Literacy and numeracy abilities of overeducated and undereducated workers: Revisiting the allocation process in the labour market

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Literacy and numeracy abilities of overeducated and undereducated workers: Revisiting the allocation process in the labour market"

Transcription

1 Literacy and numeracy abilities of overeducated and undereducated workers: Revisiting the allocation process in the labour market Philipp Grunau 1 Institute for Employment Research January 2014 Abstract Both the theory of allocation and the human capital model imply that over- and undereducated individuals systematically differ from correctly-educated workers with respect to marketable human capital components beyond formal education. Using an innovative German dataset 2 entailing test scores on survey attendants literacy and numeracy competencies, I find evidence that overeducated (undereducated) workers possess inferior (superior) reading and math abilities compared to their educational peers. However, when compared to correctly allocated employees in jobs of the same level of required education, in line with the signalling theory, the findings are reverse. Controlling for employment biographies to account for mismatch-induced skill alterations over time strengthens the relevance of the selection into over- and undereducation based on competencies. Moreover, a certain part of the wage effects associated with educational mismatch can be attributed to the more comprehensive account for human capital components. [216 words] JEL classification: I21, J24, J31, M53 Keywords: overeducation, undereducation, ability, literacy, numeracy, wages, allocation, human capital, signalling. 1 Institute for Employment Research, Department Establishments and Employment, Regensburger Str. 104, Nuremberg, Germany. philipp.grunau@iab.de. 2 This paper uses data from the National Educational Panel Study (NEPS): Starting Cohort 6 Adults, doi: /neps:sc6: From 2008 to 2013, NEPS data were collected as part of the Framework Programme for the Promotion of Empirical Educational Research funded by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF). As of 2014, the NEPS survey is carried out by the Leibniz Institute for Educational Trajectories (LIfBi) at the University of Bamberg in cooperation with a nationwide network. 1

2 Introduction Fostered by politics, most countries have recently faced a phase of substantial educational expansion. In Germany, for example, during 1976 and 2012 the proportion of (all) individuals holding a university (of applied science) degree rose from 4.8% to 13.0%, whereas the share holding the lowest secondary qualification (Hauptschulabschluss) meanwhile more than halved itself from 74.0% to 35.6% (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2013). This development is in fact intended by politics. The European Union sets the goal for successful completed tertiary education (for the population aged 30 to 34) at 40% in Meeting this goal seems far from unrealistic, since until 2012 the proportion has already risen up to 35.7% (European Commission, 2013). Moreover, the OECD recently attested to Germany that its rise in the share of tertiary educated adults between 2000 and 2012 is comparably low and hence, the nowadays share is even below the OECD average (OECD, 2014). However, this politically intended development bears the peril of rising overeducation in case the increased supply of higher educated workers is not adequately met by a respectively enhanced demand (McGuinness, 2006). Furthermore, undereducation may arise, too, for example if in certain occupations the demand for university graduates exceeds its supply (e.g., in STEM 3 -related jobs), forcing hiring firms to employ undereducated workers from these fields, perhaps in combination with the provision of intense training measures. Frequently, the phenomena of over- and undereducation are regarded to result from a dysfunctional allocation mechanism. However, in light of the occurrence of over- and undereducation, both the theory of allocation and human capital theory stipulate that these groups should systematically differ in terms of other marketable qualities beyond formal education that are observable to the employer during the application process. To be more precise, overeducated (undereducated) workers should therefore be worse (better) endowed than correctly-matched educational peers, which is what Sloane et al. (1999) refer to as substitutability hypothesis and which is also pointed out by several other authors. 4 Addressing the increasing importance of this, Chevalier and Lindley (2009) argue that the expanded access to higher education through the last decades has led to an increased heterogeneity of graduates as it implies the admission of students from lower parts of the ability distribution. Moreover, due to considerations from the signalling theory (Spence, 1983) as well as concerning skill updating caused by educational attainment, when compared to correctly-educated workers of deviating levels of attained education but in jobs with the same amount of required education, overeducated (undereducated) workers should possess superior (inferior) marketable properties. However, despite these conceivable mechanisms, most analyses restrict explicit consideration of human capital endowments to formal educational attainment, labour market experience, and on-the-job training, presumably because other parts of human capital are usually not observed. 3 STEM refers to the fields of science, technology, engineering, and mathematics. 4 e.g. Green and McIntosh, 2007; Jochmann and Pohlmeier, 2004; Allen and van der Velden, 2001; and Groot,

3 Considering discrepancies in the returns to wages, to date the results relying on the restricted consideration of human capital endowments lead to the rejection of human capital theory (HCT). According to this theory, wage discrepancies can solely be originated in differences in individuals human capital. The detected wage penalty (wage premium) for overeducation (undereducation), controlling for formal education, therefore cannot be explained by HCT. If selection into over- and undereducation is nonrandom and the hypothesis mentioned above proves right, the hitherto restricted consideration of human capital endowments might turn out to be responsible for at least part of the differences between adequately-allocated and educationally mismatched workers. Depending on the size of this effect, the validity of HCT for explaining wage differences may to some part be restored and the problems associated with formal educational mismatch only be due to misspecification. Taking into consideration what is mentioned above, this study is devoted to elucidate the following research questions: (1) Do workers equipped with more (less) formal education than required by their current job possess worse (more) literacy and numeracy skills when compared to their educational peers?, (2) Do overeducated (undereducated) employees have superior (inferior) literacy and numeracy abilities than correctly allocated colleagues of similar jobs?, and (3) Can this more comprehensive account of human capital components contribute to explain the wage penalty (wage premium) compared to educational peers that is usually found accompanying overeducation (undereducation) when only considering formal education and work experience? To address these questions I use data from the German National Educational Panel Study (NEPS) which encompass information on individuals employment, including a measure for required education, and several socio-demographics. Exploiting the subjective assessment on the educational attainment that is usually required by the job currently pursued allows identifying required education and hence, when compared to the highest educational degree currently held, the (vertical) adequacy of attained education for the current job. In the second wave of the adult starting cohort this comprehensive set of information for the first time is further enriched by test scores from comprehensive tests on basic competencies with respect to reading speed, reading comprehension, and maths competency. Therefore, it is possible to account for a substantially more comprehensive part of individuals human capital endowment. Theoretical considerations Considering the theory of allocation and adapted versions of the human capital model, the occurrence of over- and undereducation implies that overeducated (undereducated) workers when compared to their educational peers lack (possess) other marketable and observable properties beyond formal education. However, when comparing to correctly-educated workers in jobs of the same level of required education, signalling theory (Spence, 1983), which stipulates that individuals invest in the attainment of formal education according to their amount of ability or productivity, suggests the oppo- 3

4 site. Both hypotheses combined, overeducated (undereducated) workers, although possessing inferior (superior) cognitive abilities compared to their educational peers, should have better (worse) numeracy and literacy competencies than well-matched colleagues in jobs of the same level of required education. Furthermore, these differences in human capital endowments apart from formal education numeracy and literacy abilities should contribute to explaining the discrepancies in the returns to different parts of education if those additional components are in fact marketable. Therefore, in this paper I consider test scores from comprehensive tests on reading and math competencies which are assumed to depict basic abilities that are observable for the employer during the application process. Corresponding studies suggest that such cognitive abilities are positively associated with earnings (e.g. Anger and Heineck, 2010, for Germany; Bronars and Oettinger, 2006, and Murnane et al., 1995, for the US), while others point out the importance of noncognitive skills (Heckman et al., 2006). More similar to the data used in the present paper, McIntosh and Vignoles (2001) utilise test-based measures of basic literacy and numeracy skills from the UK and find that these skills play an important role for the determination of wages. These results are confirmed by Vignoles et al. (2011), again with data from the UK. If now higher basic reading and math skills coincide with both higher wages and the likelihood of being overor undereducated, this could explain the wage discrepancies accompanying over- and undereducation in models that fail to account for these additional human capital components, hence restoring significance of human capital theory and the efficacy of the allocation mechanism. Literature review The phenomenon of educational mismatch is regarded to result from dysfunctional allocation. However, as pointed out by several authors (e.g. Green and McIntosh, 2007; Allen and van der Velden, 2001; Sloane et al., 1999; Groot, 1996), there may be individual heterogeneity within a level of formal education with respect to differences in further components of human capital like ability and competencies In their meta-analysis of 25 studies, Groot and van den Brink (2000) conclude that the phenomenon of overeducation has become increasingly frequent among individuals from the lower area of the ability distribution. For the UK, Green et al. (2002) find that overeducated workers are less able when compared to individuals of the same educational attainment who are well-matched in their jobs. They explain this result with certain groups of similar formal education in which workers of comparably low ability are forced to accept jobs who match their actual skills. Estimating correlations between overeducation and overskilling, Green and McIntosh (2007) come to a similar conclusion. The low correlation of 0.2 the authors detect implies that once additional components of human capital are accounted for, a true mismatch is rather rare. Moreover, Chevalier and Lindley (2009), comparing the graduate labour market before and after the educational expansion in the early 1990s, reveal the dramatically 4

5 rising importance of non-observable characteristics, whose effect has increased more than 10 times over this period. Against this backdrop, they conclude that overeducated workers tend to have less favourable unobservable characteristics. For the Netherlands, Allen and van der Velden (2001) also find evidence for unobserved differences playing a substantial role for the existence of the mismatch between formal education and the requirements of jobs. De Grip et al. (2007) extend this view by investigating on reverse causality. The authors argue that being overeducated leads to a decline in cognitive ability as response to reduced intellectual challenge. On the other hand, undereducation involves an increased intellectual challenge through skill updating (cf. Pazy, 2004; Fratiglioni et al., 2004; Bosma et al., 2003a/b). However, de Grip et al. do not detect deviating abilities for overeducated or undereducated workers. Using Italian data with information on individuals detailed self-assessment concerning the effectiveness of provided skills as proxies for ability, Cainarca and Sgobbi (2012) conclude that employees ability despite being of importance for the determination of wages does not significantly affect the wage effects of required, surplus, and deficit education. For Germany, Buechel and Pollmann-Schult (2004) find that the risk of being overeducated depends on the type of school diploma, which they take as a proxy for educational quality. Moreover, Jochmann and Pohlmeier (2004) point to the importance of the selection into overqualification. In their analysis which is based on a Bayesian approach to account for selection into overqualification, they find that once controlling for this selectivity, the average treatment effect on the treated converges close to zero. This implies that overqualified workers would not receive higher wages if they were employed adequately, again implying that they do not depict a random pick from all individuals. Addressing the probability to be overeducated at a certain time from a different perspective, Clark et al. (2014) find that the probability to exit overeducation is also rather caused by selection on unobservables than by true state dependence. Addressing potential causes, Chevalier and Lindley (2009) argue that the expanded access to higher education through the last decades has led to an increased heterogeneity of graduates as it implies the admission of students from lower parts of the ability distribution. Hence, when the best workers select into the best jobs, selection into overeducation and undereducation, respectively, is non-random and depends on those further components of human capital. This would imply that overeducated (undereducated) workers tend to have less (more) human capital apart from formal education than their wellmatched peers of the same formal education, which is what Sloane et al. (1999) referred to as the substitutability hypothesis. Despite this conceivable mechanism, most analyses restrict consideration of human capital endowments to formal educational attainment and labour market experience, presumably because other parts of human capital are usually not observed. 5

6 Data and estimation approach The German National Educational Panel Study (NEPS), a project funded by the Federal Ministry of Education and Research, has been established to study different educational processes in Germany across the entire life span. Out of the eight stages ranging from early childhood to adulthood, this study makes use of the data on starting cohort 6 (adults). In its second wave from 2012, for the first time test scores from tests on basic reading and math competencies have been collected and provided. Since both education and employment decisions of women may be driven by other important characteristics or circumstances not observed in the data, regressions are restricted to men. Moreover, only full-time working men are used in order to avoid the estimates to be biased due to structural differences between full-time and part-time (or marginal) employment. Additionally, because of the survey design which assigns the time-consuming competence tests on reading comprehension and mathematical competency only to a subgroup of participants who have answered the questionnaire, a full set of information on educational decisions, other important characteristics, and at least one competency test is available for 2,414 full-time working men. The test scores included in the NEPS data contain test scores for reading (Gehrer et al., 2013) and math competencies (Neumann et al., 2013), where the former is divided into reading speed and reading comprehension 5. All these tests are accomplished using the paper-pencil mode. They can be regarded as comparatively objective and comprehensive since participants are not asked their subjective perception of their skills. The scores on reading comprehension and math competency where each consists of several items and takes about half an hour are introduced to the analyses in this paper as weighted maximum likelihood estimates (WLE), which depict the best point estimates of the individual competence scores. In contrast to the application of plausible values, WLE are manifest scores (not latent) that do not account for measurement error. However, for the purpose of this paper WLE appear to be the superior solution, since plausible values correct for the measurement error by shifting competence scores towards the mean of the group whose (observed) characteristics have been used for their calculation, hence implying that there is a measurement error for all individuals and that its direction is away from the group mean. For a description of the scaling of the competence tests see Pohl and Carstensen (2012, 2013). To account for the measurement precision of the competence estimates of each individual, the standard errors of the WLE for both reading comprehension and math competency are included into the wage regression as well. The incorporation of reading speed is realised by introducing the number of correctly judged simple sentences during a 2 minute test (range: 0 to 51) to the estimation equation. 5 There is a further test on procedural metacognition which depicts the knowledge and control of the own cognitive system, identified by asking participants after they have finished their competence tests to rate their own performance. As this concept, however, is not of use in this study, it is neglected. 6

7 To assess the educational adequacy of the current job this study relies on the subjective perception of individuals. During the interview respondents are asked what kind of educational degree is usually required to do their job. By comparing this information with the one on attained education of the interviewee then provides an evaluation of whether an individual s formal education matches the one required by his or her job, allowing to classify each worker as over-, under-, or adequately educated. To acknowledge the fact that there are many ways of measuring educational mismatch and that these measurements can lead to different results, I additionally use an alternative measure as a robustness check. This measure relies on large-scale administrative data on employees liable to social security contributions, allowing me to identify required education per each of the 332 occupations of the occupational classification KldB 1988 via the mode of actually attained educational degrees. When investigating the differences concerning literacy and numeracy competencies between over-, under-, and adequately educated workers, in order to address comparison to both groups of correctly allocated workers i.e. to answer research questions (1) and (2), I utilise two different approaches, which both are widely used in the corresponding literature. The first one, mostly referred to as the ORU approach, has been proposed by Duncan and Hoffmann (1981) in their seminal paper on overeducation in the US. This approach requires information on years of attained education, which are decomposed into years of education required by the job, years of excess education (if years of attained education exceed the years of required education) and years of deficit education (if years of required education exceed the years of attained education). In the NEPS data, while information on the exact years of education is available, years of required education are not and therefore have to be generated. This is achieved on the individual rather than on the occupation level where the respondent s statement on the education usually required for his or her current job has to be translated into (required) years of education. The latter, again, is realised by calculating mean years of education for each of the categories of required education actually observed in the data (confer Table A1 in the appendix). Therefore, within each group of the same educational degree, years of attained education may vary, whereas years of required education are the same by construction. By including variables for required, excess, and deficit years of education into the estimation equation, the coefficients on the latter two variables implicitly exhibit the impact of over- and undereducation on the respective outcome conditional upon the same years of required education, i.e. in comparison to individuals working in a job which is similarly demanding concerning formal education. On the contrary, the dummy approach provides another interpretation. It introduces variables indicating the highest attained educational degree and one for each being over- and undereducated. Thus, for correctly allocated workers, the latter two dummies turn out zero. By this means, the latter two dummy variables indicate the effect of over- or undereducation, respectively, on the respective outcome conditional upon the same educational degree, i.e. in comparison to individuals who have attained the same formal education but are adequately educated for their current job. 7

8 Utilising both estimation approaches thus provides the advantage of investigating on the effects of over- and undereducation in a twofold manner, comparing them to both adequately matched colleagues of different educational attainment doing the same job (ORU approach) and correctly allocated educational peers (dummy approach). Addressing the hypotheses underlying this paper I will regress both wages and the different competency scores on over- and undereducation. The specification based on the dummy approach looks like this: Wage(ln) Comp read speed read comp mat comp = β 0 + β 1 educ + β 2 OE + β 3 UE + β 4 X + ε with educ denoting a vector of dummies for the level of attained education, OE being the coefficient of a dummy indicating overeducation and UE indicating undereducation. The vector X comprises control variables included in the equation such as age, age squared, a dummy indicating whether a person is born in Germany or not, as well as regional dummies indicating the German Länder and 7 sectoral dummies. Alternatively, the specification following the ORU approach looks like this: Wage(ln) Comp read speed read comp mat comp = β 0 + β 1 Yrs RE + β 2 Yrs OE + β 3 Yrs UE + β 4 X + ε with Yrs RE denoting years of required education, Yrs OE those of excess, and Yrs UE those of deficit education. The control variable vector is the same as in the dummy specification. The wage equations addressed thereafter basically follow the same approach, with the only differences being that the vector of control regressors additionally includes dummies indicating the sector a worker is currently employed in. Both the weighted maximum likelihood estimates (WLE) from the tests on reading comprehension and math competency, which are constrained to mean zero and a value range from -5 to +5, and wages will be considered in the estimation utilising OLS regression. However, because the score for reading speed can take values from 0 to 51, for these estimations I apply negative binomial regressions to account for the count nature of this (dependent) variable. Descriptive Evidence Within the restricted estimation sample of 2,414 full-time working men with information on required and attained educational attainment as well as at least on one competency test approximately 66 per 8

9 0 0 kdensity lnwage kdensity wage cent turn out being adequately educated. In contrast, 21 per cent can be regarded as overeducated and about 13 per cent as undereducated for the current job. First, let us take a look at the unconditional distribution of wages illustrated below using kernel density plots (Figure 1a). Both for wages in logarithmic and absolute values it is clear from first sight that employees who have attained more education than required by their current job tend (solid line) to earn less than both the under- and adequately educated. On the other hand, undereducated workers (dashed line) appear to receive higher wages than those with the exact amount of education as required (dotted line). This pattern becomes even more distinct when misallocated workers are compared with adequately matched individuals of the same educational attainment, as is illustrated in Figure 1b. When, however, comparing individuals to workers in jobs with a similar amount of required education (confer Figure 1c), the differences seem to be less distinct (undereducation) or even to vanish (overeducation). Figure 1a: Kernel density plots of gross monthly earnings (left: in logs, right: absolute values), by match of educational attainment Gross monthly wage (log) Gross monthly wage (abs) Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. 9

10 0 0 0 kdensity comp_read_speed kdensity comp_read kdensity comp_math kdensity lnwage2.5 kdensity wage kdensity lnwage kdensity wage Figure 1b: Kernel density plots of gross monthly earnings (left: in logs, right: absolute values), by match of educational attainment; restricted to workers with a vocational degree Gross monthly wage (log) Gross monthly wage (abs) Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Figure 1c: Kernel density plots of gross monthly earnings (left: in logs, right: absolute values), by match of educational attainment; restricted to workers of jobs with similar required education Gross monthly wage (log) Gross monthly wage (abs) Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Turning to the workers literacy and numeracy skills, the comparison of the unconditional distribution by educational match status displayed in Figure 2a shows that overeducated workers tend to be worse equipped than correctly allocated employees, whereas there does not seem to be a clear difference between the latter and undereducated workers. Figure 2a: Kernel density plots of test scores on reading speed (number of correctly judged sentences), reading comprehension, and math competency (both WLE); unrestricted Test score of reading speed (between 0 and 51) WLEs of reading competence (constrained to have mean zero) WLEs of math competence (constrained to have mean zero) 10

11 0 0 0 kdensity comp_read_speed kdensity comp_read kdensity comp_math Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. However, as the pivotal hypotheses of this paper stated above suggest, when compared to their educational peers, overeducated workers should be of inferior and undereducated workers should be of superior literacy and numeracy abilities. Consequently, when re-considering the unconditional distributions by restricting those to workers with a vocational degree as highest educational attainment (Figure 2b), the picture sharpens considerably. While overeducated workers (solid line) still tend to have inferior literacy and numeracy skills compared to adequately educated individuals (dotted line), undereducated employees (dashed line) now tend to be better endowed. Figure 2b: Kernel density plots of test scores on reading speed (number of correctly judged sentences), reading comprehension, and math competency (both WLE); restricted to workers with a vocational degree Test score of reading speed (between 0 and 51) WLEs of reading competence (constrained to have mean zero) WLEs of math competence (constrained to have mean zero) Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. To address the mirrored hypothesis that compares cognitive abilities of mismatched workers with those of correctly allocated employees in jobs with the same level of required education, graphics are presented for the sample restricted to individuals whose jobs require the same amount of formal education (here: set to 12.9 years which is the largest group in the dataset). As the graphics in Figure 2c suggest, both over- and undereducated employees tend to have superior reading and math skills than correctly allocated workers in jobs with a similar required education. In the case of overeducation, this result is in line with the corresponding hypothesis, but for undereducation it implies that those possessing deficit amounts of formal education appear to outdo correctly educated workers of both the same attained and required educational attainment. However, of course, these results do not take into account potentially important influence factors; hence, the concluding assessment requires conditional correlations with control variables which is provided throughout the subsequent section. 11

12 0 0 0 kdensity comp_read_speed kdensity comp_read kdensity comp_math Figure 2c: Kernel density plots of test scores on reading speed (number of correctly judged sentences), reading comprehension, and math competency (both WLE); restricted to workers in jobs of similar required education Test score of reading speed (between 0 and 51) WLEs of reading competence (constrained to have mean zero) WLEs of math competence (constrained to have mean zero) Source: NEPS starting cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. To draw an interim conclusion, we have seen that in the cross section of 2012 and without taking into account individual characteristics, workers appear to differ with respect to literacy and numeracy abilities conditional upon the adequacy of the match between their attained formal education and the one required by their current job. Especially when compared to their educational peers, overeducated (undereducated) workers tend to possess inferior (superior) reading and math competencies. However, when compared to correctly allocated employees in job with a similar amount of required education, both over- and undereducated workers appear better equipped with respect to cognitive abilities. Since owing to the survey design not each participant is assigned to each competency test, the estimations that will be exhibited within this study possess deviant subsamples of full-time working men 6. Thus, corresponding summary statistics of the variables incorporated in each regression are provided in Tables A2a and A2b in the appendix. A comparison of these statistics reveals small but mostly insignificant biases in the subsample of those who took part in all three competency tests (N=1,047, specification (5) of Table A2b) compared with the baseline sample of all 2,414 full-time working men with a full set of required information (specification (1) of Table A2a). However, the only significant deviation is that the former exhibit a slightly higher likelihood of being adequately matched with respect to formal education, which turns out to be only marginally significant on the 5 per cent level 7. Econometric results Selection on basic competencies Before turning to the impact on the returns to education, let us first consider the significance of the further human capital components apart from formal education for the state of being over-, under-, or adequately educated, when this state is solely determined by attained formal education. As has been 6 About 50 per cent of the sample have undertaken both tests and approximately each a forth only one of the two tests. 7 A corresponding t-test for the null of equal means across groups reveals a p-value of

13 proposed, the occurrence of both over- and undereducation is assumed to pose a negative selection with respect to literacy and numeracy skills which are also responsible for individual performance. Following this argumentation, overeducated (undereducated) workers should have inferior (superior) competencies than their correctly allocated educational peers. However, when compared to correctly allocated colleagues of lower (higher) educational attainment, overeducated (undereducated) employees are supposed to possess superior (inferior) competencies. Therefore, in terms of these additional components of human capital workers whose education is incommensurate with the one required by their current job ought to lie between those of the same education who are correctly allocated and those well matched colleagues doing the same job (i.e. of different educational attainment). Turning to reading speed (Table 1a), reading comprehension and math competency (both Table 1b), we can see that controlling for sex, working time, age, place of birth, and region (federal states), the results seem to confirm the hypothesis stated above. Relying on the dummy approach (specifications (1), (3), and (5)), where the account for attained education in terms of dummies for the respective highest degree holds attained education fixed, the dummies for over- and undereducation, respectively, convey these statuses impact in comparison to adequately allocated peers of the same educational group. Hence, the negative coefficient for overeducation in column (1) suggests that employees with more education than is required by their current job have a reading speed inferior to those of their well-matched educational peers. In contrast, undereducation is associated with higher reading skills. The same holds true for both reading comprehension and mathematical ability, as can be seen in specifications (3) and (5). Focussing on the alternative ORU specification displayed in column (2), (4), and (6) of Tables 1a and 1b, the comparison differs in that because of the inclusion of required years of education effects now are in comparison to the test performance of individuals in jobs with the same level of required education, which in turn necessarily implies that comparison is made with workers of different attained education. The coefficient on overeducation compares to correctly allocated colleagues of lower education, and vice versa for undereducation. In line with the hypothesis, the coefficient on years of excess education is positive, implying that overeducation corresponds to superior competencies when compared to adequately-educated individuals of lower education. On the other hand, when interpreting this coefficient with the one for years of required education, where the latter is larger, this confirms the conclusion drawn from the results based on the dummy specification, meaning that the overeducated are of superior competencies compared to adequately educated individuals of the same educational attainment. As the association between undereducation on the one hand and both reading and math skills on the other turns out negative but smaller than the effect on required education, conclusions are vice versa: have superior competencies when compared to adequately matched educational peers but inferior competencies when compared to correctly allocated colleagues doing the same job, i.e. of higher educational endowment. 13

14 Table 1a: Negative binomial regression estimates from regressing test scores from reading speed on individual characteristics Reading speed test score 1 Selected regressors: (1) (2) Age.381***.371*** (.141) (.140) Age squared -.006*** -.006*** (.002) (.002) Place of birth (D; 1=Germany) 9.197*** 9.376*** (1.038) (1.009) Education Secondary school leaving certificate/a levels 8.412*** (1.983) Vocational qualification 7.684*** (1.877) University (of Applied Science) degree *** (1.913) Overeducated (D) *** (.437) Undereducated (D) 2.411*** (.529) Years of required education 1.316*** (.084) Years of excess education 1.002*** (.155) Years of deficit education -.658*** (.176) Number of observations 2,423 2,423 α (dispersion coeff.).025*** (.002).024*** (.002) LR test (H 0 : α=0) x ²= (p=.000) x ²= (p=.000) Source: NEPS Starting Cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance denoted as: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The constant, 16 state dummies, and 7 industry dummies are included in the regression, but not displayed. 1 The test score is scaled from 0 to 51 depicting the number of correctly judged sentences during a 2-minute test. 14

15 Table 1b: OLS estimates from regressing test scores (WLE) for reading comprehension and math competency on individual characteristics Dependent variable: Test scores 1 on Reading comprehension Math competency Selected regressors: (3) (4) (5) (6) Age.118***.111***.100***.093*** (.022) (.021) (.023) (.023) Age squared -.002*** -.002*** -.001*** -.001*** (2.46e-04) (2.44e-04) (2.69e-04) (2.59e-04) Place of birth (D; 1=Germany).731***.694***.365***.325*** (.131) (.126) (.129) (.118) Education Secondary school leaving certificate/a levels 1.733*** 1.581*** (.260) (.299) Vocational qualification 1.373*** 1.473*** (.235) (.269) University (of Applied Science) degree 2.467*** 2.680*** (.241) (.275) Overeducated (D) -.162** -.268*** (.072) (.072) Undereducated (D).304***.291*** (.089) (.092) Years of required education.269***.325*** (.015) (.014) Years of excess education.224***.227*** (.027) (.028) Years of deficit education -.143*** -.172*** (.027) (.027) Number of observations 1,793 1,793 1,753 1,753 R-squared Source: NEPS Starting Cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance denoted as: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The constant, 16 state dummies, and 7 industry dummies are included in the regression, but not displayed. 1 Weighted maximum likelihood estimators (WLEs) based on scores across all test of the respective discipline, constrained to have mean zero, a minimum at -5 and a maximum at +5. As the estimations within the last chapter have shown, depending on their commensurateness of attained and required education, workers differ in their literacy and numeracy abilities. Thus, both hypotheses (1) and (2) can be confirmed. However, from these results it cannot be distinguished between two conceivable effect directions. On the one hand, overeducated (undereducated) workers, when compared to their educational peers, may be employed in a job under-utilising (over-utilising) their formal education because they possess superior (inferior) skills and competencies, as is hypothesised in this paper. On the other hand, due to the decay of unused skills (skill updating due to intellectual challenge) these workers may have inferior (superior) endowments because of being overeducated (undereducated), as has been argued by de Grip et al. (2007). A strategy to encounter this interpretational issue is to take into account the employment biography of each individual observed in the data, which is available due to the retrospective design of the NEPS survey. For instance, apart from considerations on state dependence, there is a correlation between the 15

16 occurrences of overeducation and unemployment, as is shown by (Buechel, 2001). Once controlling for the employment biography, the coefficients on educational (mis)match should convey the conditional correlation for the current state only, hence avoiding them to be corrupted by impacts from former periods of educational mismatch or unemployment. If the coefficients on over- and undereducation lose their significance when comparing an overeducated (undereducated) with an adequately allocated worker conditioning on a similar employment biography, this points to the relevance of the skill alteration hypothesis as skills and competencies need time to develop. On the contrary, if the results remain significant (and retain their effect sign) this strengthens the relevance of the selection into overand undereducation based on cognitive (numeracy and literacy) abilities. To account for the employment biography in a suitable manner, additional variables are added to the regression equations, one of each representing the time spent in adequately allocated employment, in overeducation, in undereducation, and in unemployment. 8 Beyond exploiting the information on the workers employment biography, an additional test for effect direction is to interact job tenure with the indicator variables on over- and undereducation in the dummy specification to account for the duration of the current experience in educational mismatch. If the coefficients of the interaction terms turn out significant, this again would vote in favour of decaying skills due to over- and improving skills due to undereducation. The corresponding results are displayed in Table 2. Except for dummy specification (3) on reading comprehension, all corresponding coefficients on the educational match retain both their sign and their statistical significance, giving validity to the interpretation that workers are overeducated (undereducated) because of an inferior (superior) skill and competency endowment when compared to educational peers. 8 For the calculation of the years spent in each of this states of (un)employment information on a monthly level is utilized, hence resulting in more accurate measures than with exploiting years only. 16

17 Table 2: OLS estimates from regressing test scores (WLE) for literacy and numeracy skills on individual characteristics, including employment biographies Dependent variable: Test scores 1 on Reading speed Reading comprehension Math competency Selected regressors: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Age.408***.382***.125***.117***.105***.095*** (.142) (.141) (.022) (.022) (.024) (.023) Age squared -.007*** -.007*** -.002*** -.002*** -.001*** -.001*** (.002) (.002) (2.46e-04) (2.43e-04) (2.71e-04) (2.60e-04) Job tenure (.034) (.032) (.005) (.005) (.005) (.005) Place of birth (D; 1=Germany) 8.982*** 9.005***.721***.660***.347***.293** (1.026) (.996) (.129) (.125) (.129) (.119) Secondary school leaving certificate/a levels 7.831*** 1.630*** 1.528*** (2.007) (.260) (.288) Vocational qualification 6.873*** 1.276*** 1.379*** (1.912) (.236) (.258) University (of Applied Science) degree *** 2.349*** 2.566*** (1.963) (.244) (.266) Overeducated (D) * * (.677) (.118) (.115) Undereducated (D) 1.751** ** (.788) (.132) (.143) Years of required education 1.280***.265***.320*** (.091) (.015) (.015) Years of excess education.979***.238***.259*** (.245) (.049) (.043) Years of deficit education *** -.200*** -.203*** (.270) (.039) (.040) Years of adequate employment (.019) (.018) (.003) (.003) (.003) (.003) Years of under-utilising employment (.021) (.019) (.004) (.003) (.003) (.003) Years of over-utilising employment *** (.038) (.023) (.006) (.003) (.006) (.004) Years of unemployment -.466*** -.444*** -.031* ** -.037* (.123) (.122) (.017) (.017) (.021) (.022) Interaction OE x job tenure (.063) (.017) (.010) (.003) (.010) (.003) Interaction UE x job tenure (.080) (.021) (.013) (.003) (.012) (.003) Number of observations 2,411 2,411 1,784 1,784 1,744 1,744 Source: NEPS Starting Cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance denoted as: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The constant, 16 state dummies, and 7 industry dummies are included in the regression, but not displayed. 1 Weighted maximum likelihood estimators (WLEs) based on scores across all test of the respective discipline, constrained to have mean zero, a minimum at -5 and a maximum at

18 Returns to education Considering the returns to education, to the extent that the additional human capital components of literacy and numeracy abilities that reach beyond formal education itself are associated with wages what is implied by corresponding studies, the introduction of these characteristics to the estimation of the returns to education is assumed to explain some part of the wage penalty associated with overeducation (wage premium of undereducation) when compared to educational peers as well as of the wage premium of overeducation (wage penalty of undereducation) when compared to workers in the same job. If this proves to be true, the rejection of human capital theory should be reconsidered. The residual deviation, if still existent, thus would imply either a prevailing mismatch and hence a dysfunctional allocation in the labour market or the existence of other unobserved marketable (=productivity-related) properties of individuals that overeducated (undereducated) workers lack (abound in), as implied by theory for the case of perfect allocation. To pursue this research question I run standard linear OLS estimations regressing wages (in logarithms) on several individual characteristics. In order to produce a viable benchmark, I estimate the standard regression excluding all human capital components beyond formal education on the same subsample for which information is available when estimating the extended specification including both working experience (age and tenure) and numeracy and literacy abilities. These further characteristics are then included step-by-step in specifications (2) and (3) to identify the impact of their consideration on the main coefficients, i.e. on the wage effects of over- and undereducation. The results are presented in Table 3. 18

19 Table 3: Returns to education and the impact of various competencies; dummy specification Dependent variable: Gross monthly wages (log) Formal education only Including Experience Full specification Selected regressors (1) (2) (3) Place of birth (D; 1=Germany).292***.260***.153*** (.048) (.047) (.046) Formal education Secondary school leaving certificate/a levels (.209) (.190) (.181) Vocational qualification (.169) (.147) (.140) University (of Applied Science) degree.531***.479***.265* (.171) (.149) (.144) Overeducated (D) -.096*** -.104*** -.096*** (.034) (.034) (.034) Undereducated (D).208***.202***.167*** (.062) (.058) (.057) Experience-related measures Age.056***.048*** (.015) (.015) Age squared -.001*** -4.82e-04*** (1.49e-04) (1.66e-04) Job tenure.013***.013*** (.005) (.005) Job tenure squared -3.34e-04** -3.29e-04** (1.31e-04) (1.30e-04) Literacy and numeracy abilities Reading speed test score 1.005*** (.002) Reading comprehension test score (WLE 2 ).052** (.021) Reading comprehension test score (SE) (.077) Math competency test score (WLE 2 ).027* (.016) Math competency test score (SE) (.098) Number of observations 1,024 1,024 1,024 R-squared Source: NEPS Starting Cohort 6 (adults), wave 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance denoted as: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The constant, 16 state dummies, and 7 industry dummies included in the regression, but not displayed. 1 Test score is scaled from 0 to 51 depicting the number of correctly judged sentences during a 2-minute test. 2 Weighted maximum likelihood estimators (WLEs) based on scores across all test of the respective discipline, constrained to have mean zero, a minimum at -5 and a maximum at +5. Let s start with the basal specification (1) that apart from the state and industry dummies included in every specification only contains formal educational attainment (in degrees) and a dummy on whether the place of birth is Germany. The coefficients appear as suggested by findings from similar studies. Compared to correctly-allocated educational peers, overeducation is associated with a wage penalty of about 9.6 log points (10.1 per cent), whereas undereducation involves a wage premium of 20.8 log points (23.1 per cent). Turning to specification (2) containing labour market experience proxied by age and job tenure (as well as their squared transformations), the coefficients for both over- and undereducation do not change significantly. This points to the restricted importance of work experience for 19

20 explaining the wage discrepancies between over-, under-, and adequately educated employees. Further extending the account for additional human capital components to literacy and numeracy abilities reveals distinctive and positive ceteris paribus correlations for each of the test scores on reading speed, reading comprehension, and math competency (confer specification (3)). First, an increase in reading speed corresponding to one more sentence judged correctly is associated with higher earnings. Although the coefficient appears small (0.5 log points), an increase in the test score for readings speed by one standard deviation is associated with 4.6 log points (4.7 per cent) higher earnings. In comparison, an increase in reading comprehension by one standard deviation is accompanied by higher earnings of around 5.2 log points (5.3 per cent). A corresponding increase in math competency is associated with higher wages by 2.7 log points (2.7 per cent). As opposed to experience-related measures, the inclusion of the literacy and numeracy competencies only shows the expected effect for undereducation in that it drives the corresponding coefficient statistically significant and substantially closer to zero. The coefficient on overeducation by and large retains its size. Thus, the importance of accounting for this competency-related heterogeneity of workers of similar educational attainment appears to be limited for explaining the wage penalty of overeducation but substantial for explaining the wage premium associated with undereducation. Addressing the ORU specification (Table A3 in the appendix), hence shifting comparison from educational peers to workers of the same job, conclusions are similar. However, in this case the coefficients on both returns to over- and undereducation are significantly reduced towards zero when comparing specification (1) and (3), thus implying that part of the wage premium (wage penalty) associated with overeducation (undereducation) can be explained by the heterogeneity with respect to reading and math competencies. Furthermore, as the coefficients are still both statistically and economically significant in both the dummy and the ORU specification it follows that there is a substantial mismatch in the labour market. Hence, this result is in line with similar analyses (cf. Alba-Ramírez (1993); Green et al., 2002; Chevalier and Lindley, 2009). However, there is still the possibility of other unobserved marketable human capital components that significantly affect the relative returns to wages between required, surplus, and deficit education. Such factors could further diminish the unexplained discrepancies in the returns to different parts of attained education, hence reducing the significance of the mismatch in the labour market. Alternative measurement of educational mismatch To acknowledge the fact that there are many ways of measuring educational mismatch and that these measurements can lead to different results, I additionally use an alternative measure as a robustness check. This measure relies on large-scale administrative data on employees liable to social security contributions, allowing me to identify required education per each of the 332 occupations of the occu- 20

THE DYNAMICS OF SKILL MISMATCHES IN THE DUTCH LABOR MARKET

THE DYNAMICS OF SKILL MISMATCHES IN THE DUTCH LABOR MARKET THE DYNAMICS OF SKILL MISMATCHES IN THE DUTCH LABOR MARKET Wim Groot* Department of Health Sciences, Maastricht University and "Scholar" Research Centre for Education and Labor Market Department of Economics,

More information

Much Ado About Social Outcomes?

Much Ado About Social Outcomes? Much Ado About Social Outcomes? Skill Effort, mismatches, and their relation with non-economic outcomes and job satisfaction Marie-Christine Fregin Ineke Bijlsma Rolf van der Velden Presentation for the

More information

Chasing the carrot. Effort provision of fixed-term employees

Chasing the carrot. Effort provision of fixed-term employees Chasing the carrot Effort provision of fixed-term employees Mario Bossler * Philipp Grunau October 2016 Abstract Fixed-term contracts can serve as a screening device to reveal the true ability of workers.

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2596 3 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 940 JUNE 2005 CAUSES OF OVEREDUCATION IN THE AUSTRALIAN LABOUR MARKET by Ingrid Linsley Department

More information

MEASURES OF OCCUPATIONAL MISMATCH

MEASURES OF OCCUPATIONAL MISMATCH Monica Mihaela MAER MATEI Bucharest University of Economic Studies, Romania National Scientific Research Institute for Labour and Social Protection (INCSMPS), Bucharest, Romania MEASURES OF OCCUPATIONAL

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2595 5 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 939 JUNE 2005 OVEREDUCATION IN THE AUSTRALIAN LABOUR MARKET: ITS INCIDENCE AND EFFECTS by Ingrid

More information

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data Andreas Mueller 1 Stockholm University First Draft: May 15, 2009 This Draft: August 11, 2010 Abstract This paper provides new evidence

More information

The Age Pay Gap in Italy Investigating the Sources of the Pay Differential by Age

The Age Pay Gap in Italy Investigating the Sources of the Pay Differential by Age The Age Pay Gap in Italy Investigating the Sources of the Pay Differential by Age Marina Töpfer University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, Department of Economics, Germany November 22, 2017 Preliminary version,

More information

Keywords: Education System, Vocational Education, Youth Labour Market, Unemployment

Keywords: Education System, Vocational Education, Youth Labour Market, Unemployment The Impact Of Vocational Orientation Of Education Systems On Quantitative And Qualitative Dimensions Of The Youth Labour Market Situation. Bolli, Thomas; Egg, Maria Esther; Rageth, Ladina. Eidgenössische

More information

Deconstructing Theories of Overeducation in Europe: A Wage Decomposition Approach

Deconstructing Theories of Overeducation in Europe: A Wage Decomposition Approach DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 9698 Deconstructing Theories of Overeducation in Europe: A Wage Decomposition Approach Seamus McGuinness Konstantinos Pouliakas February 2016 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft

More information

OVERQUALIFICATION: PERMANENT OR TRANSITORY? DAVID DORN and ALFONSO SOUSA-POZA UNIVERSITY OF ST. GALLEN

OVERQUALIFICATION: PERMANENT OR TRANSITORY? DAVID DORN and ALFONSO SOUSA-POZA UNIVERSITY OF ST. GALLEN OVERQUALIFICATION: PERMANENT OR TRANSITORY? DAVID DORN and ALFONSO SOUSA-POZA UNIVERSITY OF ST. GALLEN Abstract: This paper analyzes job mismatches in Switzerland based on a subjective measure of overqualification.

More information

THE GENDER WAGE GAP IN THE HUMAN CAPITAL FRAMEWORK: A CROSS-NORDIC ASSESSMENT BASED ON PIAAC. Maryna Tverdostup, Tiiu Paas 1 University of Tartu

THE GENDER WAGE GAP IN THE HUMAN CAPITAL FRAMEWORK: A CROSS-NORDIC ASSESSMENT BASED ON PIAAC. Maryna Tverdostup, Tiiu Paas 1 University of Tartu THE GENDER WAGE GAP IN THE HUMAN CAPITAL FRAMEWORK: A CROSS-NORDIC ASSESSMENT BASED ON PIAAC Abstract Maryna Tverdostup, Tiiu Paas 1 University of Tartu This paper studies the role of human capital in

More information

Wage Impacts of Schooling Mismatches: Evidence From A Matched Employer- Employee Panel #

Wage Impacts of Schooling Mismatches: Evidence From A Matched Employer- Employee Panel # Wage Impacts of Schooling Mismatches: Evidence From A Matched Employer- Employee Panel # Pedro Martins * University of Warwick (Work in progress. This version: 8 July 2001) Abstract: I address the spread

More information

Educational mismatches versus skill mismatches: effects on wages, job satisfaction, and on-the-job search

Educational mismatches versus skill mismatches: effects on wages, job satisfaction, and on-the-job search # Oxford University Press 2001 Oxford Economic Papers 3 (2001), 434 452 434 All rights reserved Educational mismatches versus skill mismatches: effects on wages, job satisfaction, and on-the-job search

More information

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, Spring, 2002, pp

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, Spring, 2002, pp 08. Girma article 25/6/02 3:07 pm Page 93 The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, Spring, 2002, pp. 93-100 Why are Productivity and Wages Higher in Foreign Firms?* SOURAFEL GIRMA University of

More information

Unpaid Overtime in Germany: Differences between East and West

Unpaid Overtime in Germany: Differences between East and West Unpaid Overtime in Germany: Differences between East and West Silke Anger Humboldt University Berlin Abstract Although the standard work week is longer in East than in West Germany, there is a higher incidence

More information

Private Returns to Education in Greece: A Review of the Empirical Literature

Private Returns to Education in Greece: A Review of the Empirical Literature Ioannis Cholezas Athens University of Economics and Business and CERES and Panos Tsakloglou Athens University of Economics and Business, IMOP and CERES Private Returns to Education in Greece: A Review

More information

International Journal of Economics

International Journal of Economics [[ Page 27 International Journal of Economics 02, 01 (2015): 27-43 contents available as open access International Journal of Economics Full-length Original Research Paper journal homepage: Overeducation

More information

Gender pay gap and returns to cognitive and non-cognitive skills: Evidence from Australia

Gender pay gap and returns to cognitive and non-cognitive skills: Evidence from Australia Gender pay gap and returns to cognitive and non-cognitive skills: Evidence from Australia Garry Barrett and Anita Staneva School of Economics, University of Sydney 2017 Australian Conference of Economists

More information

The returns to learning later in life: a summary of CEE work

The returns to learning later in life: a summary of CEE work The returns to learning later in life: a summary of CEE work Leon Feinstein, Fernando Galindo- Rueda, Andrew Jenkins, Anna Vignoles, Alison Wolf See: CEE DPs 19, 36, 37, 39 Background Labour force has

More information

OVERQUALIFICATION AND CAREER. Simonetta Longhi Malcolm Brynin ISER University of Essex

OVERQUALIFICATION AND CAREER. Simonetta Longhi Malcolm Brynin ISER University of Essex OVERQUALIFICATION AND CAREER Simonetta Longhi (slonghi@essex.ac.uk) Malcolm Brynin (brins@essex.ac.uk) ISER University of Essex 1 OVERQUALIFICATION AND CAREER Abstract A considerable proportion of the

More information

Rising Work Complexity but Decreasing Returns

Rising Work Complexity but Decreasing Returns DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 9878 Rising Work Complexity but Decreasing Returns Anna Katharina Pikos Stephan L. Thomsen April 2016 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study

More information

How well matched are South African workers to their jobs?

How well matched are South African workers to their jobs? 2017 LMIP WORKING PAPER 1 How well matched are South African workers to their jobs? A comprehensive analysis of education and skills mismatch Erofili Grapsa This working paper is published in 2017 by the

More information

Training and the New Minimum Wage

Training and the New Minimum Wage Training and the New Minimum Wage Wiji Arulampalam +, Alison L Booth ++, and Mark L Bryan +++ Revised July 2003 May 2003 Abstract Using the British Household Panel Survey, we estimate the impact of the

More information

Standard analysis model for monitoring compliance with wage equality between women and men in federal procurement (methodology)

Standard analysis model for monitoring compliance with wage equality between women and men in federal procurement (methodology) Federal Department of Home Affairs FDHA Federal Office for Gender Equality FOGE Standard analysis model for monitoring compliance with wage equality between women and men in federal procurement (methodology)

More information

Overeducation, labor market dynamics, and economic downturn in Europe

Overeducation, labor market dynamics, and economic downturn in Europe Overeducation, labor market dynamics, and economic downturn in Europe Camilla Borgna, Heike Solga, Paula Protsch International Conference on PIAAC and PIAAC-Longitudinal Symposium Overeducation and skill

More information

Linking survey data with administrative employment data: The case of the IAB-ALWA survey

Linking survey data with administrative employment data: The case of the IAB-ALWA survey Linking survey data with administrative employment data: The case of the IAB-ALWA survey 4th User Conference of the FDZ of the BA at the IAB April 09, 2011 Manfred Antoni (GradAB, FB E1) Motivation I:

More information

RESEARCH SUMMARY THE DIGITAL DIVIDE: COMPUTER USE, BASIC SKILLS AND EMPLOYMENT

RESEARCH SUMMARY THE DIGITAL DIVIDE: COMPUTER USE, BASIC SKILLS AND EMPLOYMENT RESEARCH SUMMARY THE DIGITAL DIVIDE: COMPUTER USE, A COMPARATIVE STUDY IN PORTLAND, USA AND LONDON, ENGLAND John Bynner, Steve Reder, Samantha Parsons and Clare Strawn OCTOBER 2008 2 RESEARCH SUMMARY INTRODUCTION

More information

ERSA th Congress of the European Regional Science Association August 30 th September 3 rd 2006 Volos, Greece

ERSA th Congress of the European Regional Science Association August 30 th September 3 rd 2006 Volos, Greece ERSA 2006 46th Congress of the European Regional Science Association August 30 th September 3 rd 2006 Volos, Greece REGIONAL DIFFERENCES IN OVEREDUCATION Signe Jauhiainen * University of Jyväskylä, School

More information

Appendix (Additional Materials for Electronic Media of the Journal) I. Variable Definition, Means and Standard Deviations

Appendix (Additional Materials for Electronic Media of the Journal) I. Variable Definition, Means and Standard Deviations 1 Appendix (Additional Materials for Electronic Media of the Journal) I. Variable Definition, Means and Standard Deviations Table A1 provides the definition of variables, and the means and standard deviations

More information

Over- and under-education and the relation to vocational training 1

Over- and under-education and the relation to vocational training 1 Over- and under-education and the relation to vocational training 1 Joop Hartog University of Amsterdam Results on overand under-education The well-known Mincerian earnings function relates the log of

More information

Assessing the incidence and wage effects of overeducation among Italian graduates using a new measure for educational requirements

Assessing the incidence and wage effects of overeducation among Italian graduates using a new measure for educational requirements ISSN 2282-6483 Assessing the incidence and wage effects of overeducation among Italian graduates using a new measure for educational requirements Luca Cattani Giovanni Guidetti Giulio Pedrini Quaderni

More information

The Computer Use Premium and Worker Unobserved Skills: An Empirical Analysis

The Computer Use Premium and Worker Unobserved Skills: An Empirical Analysis The Computer Use Premium and Worker Unobserved Skills: An Empirical Analysis Michael D. Steinberger * May, 2005 Abstract: On-the-job computer use is associated with a 10-15% wage premium for US workers.

More information

LABLAC LABOR DATABASE FOR LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

LABLAC LABOR DATABASE FOR LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN This version: March, 2018 A GUIDE TO LABLAC LABOR DATABASE FOR LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN CEDLAS * and The World Bank ** * Centro de Estudios Distributivos, Laborales y Sociales at Universidad Nacional

More information

Performance-based Wage System and Motivation to Work

Performance-based Wage System and Motivation to Work Performance-based Wage System and Motivation to Work Fumio Ohtake, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University Koji Karato, Faculty of Economics, Toyama University Abstract This paper presents

More information

Over-Education in the Graduate Labour Market: Some Evidence from Alumni Data

Over-Education in the Graduate Labour Market: Some Evidence from Alumni Data ISSN 2045-6557 Over-Education in the Graduate Labour Market: Some Evidence from Alumni Data Peter Dolton and Mary Silles June 2001 Published by Centre for the Economics of Education London School of Economics

More information

Plan of the presentation

Plan of the presentation Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Over-Qualified or Under-Skilled? Glenda Quintini OECD DELSA, Employment Analysis and Policy Division OECD Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social

More information

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Beyond balanced growth 11 PartA Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Uwe Sunde and Thomas Vischer Abstract: Human capital plays a central role in theoretical

More information

The Return to Cognitive Skills in the Australian Labour Market

The Return to Cognitive Skills in the Australian Labour Market The Return to Cognitive Skills in the Australian Labour Market Garry Barrett UNSW April 2010 Garry Barrett (UNSW) Return to Cognitive Skills April 2010 1 / 27 Motivation Returns to Education and Cognitive

More information

A Note on Risk Aversion and Labour Market Outcomes: Further Evidence from German Survey Data

A Note on Risk Aversion and Labour Market Outcomes: Further Evidence from German Survey Data DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3523 A Note on Risk Aversion and Labour Market Outcomes: Further Evidence from German Survey Data Christian Pfeifer May 2008 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

World of Labor. Peter J. Sloane Swansea University, UK, Flinders University, Australia, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

World of Labor. Peter J. Sloane Swansea University, UK, Flinders University, Australia, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros Peter J. Sloane Swansea University, UK, Flinders University, Australia, and IZA, Germany World of Labor Overeducation, skill mismatches, and labor market outcomes for college graduates Overskilling or

More information

Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence

Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence Spring 2010 Rosburg (ISU) Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence Spring 2010 1 / 40 Earnings Equations We have discussed (and will discuss

More information

Working from Home: Heterogenous Effects on Hours Worked and Wages

Working from Home: Heterogenous Effects on Hours Worked and Wages Working from Home: Heterogenous Effects on Hours Worked and Wages Melanie Arntz, Sarra Ben Yahmed and Francesco Berlingieri Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) February 2018 Preliminary draft Keywords:

More information

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6 Econ 792 Labor Economics Lecture 6 1 "Although it is obvious that people acquire useful skills and knowledge, it is not obvious that these skills and knowledge are a form of capital, that this capital

More information

Over-skilling and job satisfaction in the Australian labour force

Over-skilling and job satisfaction in the Australian labour force Over-skilling and job satisfaction in the Australian labour force NILS, FLINDERS UNIVERSITY Kostas Mavromaras ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL RESEARCH INSTITUTE, DUBLIN Seamus McGuinness NILS, FLINDERS UNIVERSITY

More information

Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany

Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany Marco Caliendo Ricarda Schmidl Arne Uhlendorff Working Paper February 1, 2010 Abstract In this paper we analyze the relationship

More information

Skills Mismatch and Firm Dynamics:

Skills Mismatch and Firm Dynamics: European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training Centre for Research in Employment, Skills & Society Skills Mismatch and Firm Dynamics: Integrating skills with the world of work Expert workshop

More information

Horizontal Skills Mismatch and Vocational Education

Horizontal Skills Mismatch and Vocational Education Horizontal Skills Mismatch and Vocational Education Annina Eymann and Juerg Schweri February 24, 2015 Discussion Paper Abstract We analyze horizontal mismatch in Switzerland defined as a mismatch between

More information

Over-education and over-skilling in the labour market: theory and empirics

Over-education and over-skilling in the labour market: theory and empirics Institut d Études Politiques de Paris École Doctorale Economics and Public Policy Over-education and over-skilling in the labour market: theory and empirics By: Joanne Tan Supervisor: Jean-Marc Robin Denis

More information

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria Mariya Neycheva Burgas Free University April 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/55633/ MPRA Paper

More information

WORK INTENSIFICATION, DISCRETION, AND THE DECLINE IN WELL-BEING AT WORK.

WORK INTENSIFICATION, DISCRETION, AND THE DECLINE IN WELL-BEING AT WORK. WORK INTENSIFICATION, DISCRETION, AND THE DECLINE IN WELL-BEING AT WORK. INTRODUCTION Francis Green University of Kent Previous studies have established that work intensification was an important feature

More information

THE QUANTITY AND PRICING OF HUMAN CAPITAL IN CANADA AND THE UNITED STATES

THE QUANTITY AND PRICING OF HUMAN CAPITAL IN CANADA AND THE UNITED STATES Preliminary and Incomplete: Please do not quote THE QUANTITY AND PRICING OF HUMAN CAPITAL IN CANADA AND THE UNITED STATES Audra Bowlus*, Haoming Liu** and Chris Robinson* *University of Western Ontario

More information

DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES

DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES Antonio Di Paolo*, Ferran Mañé^ Universitat Rovira i Virgili & Employment Observatory Author correspondence:

More information

DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES

DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES DETERMINANTS AND CONSEQUENCES OF QUALIFICATION AND SKILLS MISMATCH AMONG RECENT PHD GRADUATES Antonio Di Paolo*, Ferran Mañé^ Universitat Rovira i Virgili & Employment Observatory Author correspondence:

More information

Empirical Exercise Handout

Empirical Exercise Handout Empirical Exercise Handout Ec-970 International Corporate Governance Harvard University March 2, 2004 Due Date The new due date for empirical paper is Wednesday, March 24 at the beginning of class. Description

More information

Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1

Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1 Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1 Jóannes Jacobsen, Jan Rose Skaksen and Anders Sørensen, CEBR, Copenhagen Business School 1. Introduction In the literature on information technology

More information

NO. 70 GRADUATE OVER-EDUCATION AS A SHEEPSKIN EFFECT: EVIDENCE FROM NORTHERN IRELAND. SEAMUS McGUINNESS

NO. 70 GRADUATE OVER-EDUCATION AS A SHEEPSKIN EFFECT: EVIDENCE FROM NORTHERN IRELAND. SEAMUS McGUINNESS WORKING PAPER SERIES NO. 70 GRADUATE OVER-EDUCATION AS A SHEEPSKIN EFFECT: EVIDENCE FROM NORTHERN IRELAND SEAMUS McGUINNESS NORTHERN IRELAND ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTRE GRADUATE OVER-EDUCATION AS A SHEEPSKIN

More information

Designing the integration of register and survey data in earning statistics

Designing the integration of register and survey data in earning statistics Designing the integration of register and survey data in earning statistics C. Baldi 1, C. Casciano 1, M. A. Ciarallo 1, M. C. Congia 1, S. De Santis 1, S. Pacini 1 1 National Statistical Institute, Italy

More information

Discussion Papers. Silke Anger Guido Heineck. Cognitive Abilities and Labour Market Outcomes: First Evidence for Germany

Discussion Papers. Silke Anger Guido Heineck. Cognitive Abilities and Labour Market Outcomes: First Evidence for Germany Discussion Papers Silke Anger Guido Heineck Cognitive Abilities and Labour Market Outcomes: First Evidence for Germany Berlin, December 2006 Silke Anger a Guido Heineck b Cognitive Abilities and Labour

More information

THE IMPACT OF IN-HOUSE TRAINING ON THE DIVERSITY

THE IMPACT OF IN-HOUSE TRAINING ON THE DIVERSITY THE IMPACT OF IN-HOUSE TRAINING ON THE DIVERSITY DIMENSIONS OF EMPLOYEE PRODUCTIVITY IN THE SOUTH AFRICAN WORKPLACE Gerhardus van Zyl* University of Johannesburg Received: May 2016 Accepted: December 2016

More information

December Abstract

December Abstract PULLED AWAY OR PUSHED OUT? EXPLAINING THE DECLINE OF TEACHER APTITUDE IN THE UNITED STATES CAROLINE M. HOXBY AND ANDREW LEIGH* December 2003 Abstract There are two main hypotheses for the decline in the

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES. CEEAplA WP No. 01/2007. Overeducation and Wages in Europe: Evidence from Quantile Regression. Santiago Budría Ana Moro-Egido

WORKING PAPER SERIES. CEEAplA WP No. 01/2007. Overeducation and Wages in Europe: Evidence from Quantile Regression. Santiago Budría Ana Moro-Egido WORKING PAPER SERIES CEEAplA WP No. 01/2007 Overeducation and Wages in Europe: Evidence from Quantile Regression Santiago Budría Ana Moro-Egido January 2007 Universidade dos Açores Universidade da Madeira

More information

MONTHLY REVIEW OF ACADEMIC LITERATURE ON ASPECTS OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND SKILLS IN RESEARCH AND INNOVATION POLICY

MONTHLY REVIEW OF ACADEMIC LITERATURE ON ASPECTS OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND SKILLS IN RESEARCH AND INNOVATION POLICY Issue 10 /May 2016 MONTHLY REVIEW OF ACADEMIC LITERATURE ON ASPECTS OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND SKILLS IN RESEARCH AND INNOVATION POLICY Contact: DG RTD, Directorate A, A.4, Eva Rückert, Tel. 89319, eva.rueckert@ec.europa.eu

More information

The relationship between formal education and skill acquisition in young workers first jobs

The relationship between formal education and skill acquisition in young workers first jobs FACULTEIT ECONOMIE EN BEDRIJFSKUNDE TWEEKERKENSTRAAT 2 B-9000 GENT Tel. : 32 - (0)9 264.34.61 Fax. : 32 - (0)9 264.35.92 WORKING PAPER The relationship between formal education and skill acquisition in

More information

Young graduate employees between educational mismatch and skill mismatch: An empirical analysis based on REFLEX data

Young graduate employees between educational mismatch and skill mismatch: An empirical analysis based on REFLEX data Young graduate employees between educational mismatch and skill mismatch: An empirical analysis based on REFLEX data September 2011 PRELIMINARY VERSION Francesca Sgobbi DIMI, University of Brescia, Via

More information

SKILLS GAPS AND THE PATH TO SUCCESSFUL SKILLS DEVELOPMENT

SKILLS GAPS AND THE PATH TO SUCCESSFUL SKILLS DEVELOPMENT SKILLS GAPS AND THE PATH TO SUCCESSFUL SKILLS DEVELOPMENT EMERGING FINDINGS FROM SKILLS MEASUREMENT SURVEYS IN EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA Johannes Koettl, Sara Johansson de Silva, and Olga Kupets Investing

More information

International Conference on Employability of Graduates & Higher Education Management Systems Vienna, September 2011

International Conference on Employability of Graduates & Higher Education Management Systems Vienna, September 2011 International Conference on Employability of Graduates & Higher Education Management Systems Vienna, 22-23 September 2011 Young graduate employees between educational mismatch and skill mismatch: An empirical

More information

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence Mariya Neycheva * 1. Introduction The economics of growth is one of the most popular fields of study in both theoretical and empirical

More information

Jim Allen, Lourdes Badillo-Amador, Rolf van der Velden. Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: Heterogeneous skills or institutional effects?

Jim Allen, Lourdes Badillo-Amador, Rolf van der Velden. Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: Heterogeneous skills or institutional effects? Jim Allen, Lourdes Badillo-Amador, Rolf van der Velden Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: Heterogeneous skills or institutional effects? RM/13/071 Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: Heterogeneous

More information

How Useful is the concept of Skills Mismatch? Seamus McGuinness

How Useful is the concept of Skills Mismatch? Seamus McGuinness How Useful is the concept of Skills Mismatch? Seamus McGuinness WHAT IS SKILL MISMATCH? VERTICAL MISMATCH Overeducation / undereducation and overskilling /underskilling which are typically measured using

More information

Outline. Human capital theory by C. Echevarria. Investment decision. Outline. Investment decision. Investment decision

Outline. Human capital theory by C. Echevarria. Investment decision. Outline. Investment decision. Investment decision Outline Human capital theory by C. Echevarria BFW, ch. 6 M. Turcotte 1. Investment decision 2. Human Capital 3. Formal Education a) Relation between Education and Productivity b) Investment Decision c)

More information

Do Customers Respond to Real-Time Usage Feedback? Evidence from Singapore

Do Customers Respond to Real-Time Usage Feedback? Evidence from Singapore Do Customers Respond to Real-Time Usage Feedback? Evidence from Singapore Frank A. Wolak Director, Program on Energy and Sustainable Development Professor, Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford,

More information

Applied Microeconometrics I

Applied Microeconometrics I Applied Microeconometrics I Lecture 5: Identification based on observables (continued) Tuomas Pekkarinen Aalto University September 25, 2018 Lecture Slides 1/ 31 Applied Microeconometrics I Reminder: Interpreting

More information

How Working Time Reduction Affects Employment and Wages

How Working Time Reduction Affects Employment and Wages How Working Time Reduction Affects Employment and Wages Preliminary version Pedro S. Raposo Jan C. van Ours January 28, 2008 Abstract December 1, 1996 the standard workweek in Portugal was reduced from

More information

The qualifications/jobs mismatch in Scotland

The qualifications/jobs mismatch in Scotland The qualifications/jobs mismatch in Scotland John Sutherland, Centre for Public Policy for Regions (CPPR), University of Glasgow Two important features within the Scottish economy over recent decades have

More information

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay I. Theoretical Model In this paper, I define skill-biased technological change as the technological shock that began in the 1970s with

More information

Written Preliminary Ph.D. Examination

Written Preliminary Ph.D. Examination Written Preliminary Ph.D. Examination Graduate Program in Applied Economics January 30, 2015 Labor Economics Instructions Answer a total of FOUR out of the six questions. Identify yourself by code letter,

More information

Overskilling, Job Insecurity and Career Mobility

Overskilling, Job Insecurity and Career Mobility DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2938 Overskilling, Job Insecurity and Career Mobility Seamus McGuinness Mark Wooden July 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Over-education: Is it voluntary for some individuals?

Over-education: Is it voluntary for some individuals? Over-education: Is it voluntary for some individuals? David J. Black Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne January 2012 Abstract Over-education research

More information

Structural Change and the Narrowing Gender Gap in Wages: Theory and Evidence from Hong Kong

Structural Change and the Narrowing Gender Gap in Wages: Theory and Evidence from Hong Kong Structural Change and the Narrowing Gender Gap in Wages: Theory and Evidence from Hong Kong 1 2 C. Simon Fan and Hon-Kwong Lui September 1999 Abstract: This paper offers a theoretical and empirical analysis

More information

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle Emi Nakamura Harvard University May 9, 2007 Abstract This paper develops a simple model in which unemployment arises from a combination of selection and bad luck.

More information

Job Mismatches and Career Mobility

Job Mismatches and Career Mobility DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 11844 Job Mismatches and Career Mobility Le Wen Sholeh A. Maani SEPTEMBER 2018 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 11844 Job Mismatches and Career Mobility Le Wen The

More information

Available through a partnership with

Available through a partnership with The African e-journals Project has digitized full text of articles of eleven social science and humanities journals. This item is from the digital archive maintained by Michigan State University Library.

More information

Scotland's Economic Performance. Prof. Keith Bender and Dr Alexandros Zangelidis

Scotland's Economic Performance. Prof. Keith Bender and Dr Alexandros Zangelidis Scotland's Economic Performance Prof. Keith Bender and Dr Alexandros Zangelidis Disclaimer This document is a revised version of the evidence document submitted to the Economy, Jobs and Fair Work Committee

More information

Work-Related Learning and Skill Development in Europe: Does Initial Skill Mismatch Matter?

Work-Related Learning and Skill Development in Europe: Does Initial Skill Mismatch Matter? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 10302 Work-Related Learning and Skill Development in Europe: Does Initial Skill Mismatch Matter? Maria Ferreira Annemarie Künn-Nelen Andries De Grip October 2016 Forschungsinstitut

More information

GENDER UNIQUE HUMAN CAPITAL AND LABOUR MARKET RETURNS

GENDER UNIQUE HUMAN CAPITAL AND LABOUR MARKET RETURNS DIEM Maryna Tverdostup University of Tartu School of Economics and Business Administration, Estonia E-mail: Maryna.tverdostup@ut.ee Tiiu Paas University of Tartu School of Economics and Business Administration,

More information

Education and Skill Mismatches in Maptaphut Industrial Estate, Thailand

Education and Skill Mismatches in Maptaphut Industrial Estate, Thailand Journal of Reviews on Global Economics, 2017, 6, 233-238 233 Education and Skill Mismatches in Maptaphut Industrial Estate, Thailand Duangjan Varakamin * College of Innovative Business and Accountancy,

More information

Coworker Networks in the Labour Market

Coworker Networks in the Labour Market Coworker Networks in the Labour Market Albrecht Glitz 1 Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE January 2012 PRELIMINARY - PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE Abstract This paper studies the role of coworker-based

More information

DETERMINANTS OF LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN MALTA FROM A FIRM-LEVEL SURVEY

DETERMINANTS OF LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN MALTA FROM A FIRM-LEVEL SURVEY DETERMINANTS OF LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN MALTA FROM A FIRM-LEVEL SURVEY Article published in the Quarterly Review 2018:3, pp. 43-49 BOX 3: DETERMINANTS OF LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN MALTA FROM A FIRM-LEVEL SURVEY

More information

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage Anja Lambrecht London Business School alambrecht@london.edu Catherine Tucker Katja Seim University

More information

COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE

COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE ABSTRACT Robert M. Saltzman, San Francisco State University This article presents two methods for coordinating

More information

Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles

Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles Human Capital and Income Inequality: Some Facts and Some Puzzles Amparo Castelló and Rafael Doménech 28th Annual Congress of the European Economic Association Goteborg, August 2013 1/28 . Introduction

More information

A number of studies have documented lower levels of schooling or formal education in

A number of studies have documented lower levels of schooling or formal education in 1. Introduction A number of studies have documented lower levels of schooling or formal education in developing countries among females relative to males (see for example, Dollar and Gatti 1999; Duflo

More information

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market Summary The discussion in Chapter 11 of the complex relationship between pay and productivity drew on a wide array of material from Chapters 5,

More information

demographic of respondent include gender, age group, position and level of education.

demographic of respondent include gender, age group, position and level of education. CHAPTER 4 - RESEARCH RESULTS 4.0 Chapter Overview This chapter presents the results of the research and comprises few sections such as and data analysis technique, analysis of measures, testing of hypotheses,

More information

Research Centre for Education and the Labour Market How Selection in Education and Labour Market Flexibility Affect Labour Market Outcomes

Research Centre for Education and the Labour Market How Selection in Education and Labour Market Flexibility Affect Labour Market Outcomes Research Centre for Education and the Labour Market How Selection in Education and Labour Market Flexibility Affect Labour Market Outcomes Mark Levels and Rolf van der Velden Basic idea of this paper (1)

More information

Journal of Asian Scientific Research

Journal of Asian Scientific Research Journal of Asian Scientific Research journal homepage: http://aessweb.com/journal-detail.php?id=5003 A METAFRONTIER PRODUCTION FUNCTION FOR ESTIMATION OF TECHNICAL EFFICIENCIES OF WHEAT FARMERS UNDER DIFFERENT

More information

Returns to Higher Education in Timor-Leste

Returns to Higher Education in Timor-Leste Returns to Higher Education in Timor-Leste TAKAO OKAMOTO MASTER STUDENT, KOBE UNIVERSITY OCTOBER 14, 2015 2 Outline of the Presentation 1. Background 2. Problem Statement 3. Research Question 4. Objective

More information

Which Apprenticeship Training Pays-Off? Determinants of Successful Apprenticeship Training

Which Apprenticeship Training Pays-Off? Determinants of Successful Apprenticeship Training Which Apprenticeship Training Pays-Off? Determinants of Successful Apprenticeship Training Robert Wagner, Ludwig-Maximilians University, Munich Thomas Zwick, Ludwig-Maximilians University, Munich and Centre

More information

Work-related learning and skill development in Europe:

Work-related learning and skill development in Europe: Work-related learning and skill development in Europe: Does initial skill mismatch matter? Maria Ferreira, Annemarie Künn-Nelen and Andries de Grip DP 09/2016-053 Research Centre for Education and the

More information