + q 2 is an equilibrium in the second stage price game, providing q 1 < 1 and q 4 2 < 1. 4 Note that this threshold is lower than before. With proportional rationing it is harder to get a Cournot-like outcome (and in general you won t).

Recall the Davidson and Deneckere argument: When firms run out of stock, it is not always the consumers with the lowest valuations who are left without the good. This reduces the cost of being the higher priced firm, in terms of lost demand. As a result, in the first period firms will be prepared to invest more in capacity. So quantity ends up above the Cournot quantity (and profits end up below). But what if firms can collude? Collusion will tend to result in higher profits than under Cournot.

Collusion Why collude? Examples and types. Sustaining collusion in dynamic oligopoly. When is collusion easier?

Under Cournot or Bertrand competition, the price is always below the monopoly one (and quantity is higher). Since a monopolist could choose either the Cournot or Bertrand price if they really wanted, aggregate industry profits must be lower under Cournot or Bertrand. So by agreeing to collude on a high price, all firms may increase their profits. The business stealing effect underlying oligopoly competition drives this. A firm that increases its quantity does not internalise the negative impact it will have on the profits of other firms. This externality means that (relative to the goal of maximising industry profits) firms will produce too much. A bit like a prisoner s dilemma. There is a Pareto-dominant outcome (featuring collusion), that cannot be sustained as an equilibrium.

Open agreements. (Analysed in OZ 5.4) E.g. the OPEC cartel. Generally just maximise joint profits, i.e. the cartel acts as if it was one firm not several. Illegal in most developed countries. Secret agreements. E.g. between Sotherby s and Christie s in the 90 s. CEO s of the two companies met in secret, and agreed on common commission charges. (Also shared client lists and removed the possibility of negotiating rates.) Eventually Christie s came forward with information, leading to a $65 million fine of Sotherby s (combined US and EU), and a $7.5 million fine for the CEO of Sotherby s along with one year in jail. The two auction houses also paid customers over $0.5 billion in compensation.

Secret agreements (continued). Or the Vitamin cartel of the 90 s (Hoffman-LaRoche, BASF, Aventis, Solvay, Merck, etc.) Regular exchange of sales data, price fixing. Eventually prosecuted, $0.5 billion fine for Hoffman-LaRoche in the US and $225m for BASF, plus additional fines in the EU. Prison time and personal fines for the executives. Tacit agreements. What we shall mostly focus on. E.g. the fact that almost all shops selling Sony TV s charge the same price (well above MC).

If my rival is selling vitamin C pills at 1 per 100 pills, no matter what informal agreement we might have in place, I will always be tempted to start selling them at 99p per 100. To sustain collusion then, my rival needs to be able to punish me for undercutting them. E.g. by pricing at marginal cost for a prolonged period. Collusion is thus always a dynamic phenomenon.

Is having a finite number of sales periods enough to sustain P > MC? Consider any game with a unique Nash equilibrium (e.g. Prisoner s Dilemma, Cournot, Bertrand, etc.), and imagine it is to be played T times in succession, with final payoffs given by a (discounted) sum of payoffs from each period s game. To find the SPNE, as usual we start at the final period and work backwards. The final period is just the stage-game, so all players will play the Nash equilibrium of the stage-game. Given everyone is playing the Nash equilibrium in the stage-game in the final period (independent of the history up to there), in the penultimate period everyone will also play the Nash equilibrium of the stage-game. Etc. Thus finitely repeated symmetric marginal cost Bertrand competition results in P = MC in each period.

Infinitely many periods, indexed by t = 0,1,2,. n firms, each with constant marginal cost c. Market demand curve Q p, finite monopoly profits π M, corresponding to a price p M. A monopolist would maximise Q p p c, meaning 0 = Q p M p M c + Q p M. Each firm i 1, n simultaneously sets its price p i,t each period t, to maximise the discounted sum of their present and future profits: s=0 β s π i,t+s = π i,t + βπ i,t+1 + β 2 π i,t+2 + where π i,t is firm i s profits in period t.

Trivial equilibrium: all firms set p i,t = c in each period t. Maximum-profit collusive equilibrium: In the first period, all firms set p i,1 = p M. In subsequent periods t, all firms set p i,t = p M unless they have ever observed another firm setting a price other than p M, in which case they set p i,t = c. Thus if a firm ever deviates and sets a price below the monopoly one, from then on no firm makes a profit. This is a grim trigger strategy.

A strategy is an SPNE if and only if there is no possible history up to a point t such that some player i would like to deviate from the strategy in period t only. Proof is omitted. Means we do not have to worry about complicated multi-period deviations.

Use one-stage deviation principle to prove that the collusive equilibrium is an SPNE: If at some point a firm has ever set a price other than p M, then all firms are pricing at cost, which means we are effectively in the trivial equilibrium (from which no firm wants to deviate).

Use one-stage deviation principle to prove that the collusive equilibrium is an SPNE: If up to now all firms have priced at p M, does a firm want to deviate? Profits from now on from not deviating are π M n + β π M n + β 2 π M + = π M. n n 1 β Profits from deviating are π M. (The deviating firm sets a price just below p M, then all firms price at c from then on.) So the proposed strategy is an SPNE if and only if π M n 1 β π M, i.e. if and only if 1 n 1 β, which is true if and only if β n 1 n, i.e. if and only if firms are sufficiently patient.

Firms with rational owners will use β = 1 where r is the real interest rate for a one period bond. Could be months, years, etc. Due to arbitrage between shares and bonds. The material in the next slide goes a bit beyond the textbook, but is still worth understanding. 1+r

Now suppose that demand was given by Q t p = 1 + g t Q p, so if g > 0 demand is growing. A monopolist would maximise 1 + g t Q p p c in period t, so the monopoly price is constant at p M, and monopoly profits are 1 + g t π M. Also suppose that each period, a firm has a probability of h of being hit by a death-shock which would force it to exit the industry. (Assume exiting firms are immediately replaced.) Finally suppose that the discount factor was 1. 1+r Then the expected profits from setting the monopoly price would be: π M + 1 1 + g 1 h π M + 1 1 + g 2 1 h 2 π M n 1+r n 1+r 2 n + Therefore behaviour in this model is the same as behaviour in our original model with β = 1 1+r 1 + g 1 h.

Putting the previous results together, setting the monopoly price is an SPNE in this richer model (with growing demand and death shocks) if and only if 1 1 + r 1 + g 1 h n 1 n. So, the likelihood of observing collusion is: Decreasing in the number of firms. Increasing in the speed with which the market is growing. Decreasing in the probability of a death shock. Decreasing in real interest rates.

In a growing market, n fixed is implausible. Guess that n t = n 1 + g t. Then the profits from setting the monopoly price (in the set up of 2 slides ago) would be: π M + n 1 1 + g 1 h π M + 1 1 + g 2 1 h 2 π M +. 1+r n 1+g 1+r 2 n 1+g 2 Our guess is verified as profits are not growing over time, so this is consistent with constant entry cost. So this model is just like having β = 1 model. The 1 + g terms cancel. 1+r 1 h in our original So when there is free entry, growing demand neither makes collusion more nor less likely.

Yes, because of: The Folk Theorem (Fudenburg and Maskin 1986): Consider any infinitely-repeated n player game, with payoffs given by the discounted sum of payoffs from each period s stage-game. For each player i, let π i be the lowest payoff that players other than i can force on player i in the stage-game. Everyone else gangs up on i to minimise their payoff. Imagine that all of the players had instructions that told them what action they should take in every period. And suppose that under these instructions, player i s average payoff would be v i, with v i > π i. Then providing a minor technical condition is satisfied, if players are sufficiently patient (i.e. discount factors are sufficiently high), there is an SPNE in which player i attain an average payoff off v i (for all i 1,, n ).

In symmetric Bertrand competition, the lowest payoff (profit) other players (firms) can force on a player is zero. A firm can always set its price equal to c and either sell nothing, or sell at cost. In symmetric Cournot competition, the lowest payoff (profit) other players (firms) can force on a player is also zero, by producing the perfect competition quantity. The remaining firm can always produce nothing. Highest possible profit that a single firm may make is π M, when other firms make zero profits. Thus for any vector of firm profits π 1, π 2,, π n with π i > 0 for all i and π 1 + π 2 + + π n π M : for sufficiently patient firms, there is an SPNE of both repeated Bertrand and repeated Cournot in which average profits are given by the vector π 1, π 2,, π n.

Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) extend the repeated- Bertrand setting to allow for stochastic demand. ( booms and recessions ) In a boom, it is more tempting to deviate, so prices have to be lower in booms to remove this temptation. Leads to counter-cyclical mark-ups. Green and Porter (1984) modify this model, supposing firms cannot observe aggregate demand. Then firms do not know if demand is low because they have been undercut, or because of the aggregate state. So they must punish for only a short period. Leads to pro-cyclical mark-ups. Agrees with Nekarda and Ramey (2010). Nice evidence for this particular story is provided by the Porter (1983) case study of 19 th century US railroad cartels.

Rather than thinking about common business cycle shocks, we can also think about shocks that hit one firm and not another. E.g. a firm s bank going bankrupt. Or a vital machine breaking. Or a new invention. Such shocks may lead a firm to have no alternative but to cut its price, so to punish them with P = MC for ever cannot be optimal. But the less often such shocks arrive, plausibly the easier sustaining collusion will be.

Evans and Kessides (1994) perform an empirical study of competition amongst US airlines. Find that prices are higher on routes served by airlines that compete on a lot of other routes. Deviating on one route may be punished by price cuts on all other routes on which the deviating airline flies. If all routes were identical this would not make any difference, because the cost of deviation would exactly balance the benefits of it (you could deviate in several markets simultaneously, thus earning higher profits). However, if airlines have natural cost advantages in some markets, then the maximal-profit collusive equilibrium would feature each airline serving the market in which it is most efficient, but ready to serve the other market should their rivals deviate.

Albraek et al. (1997) look at the consequences of the Danish Competition Council s 1993 decision to begin publishing the various prices charged by firms selling ready-mixed concrete. Idea was that the increased transparency would make it easier for consumers to shop around. Reality was that prices increased by 15%-20% within a year, and price dispersion fell. Cannot be explained by e.g. the business cycle. Natural explanation is that the public price information made it easier to detect firms deviating from collusive equilibria, and thus made collusion more likely.

OZ Ex. 6.8 Question 4 OZ Extra exercises: http://ozshy.50webs.com/io-exercises.pdf Set #9

Cournot competition is capacity constrained Bertrand. Plausible rationing results in lower profits than standard Cournot. Collusion with monopoly profits is sustainable as an SPNE of Cournot or Bertrand competition. As are many other profit levels, thanks to the Folk Theorem. We are more likely to observe P MC in dynamic oligopoly when: There are few firms in an industry. Markets are growing, but firm entry is blocked. Firms rarely leave the market. Real interest rates are low. Demand is observable and low. Demand is unobservable and high. There are few asymmetric shocks. Firms compete in multiple markets. Prices are transparent.