Endogenous Job Contact Networks

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Endogenous Job Contact Networks"

Transcription

1 Endogenous Job Contact Networks Andrea Galeotti Luca Paolo Merlino November First Draft. Abstract We use the UK Quarterly Labour Force Survey to document the presence of two phenomena. First, a positive correlation between unemployment rate and the proportion of job seekers who use social networks to find jobs network use. Second, a non-monotone relation between unemployment rate and the proportion of recently employed workers who found their job through friends or relatives network productivity. This second relation is positive for low levels of unemployment rate, while it becomes negative for high levels of unemployment rate. Existing models of social networks and labor market generally assume that social networks are exogenous. This assumption implies a negative correlation between unemployment rate and network productivity. We develop a model where social networks are used to collect job offers, but workers decide strategically how much to invest in their network. We show that equilibrium job contact networks are dense and more productive in transmitting information when labor market turnover is moderate, while they are less productive and segmented into clusters for either high or low turnover. The equilibrium response of job contact networks to changes in labor market conditions is sufficient to generate the empirical patterns which we document for the UK. JEL classifications: A14; J64; J63; D85; E24 Keywords: Unemployment; Job search; Endogenous Job Contact Networks. Department of Economics, University of Essex, Colchester, UK. agaleo@essex.ac.uk Departament d Economia i d Història Econòmica, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Edici B, Cerdanyola del Vallès (Barcelona), Spain. lmerlino@idea.uab.es. Merlino acknowledges financial support from the Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and the Spanish Ministry of Education and Science, through grant SEJ /ECON and FEDER.

2 1 Introduction It is well established that job contact networks play a prominent role in the matching between workers and vacant jobs. Empirical work, starting from Rees (1966) and Granovetter (1973), and generalized over the years, shows that between 30% and 50% of jobs are filled through social exchange of information. 1 This evidence has led to a number of theoretical studies in economics which explore the importance of social networks in labor markets, see, e.g., Boorman (1975), Montgomery (1991), Mortensen and Vishwanath (1994), Arrow and Borzekowski (2004), Calvó-Armengol (2004), Calvó-Armengol and Jackson (2004, 2007), Calvó-Armengol and Zenou (2005), Fontaine (2007) and Cahuc and Fontaine (2007). Most of this work (with some exception we shall describe below in this introduction) takes the network as given and focuses on its implications for aggregate and individual labor market outcomes. A direct implication of the assumption that job contact networks are exogenous is a negative correlation between the probability that connections match job seekers with vacancy jobs (network productivity) and aggregate unemployment rate. In fact, in periods of high unemployment, most job seekers will be linked with other job seekers and therefore information flow of job offers in the network will be limited. We use the UK Quarterly Labor Force Survey (QLFS) over the period from 1995 to 2005 to explore whether this correlation is present in the data. 2 As a proxy of network productivity we consider the proportion of newly employed workers that found a job through a friend or acquaintance that worked at the same employee. We also consider total network productivity: the number of newly employed workers that found a job through a friend or acquaintance that worked at the same employee. Figure 1(a) and figure 1(b) depicts the network productivity and the total network productivity against unemployment rate in Great Britain over the period 1995 to 2005, respectively. Conflicting with the theoretical prediction, we find that for low levels of unemployment 1 The findings of Granovetter (1973) and Rees (1966) have been generalized across countries, industrial sectors and demographic characteristics, see e.g., Blau and Robins (1990), Topa (2000), Munshi (2003), Bayer et al. (2005), Cingano and Rosolia (2006), Loury (2006). See Ioannides and Loury (2004) for an exhaustive survey on social networks and labor market. 2 Only males of working age (aged 16 to 64) resident in Great Britain are considered in our analysis. The sample is representative of the UK population. Appendix A provides a detailed account of the data and of the derivation of variables. 1

3 (a) Network productivity and unemployment rate in (b) Total network productivity and unemployment rate Great Britain in Great Britain Source: Quarterly Labour Force Survey, male respondents, aged 16-64, residents in Great Britain, waves from 1995:Q1 to 2005:Q1. Figure 1: Productivity of networks and unemployment. rate there is a strong positive relation between unemployment rate and network productivity. This relation eventually becomes negative for high levels of unemployment rate. A possible explanation for this pattern is that the extent to which individuals use or invest in their social networks depend on labor market conditions. As a proxy of network use we consider the proportion among job seekers that reported to use friends and acquaintances as the main job search method; total network use is the total number of job seekers that reported to use friends and acquaintances as the main job search method. Figure 2(a) and figure 2(b) depict network use and total network use against unemployment rate and it shows the presence of a strong positive correlation between the two. 3 In view of these findings, we develop a simple model where the role of social networks as a manner of obtaining information is taken as given, but the actual job contact network is endogenously determined by strategic interaction. We will show that, by allowing individuals to adjust their network investment to changes in labor market conditions, we can replicate the empirical patterns documented in Figures We would like to make three remarks about these empirical patterns. First, Appendix A contains the estimates of the correlations and of the quadratic fit displayed in figures 1-2. Second, in the same Appendix, we show that these patterns still obtain when we disaggregate the data at a regional level. Finally, we have considered the relation between network productivity and network use at some period t with respect to lagged unemployment (unemployment at some period t ) and we found qualitatively similar patterns. 2

4 (a) Network use and unemployment in Great Britain (b) Total network use and unemployment rate in Great Britain Source: Quarterly Labour Force Survey, male respondents, aged 16-64, residents in Great Britain, waves from 1995:Q1 to 2005:Q4. Figure 2: The use of networks and unemployment. In our basic model, workers lose their job with some probability job destruction rate, while with some other probability they access direct information about new available jobs vacancy rate. Workers, anticipating the risk of becoming unemployed, invest in connections with the view of accessing information that other workers may have. The protocol of job contact network formation follows Cabrales et al. (2007). In particular, each worker chooses a level of socialization and the profile of socialization determines the meeting possibilities across pair of workers. When unemployed Paul meets Helen, he receives information about a vacant job only if Helen has it and she does not need it (i.e., Helen has a needless offer), and she has chosen Paul among all her unemployed friends. The incentives to form connections therefore depend on the riskiness of the labor market and on the value of connections in transmitting information, which, in turn, is related to the state of the labor market. We first clarify the role that job contact networks play in matching workers with vacant jobs. For a given level of socialization, the likelihood of a match resulting from social interaction the network matching rate is described by a urn-ball matching function of the kind traditionally used in search models of the labor market, augmented by the socialization dimension. 4 The network 4 Urn-ball models have been extensively studied in probability theory. In labor market contexts, urns play the role 3

5 matching rate is increasing and concave in socialization effort, it depends positively on the ratio between the proportion of workers who have a needless offer job network supply and the proportion of unemployed job network demand, and it is increasing in the average number of connections that workers form with unemployed. The network matching rate is a measure of the job contact network productivity: it corresponds to the proportional decrease of unemployment rate associated to a given socialization effort relative to unemployment rate when socialization effort is zero (there are not connections linking up workers). Secondly, we characterize job contact equilibrium networks. Our model predicts that job contact networks are dense and more productive when job destruction rate and vacancy rate are moderate, while they are less productive and segmented into clusters for either high or low labor job destruction and vacancy rate. The equilibrium response of job contact networks to labor market conditions generates different patterns of unemployment rate and network productivity as compared to a model where the job contact network is fixed. We document a variety of new empirical predictions in the paper and we hope that this will stimulate further empirical research in this field. In this introduction, we focus on the equilibrium prediction of our model with regard to the relation between network productivity and unemployment rate and network use and unemployment rate. To illustrate this, we derive for different levels of job destruction rate the equilibrium socialization effort (network use) and the corresponding equilibrium level of network productivity and unemployment rate. Figure 3(a) and figure 3(b) plot network use and network productivity against unemployment rate, respectively. These equilibrium relations are non-monotonic and they are consistent with the patterns observed in the UK labor market (see figures 1-2). The basic model assumes that a worker accesses a direct offer with some exogenous probability. In actual practice, the probability that a worker accesses directly information of a vacant job depends both on his direct search activity and on the number of new jobs that firms are willing to create. In the second part of the paper we examine how each of these two aspects interacts with workers of vacancies, which has to be filled by balls, which are the workers. Each ball reaches a urn, chosen at random. From each urn a ball is extracted and a match between a vacancy and a worker is formed. Because of the randomness in the placement of balls, coordination frictions emerge. We refer to Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) and Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001) for surveys on the matching processes used in the labor market literature, and to Albrecth et al. (2004) for an extensions to the case of multiple applications. 4

6 Equilibrium Socialization Effort Equilibrium Network Productivity Equilibrium Unemployment Rate Equilibrium Unemployment Rate (a) Equilibrium network use and equilibrium unemployment rate (b) Equilibrium network productivity and equilibrium unemployment rate Figure 3: The use of networks and unemployment rate when vacancy rate equals 0.2, cost of socialization equals 0.01, job destruction rate varies from 0 to 1. incentives to invest in connections and how this interplay shapes labor market outcomes. Here, we discuss the effect of allowing workers to choose how much to invest in collecting information personally and how much to invest in their social network. These two decisions are strategically linked: marginal returns from personal search depend on network productivity, which, in turn, depends on the extent to which individuals collect information personally. This interplay leads to multiple equilibria. In one equilibrium personal search is pervasive and job contact networks are small, while in the other equilibrium the reverse holds. We can draw two conclusions from the characterization. First, network productivity is constant across equilibria, and the model predicts that groups with lower costs of acquiring information personally experience a higher network productivity, regardless of their network size 5 Second, even if network productivity is constant across equilibria, the high personal search equilibrium Pareto dominates the low personal search equilibrium and it has a lower unemployment rate. Hence, two distinctive groups, facing identical labor market conditions, may experience a very different unemployment rate, depending on the equilibrium they coordinate. Empirical work has widely documented the persistence of labor market inequalities in 5 This prediction is consistent with the findings of Battu et al. (2008) that immigrant groups with a higher level of country assimilation which might be a proxy for higher hosting country language proficiency have more productive social networks. 5

7 wages, unemployment rates and participation in the labor force across groups such as whites, blacks and hispanic whites that cannot be explained by individual characteristics. 6 Our findings show that the interplay between formal and informal search generates different unemployment outcomes across groups, where these differences are entirely driven by strategic interaction. Summarizing, this paper illustrates the importance of considering the possible endogenous nature of job contact networks to labor market conditions. The relationship between job contact networks and labor market conditions should then be taken seriously in future empirical analysis. 7 It also clear that understanding how social network usage responds to changes in labor market conditions is important for the design of effective policy intervention which try to reduce labor market inequalities. We have focused on labor markets, but the question of how the state of the economy shapes informal institutions is much broader. For example, there is a large empirical work on the effects of social capital on economic growth. Often this work struggles with the fact that social capital is itself an endogenous variable, arising concerns of identification of the models. Referring to this literature, Durlauf (2002, p. F474) noted:...it seems clear that researchers need to provide explicit models of the codetermination of individual outcomes and social capital, so that the identification problems (...) may be rigorously assessed.. Our paper aims to contribute to this line of research providing a tractable model where the interplay among aggregate variables and individual investment in informal organizations is mapped into equilibrium correlations among these variables that cannot be accounted for in a model where informal institutions are taken as given. As we have anticipated early in this introduction, most of the literature on labor market and social networks assumes that social networks are exogenous and are not affected by the labor market. Notable exceptions are Boorman (1975) and Calvó-Armengol (2004). 8 Boorman (1975) is the first 6 Trejo (1997) found that in the US, taking into account individual characteristics, one can explain only one third of the wage gap for Blacks and three quarters for Hispanics. Blackaby et al. (1998) reports similar findings for ethnic minorities in the UK. As for network usage across groups, Holzer (1987), using US data, finds that, while black and whites do not differ significantly in network usage (21.3% and 23.9% respectively), hispanics rely much more on social networks (32.8%). 7 Most of the empirical work on labor market and social networks does not analyze the impact of labor market conditions on the use and productivity of social networks. Some exceptions are Battu et al. (2008), Topa (2001), Bayer et al. (2005) and Elliott (1999). In particular, Elliott (1999) studied the use of information job search channels by less educated urban workers and found that job seekers are more likely to use their social contacts when they live in high poverty neighborhoods. 8 The theory of network formation is a very active field of study. For a survey of this research, see Goyal (2007) and 6

8 to provide a model of communication process among social contacts for job seeking purposes and his focus is on the incentives of workers to form weak versus strong ties. Calvó-Armengol (2004) provides a characterization of stable job contact networks in a two-sided link formation model of the type introduced by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996). Our model is complement to this early work. We do not focus on the specific details of the architecture of equilibrium job contact networks because our aim is to explore how labor market conditions affect social networks usage and productivity taking an explicit account of their feedbacks on workers incentives to form connections. To the best of our knowledge, our paper is the first to analyze these questions systematically. Our work is also related to the literature of labor search pioneered by Diamond (1982). For recent surveys see Pissarides (2000) and Mortensen and Pissarides (1999). We borrow from this literature the idea that search units are chosen optimally to maximize the net returns from search and we apply it to the formation of job contact networks. Our extension on Section 5 combines individual search, which has been the focus of this literature, with informal search in networks. In the conclusion we elaborate on how to extend our framework to a dynamic labor search model. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops the basic model. Section 3 derives the network matching rate. Section 4 characterizes equilibria and discusses the predictions of our model. Section 5 extends the basic model to allow for individual search and endogenous vacancy rate. Section 6 concludes. All proofs are in Appendix B. 2 Model The model has three building blocks: labor market turnover, the formation of job contact networks and information diffusion within the network. There is a large set of risk neutral workers N = {1,..., n}. Initially all workers are employed and earn an exogenous wage that, without loss of generality, is normalized to 1. Labor Market Turnover. Two exogenous parameters govern the labor market turnover. Job destruction. A randomly selected sample of size B = bn > 1 of workers become unemployed, Jackson (2008). Complex random networks have also received large attention in economics, e.g., Galeotti et al. (2007) and Cabrales, Calvó-Armengol and Zenou (2007); for a survey see Vega-Redondo (2007). 7

9 where b (0, 1) Q. We denote by B N the set of workers who lose their job and we call them job seekers. Job opening. A number V = an of new vacancies opens in the market, where a (0, 1] Q. These vacant jobs are distributed to workers in the following way: bv vacancies reach a randomly selected sample of job seekers, while the remaining vacancies reach a randomly selected sample of workers who did not lose their job. Let A N be the set of workers who receive a direct job offer. Under this protocol, nobody receives more than one direct job offer. The set U = B {N \ A} is the set of workers who have lost their job and did not receive a direct offer; note that U = b(1 a)n. The set O = A {N \ B} contains workers who have not lost their job and received a direct offer. We say that a worker i O has a needless offer and we note that there are O = a(1 b)n needless offers. Ex-ante, a representative worker anticipates that with probability b(1 a) he will be unemployed and without a new offer, in which case he will earn an unemployment benefit which, without loss of generality, is normalized to 0. In order to insure themselves against this risk, workers invest in social connections with the view of accessing needless offers. Job Contact Network. We specify the network formation game below. For the moment let s assume that workers are located in an undirected network g. A link between workers i and j is denoted by g ij = 1, while g ij = 0 means that i and j are not linked. The set of all possible undirected networks is G. With some abuse of notation, we denote the set of i s neighbors belonging to V N in network g as N i (V) = {j V \ {i} : g ij = 1}; η i (V) = N i (V) is the number of links that i has with workers belonging to V. Job transmission in the network. We assume that information about jobs flow only from workers with a needless offer to job seekers. Formally, each i O passes the information to one and only one j N i (B), chosen at random. If i has not links with job seekers, i.e., N i (B) is the empty set, the offer is lost. 9 We are assuming that information only flows one-step in the network. In actual 9 We are assuming that a worker with a needless offer passes the information only to one of his social contacts, chosen at random. This assumption greatly simplifies the analysis, but it may be not realistic. The implication of this assumption is that two job seekers both connected with a worker with a needless offer will compete for such offer. Suppose, we relax this assumption and let the worker with a needless offer to give it to both job seekers. Then the two job seekers will have an identical offer and therefore competition for the job will still be present in the hiring process 8

10 practice, we may receive information from social contacts, which in turn they have received from their acquaintances, e.g., Granovetter (1973, 1974). Indirect information flow can be easily accommodated in our framework as we show in Appendix C. Formation of job contact networks. The protocol of network formation follows Cabrales et al. (2007). We consider the following simultaneous network formation game. Each worker i chooses a costly networking effort s i 0; the cost of effort s i is cs i. 10 The set of pure strategies available to worker i is S i = R +. A pure strategy profile is s = (s 1,..., s n ) S = R n +, and s i indicates the strategies of all workers other than worker i. We denote by y(s) = i N s i the aggregate workers socialization effort. For a profile s, we assume that a link between an arbitrary pair of workers i and j forms with probability 11 Pr(g ij = 1 s) = { min { si s j y(s), 1 } if y(s) > 0, 0 otherwise. (1) A profile s generates a multinomial random graph. When workers choose the same level of effort, say s, the induced random graph is binomial, the probability that two workers are connected equals the per-capita socialization effort, min{s/n, 1}, and the average connectivity of the random graph (the expected number of neighbors of a node) is min{s/n, 1}(n 1). 12 There are two complementary interpretations of this process of network formation. The first interpretation is that socialization effort reflects the time that an individual spends in organizations, clubs, conferences, churches, etc. An individual who participates in many organizations has greater chances to meet other people and form connections with them. In turn, these connections may provide valuable information about job opportunities. The second interpretation is that individuals are connected in a pre-existing network. For example, we may think of a group of immigrants leaving (given that one job offer corresponds to one vacancy). 10 All the results we present can be derived for arbitrary cost functions C(s) which are increasing and convex in s. 11 Expression (1) can be derived by requiring three axioms on network formation. These axioms are: one, undirected links, i.e., Pr(g ij = 1 s) = Pr(g ji = 1 s); two, aggregate constant returns to scale, i.e., for all i N, P n j=1 Pr(gij = 1 s) = s i; and three, anonymous link formation, i.e., for all j, l N, Pr(g ji = 1 s)/s j = Pr(g li = 1 s)/s l, for all i N \ {j, l}. See Cabrales et al. (2007) for details. 12 We refer to Erdos and Reny (1959) for a study of binomial random graphs, and to Chung and Lu (2002) for a study of multinomial random graphs. Vega-Redondo (2007) and Jackson (2008) provide a detailed overview of the rapidly growing literature on complex networks. 9

11 in the same neighbor and define the pre-existing network based on their geographical proximity. While the existence of such a link (e.g., leaving in closed proximity) is a necessary condition for information exchange, it is not sufficient: for the information to flow from one individual to another their communication links must be active, which requires effort from both workers. In this case, workers socialization effort determines the strength of each pre-existing link in the community reliability of connections. 13 Utilities and Equilibrium. For a strategy profile s = (s i, s i ), let Ψ i (s) be the probability that worker i B accesses at least one offer from the network, which we shall refer as to i s network matching rate and that we will derive in the next section. The expected utility to a worker i N is: EU i (s i, s i ) = 1 b(1 a)[1 Ψ i (s)] cs i. The last term represents the cost of socialization, while the first part is the probability that worker i will be employed and therefore earning a wage 1. This is the complement of the probability that worker i is a job seeker and neither he accesses a direct offer nor he accesses information from the network. A pure strategy equilibrium is s such that, for all i N, EU i (s i, s i ) EU i (s i, s i ), s i S i. We focus on pure strategy symmetric equilibrium in large labor markets, hereafter equilibrium. A large labor market is a labor market in which n, V, B such that lim n B/n = b and lim n V/n = a Unemployment and network productivity in exogenous networks This section clarifies the role that job contact networks play in matching job seekers with vacant positions and the relation between unemployment rate and network productivity in a model where 13 Following up on this interpretation, we note that in this paper we are assuming that the pre-existing network is complete. It may be interesting to extend the framework to general topology of pre-existing networks. 14 For sake of clarity, we present the analyses for large labor markets. However, our results can be easily extended to an environment with finite and sufficiently large n. 10

12 job contact networks are exogenous. We shall see that the likelihood of a match resulting from social exchange of information is described by a urn-ball matching function of the kind traditionally used in search models. 15 The arguments of this function are the ratio between supply and demand of job information in the network and the average connectivity of the job contact network. Furthermore, as is standard in models with exogenously fixed social networks, we find a negative correlation between unemployment rate and the productivity of job contact networks. There are two ways in which vacant positions and job seekers may be matched: job seekers may receive a direct offer and/or they may access an offer from their social contacts. Select a job seeker i B, who chooses s i. For simplicity, let s assume that s j = s for all j i, for the time being, and let s = (s i, s i ). Since all offers are identical, the probability that worker i finds a job the matching rate is given by: m i (s) = a + (1 a)ψ i (s). We now derive the network matching rate of a job seeker i, i.e., Ψ i (s). With some abuse of notation, let p i = Pr(g ij = 1 s), for all j i, and p = Pr(g jj = 1 s), for all j, j i. The probability that i B has η links with workers who have a needless offer is: Pr (η i (O) = η) = B (η p i, O ), where B( p i, O ) is the binomial distribution, p i is the probability of a success and O is the number of trials. When determining the probability that i B gets a job from one of his acquaintances, we must consider the number of links that an arbitrary i s neighbor with a needless offer, say j N i (O), has with other job seekers, i.e., Pr(η j (B) = ω g ij = 1). This is clearly not the same as the probability that j has η links with job seekers. In fact, we need to take into account that j has already a link 15 The rate at which a vacant job is filled vacancy filling rate is formally derived in Section 5 when we study the incentives of firms to create new jobs. 11

13 with job seeker i. Using Bayes rule, we have that for all ω 1,..., B : 16 Pr (η j (B) = ω g ij = 1) = ω B Pr (η j(b) = ω) B v=0 v B Pr (η j(b) = v) = ω Pr (η j (B) = ω), (2) E[η j (B) s] where E[η j (B) s] = p(nb 1) + p i is the expected number of links that j has with job seekers under profile s. Consider now such a worker j N i (O). If j is connected with ω job seekers (including i), the probability that j passes information to i is 1/ω. So, the probability that j gives information to i is: B Pr(η j (B)) = ω g ij = 1) 1 ω. ω=1 We now observe that the probability that each i s neighbors with a needless offer passes the information to i is independent. Hence, if worker i has η links with workers like j, the probability that i does not hear about a new job is: B 1 Pr(η j (B) = ω g ij = 1) 1 ω ω=1 Thus, the expected probability that i B does not get an offer via the network is: { [ O φ i (s) = Pr(η i (O) = η) 1 η=0 ω=1 η. ] η } B Pr(η j ( B ) = ω g ij = 1) 1. (3) ω Using the binomial identity, B = bn and O = na(1 b), we can rewrite (3) as follows: 1 (1 p i )(1 p) φ i (s) = [1 nb 1 ] na(1 b) p i. (4) p(nb 1) + p i Since p = s 2 / [s(n 1) + s i ] and p i = s i s/ [s(n 1) + s i ], in large labor markets we obtain: lim φ i(s) = e a(1 b) 1 e sb s b s i. n Therefore, when s j = s for all j i and worker i chooses s i, the probability that i B gets at least 16 In general, suppose we have a binomial random graph with n workers. Let p be the probability that an arbitrary link is formed so that z = p(n 1) is the average connectivity of the random graph. Then Pr(η j(n ) = ω g ij = 1) = Pr(g ij =1 η j (g)=ω) Pr(η j (g)=ω) P n 1. Since each link is formed independently with probability p, we have that l=0 Pr(g Pr(gij = ij =1 η j (g)=l) Pr(η j (g)=l) 1 η j(g) = l) = l/(n 1), which implies that Pr(η j(g) = ω g ij = 1) = [ω Pr(η j(g) = ω)]/z. 12

14 one offer via the network is Ψ i (s i, s) = 1 e a(1 b) 1 e sb s b s i. (5) Remark 1 Suppose s j = s for all j i and worker i chooses s i. The network matching rate for worker i is increasing in his own socialization effort while it is decreasing in others socialization effort. This remark captures two simple ideas. The first idea is that connections lead to personal advantages: the greater the connectivity of an individual, the higher is the chance of accessing job information. 17 The second idea is that job seekers compete for job offers in the network: the value of a job seeker s connections decreases with the number of connections formed by other job seekers. The following lemma illustrates the properties of the network matching rate, the matching rate and overall unemployment rate, when workers choose the same socialization effort s. In that case, each job seeker has the same network matching rate, which we denote by Ψ i (s, s) = Ψ(s); we can then write the overall matching rate as m(s) = a + (1 a)ψ(s). Unemployment rate is denoted by u(s) = b(1 a)(1 Ψ(s)). We also define the productivity of the network as the proportional decrease in unemployment relative to a situation in which workers are isolated, i.e., (s) = [u(0) u(s)]/u(0). Lemma 1 Consider a large labor market and suppose that s i = s for all i N. The network matching rate equals the productivity of the network, namely Ψ(s) = (s) = 1 e a(1 b) b (1 e sb ). (6) The network matching rate and the matching rate are increasing and concave in a and in s, while they are decreasing in b. Unemployment rate is decreasing and convex in a and s, while it is increasing in b. To understand how network information transmission alleviates labor market frictions and determines the level of unemployment rate, it is useful to start considering the extreme case in which 17 The idea that social connections create personal advantages is a fundamental premise of the influential work of Granovetter (1973,1974) on job contact networks. A number of recent empirical studies document the role of connections in providing personal advantages in the labor market, e.g., Loury (2006). 13

15 the social network is complete, i.e., s. In this case the network matching rate equals 1 e a(1 b) b. In a complete network the rate at which a match results from the social exchange of information is described by a standard urn-ball matching function of the kind traditionally employed in search models of the labor market. In our context, each job seeker is an urn, and every employed worker with a needless offer places a ball (the job offer) in one randomly selected urn. Not all the needless offers result in a match because some job seekers will receive multiple offers, while others none. These frictions depend negatively on the balls-urns ratio, which is the ratio between the proportion of needless offers the job network supply and the proportion of job seekers the job network demand, i.e., a(1 b)/b. When job contact networks are not complete, the productivity of the network is lower because with positive probability an employed worker with a needless offer only connects with other employed workers, a fact which prevents information to flow. 18 In particular, the probability that a worker with a needless offer has only employed friends is (1 s/n) nb. When n goes to infinity this converges to e sb, where sb is the average number of links that a worker has with job seekers. Thus, the higher is workers average connectivity with job seekers, the more productive is the network in transmitting information. Overall, Lemma 1 shows that unemployment rate and network productivity are negatively correlated: an increase (decrease) in job destruction rate (vacancy rate) decreases network productivity and it increases unemployment rate. This is a prediction which is obtained in all existing models with exogenous social networks. Indeed, for a given network of contacts, changes in labor market conditions which decrease job network supply relatively to job network demand will unambiguously increase unemployment rate and decrease network productivity. As we documented in the introduction these predictions are not consistent with empirical patterns of unemployment and network productivity in the UK labor market. In the next section, we shall see that a key element to explain 18 Note that this inefficiency is not an artifact of our restriction on one-step information flow. Suppose, for example, that information flow two steps. Then a needless offer is lost whenever the owner of this offer is isolated and, otherwise, when he passes the information to an employed worker, who in turn is only connected with other employed workers. 14

16 these empirical correlations is to allow individuals to adjust their network investment to changes in the underlying state of the labor market. 4 Analysis We now study the implication of allowing individuals to choose strategically how much they wish to invest in the job contact network. We first show that the equilibrium level of network investment depends non-monotonically on the level of labor market turnover: job contact equilibrium networks are denser when job-destruction rate and/or vacancy rate are neither too low nor too high. Secondly, we provide examples to illustrate the implication of endogenous job contact networks on the equilibrium relation between unemployment rate and both network productivity and network investment. We also illustrate how connections generate substantial inequalities in the hazard rate of ex-ante identical workers and how the level of these inequalities depend on labor market conditions. We finally show that individuals over-invest in social connections relatively to what is socially desirable. 4.1 Job contact equilibrium networks The following proposition characterizes interior equilibria. 19 Proposition 1 Consider a large labor market. An interior equilibrium s exists if and only if c < ab(1 a)(1 b), and s is the unique solution to: b(1 a) Ψ i s i (s, s ) = c (7) In the unique interior equilibrium, socialization effort balances worker s marginal returns with marginal costs. The marginal returns are the marginal increase in network productivity, weighted by the likelihood that the worker needs the network to find a job, b(1 a). In particular, the marginal 19 We note that there always exists a zero socialization equilibrium, i.e., s i = 0 for all i N. However, analyzing the best response dynamic after a perturbation around the equilibrium, it is possible to show that the zero socialization equilibrium is unstable whenever it coexists with an interior equilibrium. A formal proof of this statement is available upon request to the authors. 15

17 increase in network productivity is: Ψ i (s, s a(1 b) ( ) ) = s i bs 1 e s b e a(1 b) 1 e b s b. This simple characterization allows us to investigate how labor market turnover shapes job contact networks. Are job contact networks more connected when job-destruction rate (respectively, vacancy rate) is high, or rather when job-destruction rate (respectively, vacancy rate) is low? Let us look at the economic forces at work here. An increase in the job destruction rate b makes investment in social networks by individuals more attractive as the labor market becomes more risky (complement effect). On the other hand, by decreasing job network supply and increasing job network demand, an increase in job destruction rate decreases the marginal value of connections, which makes investment in networks less attractive (substitute effect). We now observe that when job-destruction rate is low to begin with, the job contact network is not very connected because the labor market is not very risky. In this case, an increase in job destruction rate decreases the marginal value of connections only slightly, and, overall, the complement effect dominates the substitute effect. As jobs are destroyed at an higher rate, the network becomes denser and this amplifies the substitute effect. Thus, when b is sufficiently high, its increase decreases socialization effort. The following proposition confirms these intuitions. Proposition 2 Consider a large labor market and suppose that c < ab(1 a)(1 b). 1) For every b (0, 1), there exists ā(b) > 0 such that if a < ā(b), then s increases in a, otherwise, it decreases in a. 2) For every a (0, 1), there exists b(a) > 0 such that if b < b(a), then s is increasing in b, otherwise, it decreases in b. In view of Proposition 2, our model predicts that job contact networks are more likely to be segmented into clusters when the labor market turnover is extremely high or low. Indeed, from the theory of random graphs we know that in a Poisson graph when the average connectivity is lower than 1 the resulting network comprises different segregated components. Otherwise, the majority of workers are, almost surely, connected directly or indirectly (the network has a giant component) We refer to Vega-Redondo (2007) and Jackson (2008) for a formal treatment of random graphs. 16

18 A. Low Job Destruction Rate, b=0.2 B. High Job Destruction Rate, b=0.8 B. Moderate Job Destruction Rate, b=0.5 Figure 4: Equilibrium job contact networks and job destruction rate, when a = 0.4, c = 0.03, and n = 100. Here, the average connectivity of the network is s and Proposition 2 suggests that a giant component will emerge when the level of labor market turnover is at intermediate situations. Figure 4 illustrates these findings. Panel A and panel B of figure 4 depict a realization of the equilibrium (random) network for low and high job destruction rates, respectively, while panel C of figure 4 depicts a realization of the equilibrium network in a labor market with moderate job destruction rate. While Proposition 2 provides clear cut results on how labor market conditions shapes job contact networks, it is silent about how labor market conditions affect network productivity and unemployment rate both at the aggregate and at individual level. We now elaborate on these issues. We first observe that the non-monotonic relation between job contact networks and job destruction rate leads to a similar relation between network productivity and job destruction rate. In fact, when job destruction rate is low, job contact networks are sparse which implies that network productivity is low. In this case, an increase in job destruction rate increases the connectivity of the network and, consequently, its productivity also increases. However, as job destruction rate increases further, the network becomes crowded of job seekers. This creates a congestion effect which even- 17

19 Equilibrium Network Productivity Equilibrium Unemployment rate Job Destruction Rate Figure 5: Equilibrium network productivity, unemployment rate and job destruction rate, when vacancy rate equals 0.2, cost of socialization equals 0.01, job destruction rate varies from 0 to 1. tually reduces network productivity. Figure 5 shows how the equilibrium network productivity and the equilibrium unemployment rate are affected by job destruction rate. Our second observation, is that the equilibrium relation between unemployment rate and both socialization effort and network productivity is consistent with the empirical patterns documented in the UK labor market. To see this, we fix vacancy rate to a = 0.2 and costs of socialization to c = For different values of job destruction rate we derive the equilibrium level of network investment and the corresponding network productivity and unemployment rate. Figure 3(a) plots unemployment rate against socialization effort, while figure 3(b) plots unemployment rate against network productivity. We conclude by illustrating how labor market conditions affect inequalities across individuals located in different position in the network. Example: Ex-Post Inequalities across job seekers. Table 6.1 reports the equilibrium productivity of a connection 21, i, and the unemployment rate of job seekers conditioning on the number 21 Formally, this is the proportional decrease in the unemployment rate of a job seeker as we add him and additional connection, i.e., i = [u i (η) u i (η + 1)]/u i (η) 18

20 of connections they have established with workers with a needless offer, u i (s η i (O = η)). The value of a connection increases in a, while it decreases in b, and it changes substantially with changes in the labor market conditions. For example, when a = 0.1 and b = 0.01 an additional connection leads to a reduction in individual s hazard rate of 90 percent, while when b = 0.08 the reduction is of roughly 41 percent. Hence, individuals unemployment rates vary with their network location, and the extent to which networks induce inequalities across workers very much depends on labor market conditions. The role of social networks in creating persisting inequality in a model where the network is exogenous will therefore be generally biased, because it does not take into account how workers react to the incentives to socialization. Table 6.1: Network location and unemployment rate, c = i B u i (s µ i (O) = 0) u i (s µ i (O) = 1) u i (s µ i (O) = 2) u i (s µ i (O) = 3) i a = 0.1 b = b = b = a = 0.25 b = b = b = a = 0.4 b = b = b = u i (s η i (O) = x) is unemployment rate of job seeker with x relevant connections. i is equilibrium value of a connection. 4.2 Job contact efficient networks. Given the salience of job contact networks, it is important to understand their welfare properties. We consider the problem of a social planner who chooses a symmetric profile s [0, ) to maximize the expected utility of a randomly selected worker. The objective function of the social planner is SW (s) = 1 b(1 a)[1 Ψ(s)] cs. We note that increasing socialization effort has two effects on the employment rate of a worker. One the one hand, it increases the expected number of links of a worker, which, in turn, increases his chances of employment. On the other hand, it increases the average connectivity of the neighbors 19

21 of a worker and this decreases his hazard rate. While the social planner balances these two effects, individual workers only take into account the first effect. Since workers do not internalize the negative externalities that their links produce on others, the job contact network in the interior equilibrium is over connected relatively to what is socially desirable. The following proposition formalizes these intuitions. Proposition 3 Consider a large labor market and let s be the solution of the planner problem. If c ab(1 a)(1 b), then s = 0. Otherwise, s < s and it is the unique solution to ab(1 a)(1 b)e sb [1 Ψ( s)] = c. (8) 5 Extensions The basic model assumes that a worker accesses a direct job offer with some exogenous probability. In actual practice, the probability that a worker accesses direct information of a vacant job depends both on his search activity and on the number of vacant jobs that firms are willing to open. In this section we examine how these two aspects interact with workers incentives to built up a job contact network and how this interplay shapes labor market outcomes. 5.1 Job search and job contact networks Workers generally use different search methods in their attempt to obtain information about jobs, see e.g. Holzer (1987), Osberg (1993), Elliott (1999) and Wabha and Zenou (2005). The empirical and theoretical literature on social networks in labor markets often focuses on information flow in the network, and it ignores the process under which workers become aware of offers directly. Here, we extend the basic model by relating the probability that a worker accesses a direct offer to his search intensity. Personal search effort and socialization effort are strategically related because the information that is available in the network the proportion of needless offers depends on the extend to which workers collect information personally In a recent paper, Galeotti and Goyal (2008) study a model where individuals can search personally and form links to access information that others have acquired personally. In their model individuals invest in specific links, while we assume that investments in links are not individual-specific. Most importantly, their paper focuses on explaining the 20

22 The formation of the network and the information diffusion process in the network follow the rules described in the basic model. However, now each worker i chooses not only a socialization effort s i, but also a costly search effort a i [0, 1]. If worker i exerts effort a i, he accesses a direct offer with probability a i and incurs a cost αa i, α > 0. A strategy profile is now a socialization effort s and a profile of search effort a [0, 1] n. Given a profile (s, a) the probability that worker i accesses at least one information via the network is Ψ i (s, a i ). The network matching rate of worker i depends only on the search effort of other workers. Furthermore, when s j = s for all j N and a j = a for all j i, then Ψ i (s, a i ) is the same as the network matching rate derived in Section 3, i.e., expression Ψ i (s i, s, a) is given by (5). The expected utility to worker i under a profile (s, a) is EU i (s, a) = 1 b(1 a i )[1 Ψ i (s i, s, a i )] αa i cs i. The following proposition characterizes interior equilibria. We shall restrict attention to the case in which α < b, where we recall that b is the job destruction rate. 23 Proposition 4 Consider a large labor market and suppose α < b. For every b [0, 1], there exists α(b) > 0 and c(b, α) > 0 such that an interior equilibrium exists if and only if α α(b) and c c(b, α). An interior equilibrium (s, a ) solves b[1 Ψ(s, s, a )] = α (9) b(1 a) Ψ i s i (s, s, a ) = c (10) When c = c(b, α) there exists only one interior equilibrium, otherwise there exist two interior equilibria, (s H, a L ) and (s L, a H ), where s H > s L and a H > a L. Equilibrium condition (9) equates marginal costs of search effort with its marginal returns. Marginal returns from personal search decrease with the network matching rate. Hence, effort to colspecialization in information acquisition and social communication, while our focus is on how labor market conditions affect socialization effort and personal search and how this interplay affects market outcomes. 23 Two remarks are in order. First, if α > b there exists a unique equilibrium: workers do not search and do not socialize. Second, when α < b there exists only one corner equilibrium: s i = 0 and a i = 1, for all i N. 21

23 lect information personally and socialization effort are strategic substitutes. Equilibrium condition (10) is analogous to equilibrium condition (7). The strategic relation between individual search effort and socialization effort leads to multiple equilibria. Equilibrium (s H, a L ) describes a labor market where workers search personally with low intensity while the social network is very dense. Low search effort can be justified only if network productivity is sufficiently high. Since low search effort induces a low level of job network supply, this is attainable only if job contact networks are very dense. The reverse holds in the equilibrium (s L, a H ). Here, workers are highly engaged in collecting information personally, which is consistent with equilibrium only if the likelihood of forming connections is low, i.e., socialization effort is low. Equilibrium condition (9) in Proposition 4 implies that network matching rate is constant across the two interior equilibria and it decreases with the costs of collecting information personally. So, our model predicts that groups with lower costs of collecting information personally have also more productive social networks. This is in line with empirical findings of Battu et al. (2008) which show that ethnic minority groups with a higher level of country assimilation (which could be related to lower language proficiency or lower knowledge of the functioning of local labor markets) have more productive social networks. Even if network productivity is constant across equilibria, the two equilibria lead to a different unemployment rate and are Pareto ranked. In particular, the equilibrium with high individual search activity and small job contact networks has a lower unemployment rate and it Pareto dominates the equilibrium with low individual search and dense networks. Corollary 1 Consider the interior equilibria (s H, a L ) and (s L, a H ) described in Proposition 4. 1.) (s L, a H ) Pareto dominates (s H, a L ), 2.) network matching rate is the same in the two equilibria and 3.) unemployment rate under (s L, a H ) is lower than unemployment rate under (s H, a L ). Hence, two groups of individuals facing identical labor market conditions may experience very different labor market outcomes depending on the equilibrium they coordinate. This provides a rationale for labor market inequalities across groups which is entirely driven by strategic interaction. 22

Endogenous Job Contact Networks

Endogenous Job Contact Networks 8 Endogenous Job Contact Networks Andrea Galeotti Department of Economics University of Essex Luca Paolo Merlino ECARES Université Libre de Bruxelles No. 2010-14 April 2010 ISER Working Paper Series www.iser.essex.ac.uk

More information

A Markov Model of Referral Based Hiring and Workplace Segregation

A Markov Model of Referral Based Hiring and Workplace Segregation A Markov Model of Referral Based Hiring and Workplace Segregation Troy Tassier Department of Economics Fordham University and Center for the Study of Complex Systems University of Michigan e-mail: ttassier@umich.edu

More information

The Role of Cultural Leaders in the Transmission of Preferences

The Role of Cultural Leaders in the Transmission of Preferences The Role of Cultural Leaders in the Transmission of Preferences Thierry Verdier Yves Zenou August 25, 2015 Abstract This paper studies the population dynamics of preference traits in a model of intergenerational

More information

The implications of labor market network for business cycles

The implications of labor market network for business cycles Department of Economics Working Paper Series 401 Sunset Avenue Windsor, Ontario, Canada N9B 3P4 Administrator of Working Paper Series: Christian Trudeau Contact: trudeauc@uwindsor.ca The implications of

More information

ON THE EFFICIENCY OF JOB SEARCH WITH SOCIAL NETWORKS

ON THE EFFICIENCY OF JOB SEARCH WITH SOCIAL NETWORKS ON THE EFFICIENCY OF JOB SEARCH WITH SOCIAL NETWORKS PIERRE CAHUC Ecole Polytechnique FRANÇOIS FONTAINE Université de Strasbourg and IZA Abstract This paper provides a simple matching model in which unemployed

More information

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework ARNAUD CHÉRON (GAINS-TEPP, UNIVERSITY OF LE MANS) Attribution Non commercial - No Derivative Work : http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.0/fr/

More information

Learning by Observing

Learning by Observing Working Papers in Economics Learning by Observing Efe Postalcı, zmir University of Economics Working Paper #10/07 December 2010 Izmir University of Economics Department of Economics Sakarya Cad. No:156

More information

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe Ryosuke Okazawa April 21, 2012 A. Multiple Pooling Equilibria In Section 3, although

More information

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki Department of Economics, University of Crete, Gallos University Campus, Rethymnon 74100, Greece

More information

Section 1: Introduction

Section 1: Introduction Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design (1991) By Bengt Holmstrom and Paul Milgrom Presented by Group von Neumann Morgenstern Anita Chen, Salama Freed,

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Beveridge Curve. IZA DP No Eran Yashiv. December 2006 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2479 The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor The Beveridge Curve Eran Yashiv Tel Aviv

More information

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK. University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics Field Exam January 2017 Labor Economics There are three parts of the exam. Please answer all three parts. You should plan to spend about one hour

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

With a Little Help from My Friends? Quality of Social Networks, Job Finding Rates and Job Match Quality

With a Little Help from My Friends? Quality of Social Networks, Job Finding Rates and Job Match Quality With a Little Help from My Friends? Quality of Social Networks, Job Finding Rates and Job Match Quality Lorenzo Cappellari Università Cattolica Milano Konstantinos Tatsiramos University of Leicester and

More information

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011 Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring 2011 Honors General Exam April 6, 2011 The exam has three sections: microeconomics (Questions 1 3), macroeconomics (Questions 4 6), and econometrics

More information

The Weakness of Weak Ties in Referrals: An Obstacle for the Upwardly Mobile Black Men in the Private Sector

The Weakness of Weak Ties in Referrals: An Obstacle for the Upwardly Mobile Black Men in the Private Sector The Weakness of Weak Ties in Referrals: An Obstacle for the Upwardly Mobile Black Men in the Private Sector Shahir Safi November 3, 207 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and Barcelona GSE Abstract I build

More information

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 6935 Efficiency in a Search and Matching Economy with a Competitive Informal Sector Olivier Charlot Franck Malherbet Mustafa Ulus October 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Consumer Referral in a Small World Network

Consumer Referral in a Small World Network Consumer Referral in a Small World Network Tackseung Jun 1 Beom Jun Kim 2 Jeong-Yoo Kim 3 August 8, 2004 1 Department of Economics, Kyung Hee University, 1 Hoegidong, Dongdaemunku, Seoul, 130-701, Korea.

More information

Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications

Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications James Albrecht Department of Economics Georgetown University Washington, D.C. 20057 Susan Vroman Department of Economics Georgetown University Washington,

More information

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Economics Working Paper Series 2016/012 Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Kwok Tong Soo The Department of Economics Lancaster University Management School Lancaster LA1 4YX UK Authors All

More information

Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets

Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets Andreas Kopp a,1 a Hamburg Institute of International Economics Neuer Jungfernstieg 21 20347 Hamburg Germany Abstract The paper seeks an explanation for

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Incentives in Supply Function Equilibrium

Incentives in Supply Function Equilibrium Discussion Paper No. 2014-38 September 29, 2014 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2014-38 Please cite the corresponding Journal Article at http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2015-5

More information

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis ECONOMIC POLICY PAPER 16-02 JANUARY 2016 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Many economists believe that prices are sticky they adjust slowly. This stickiness, they suggest, means that changes in the money supply have

More information

Personal Contacts and Earnings: It is who you know! Mortensen and Vishwanath (1994)

Personal Contacts and Earnings: It is who you know! Mortensen and Vishwanath (1994) Personal Contacts and Earnings: It is who you know! Mortensen and Vishwanath (1994) Group Hicks Dena, Marjorie, Sabina, Shehryar It s not what you know, it s who you know! A postdoctoral student in biology

More information

Social Interactions and the Labor Market *

Social Interactions and the Labor Market * Social Interactions and the Labor Market * Yves Zenou To better understand the way social networks operate in the labor market, we propose two simple models where individuals help each other finding a

More information

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Paolo Fulghieri University of North Carolina Merih Sevilir University of North Carolina Abstract This paper studies mergers between competing firms and shows

More information

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup Theory Appendix In this appendix, we provide a stylized model based on our empirical setting to analyze the effect of competition on author behavior. The general idea is that in a market with imperfect

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Trade, Development and Growth June 2013 For students electing APEC 8702 and APEC 8703 option Instructions * Identify yourself by your

More information

Network Search: Climbing the Job Ladder Faster

Network Search: Climbing the Job Ladder Faster Network Search: Climbing the Job Ladder Faster Marcelo Arbex Dennis O Dea David Wiczer February 15, 2018 (Preliminary and incomplete) Abstract We introduce an irregular network structure into a model of

More information

Mismatch Unemployment Across Industries in Spain

Mismatch Unemployment Across Industries in Spain Mismatch Unemployment Across Industries in Spain Jesús Bueren Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract I measure the contribution of mismatch across industries to the rise in Spanish unemployment between 2006

More information

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Ricardo Cavalcanti Getulio Vargas Foundation Ed Nosal Cleveland Fed November 006 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We describe counterfeiting activity

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

The Role of. Reform Models. 25 CESifo DICE Report 1/2015 (March)

The Role of. Reform Models. 25 CESifo DICE Report 1/2015 (March) The Role of Coworker-based Networks in the Labour Market Albrecht Glitz 1 Introduction In 1974, Mark Granovetter published his highly influential monograph Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers

More information

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit by Robin Boadway, Queen s University, Canada Zhen Song, Central University of Finance and Economics, China Jean-François Tremblay,

More information

Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI)

Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI) Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI) Stockholm University WORKING PAPER 4/2017 LABOUR DEMAND AND REAL WAGES by Ante Farm Labour Demand and Real Wages * Ante Farm Swedish Institute for Social Research

More information

Social Network Structure, Segregation, and Equality in a Labor Market with Referral Hiring

Social Network Structure, Segregation, and Equality in a Labor Market with Referral Hiring Social Network Structure, Segregation, and Equality in a Labor Market with Referral Hiring Troy Tassier Department of Economics, Fordham University tassier@fordham.edu Filippo Menczer School of Informatics,

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

. Journal of Policy Modelling ELSEVIER Science Publishing Co AUTHORS MANUSCRIPT TRANSMITTAL FORM

. Journal of Policy Modelling ELSEVIER Science Publishing Co AUTHORS MANUSCRIPT TRANSMITTAL FORM . Journal of Policy Modelling ELSEVIER Science Publishing Co AUTHORS MANUSCRIPT TRANSMITTAL FORM Name of Journal: Journal of Policy Models Article Title: Employment and Wage Formation in a Growth Model

More information

Strategic Wage Setting and Coordination Frictions with Multiple Job Applications

Strategic Wage Setting and Coordination Frictions with Multiple Job Applications Strategic Wage Setting and Coordination Frictions with Multiple Job Applications Pieter A. Gautier Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute José L. Moraga-González University of Groningen and

More information

Wage Posting Without Full Commitment

Wage Posting Without Full Commitment The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 2008-01 Wage Posting Without Full Commitment Matthew Doyle and Jacob Wong Wage Posting Without Full Commitment Matthew Doyle The University

More information

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion Notes and Comments on Search Costs and Equilibrium Price Dispersion Moshe Barach Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion By Michael R. Baye, John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten Various models of

More information

1 Competitive Equilibrium

1 Competitive Equilibrium 1 Competitive Equilibrium Each household and each firm in the economy act independently from each other, seeking their own interest, and taking as given the fact that other agents will also seek their

More information

Hiring Through Referrals in Experimental Markets with Adverse Selection

Hiring Through Referrals in Experimental Markets with Adverse Selection Hiring Through Referrals in Experimental Markets with Adverse Selection Aurelie Dariel Arno Riedl Simon Siegenthaler May 31, 2018 Abstract It is well-known that informational asymmetries can prevent markets

More information

Globalization and Social Networks

Globalization and Social Networks Globalization and Social Networks Georg Durnecker University of Mannheim Fernando Vega-Redondo European University Institute September 14, 2012 Duernecker & Vega-R. (Mannheim & EUI) Globalization and Social

More information

Tetsuya Nakajima. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University. Hideki Nakamura. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University

Tetsuya Nakajima. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University. Hideki Nakamura. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University Economic Development under Wage Rigidity at the Start of Industrialization: A Note Tetsuya Nakajima Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University Hideki Nakamura Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University

More information

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing TI 2004-068/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing Maarten C.W. Janssen José Luis Moraga-González* Matthijs R. Wildenbeest Faculty of Economics,

More information

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand WP-2009-001 Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand Rupayan Pal Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai January 2009 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2009-001.pdf

More information

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure Employer Discrimination and Market Structure Josh Ederington Jenny Minier Jeremy Sandford Kenneth R. Troske August 29 Abstract We extend Gary Becker s theory, that competitive forces will drive discriminating

More information

Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy

Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy Sybille Lehwald July, 22 2011 1 Motivation Krugman (1980) importance of intra-industry trade no firm goes out of business

More information

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity No 10. Chapter 11 Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity Introduction We earlier described the Keynesian interpretation of the IS-LM AS-AD Model The Keynesian model assumes that there exists a horizontal

More information

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as Economists typically assume that firms or a firm s owners try to maximize their profit. et R be revenues of the firm, and C be the cost of production, then a firm s profit can be represented as follows,

More information

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Essi Eerola RUESG, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland Niku Määttänen Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain and The Research Institute

More information

The Role of Occupational Structure in Changes of Permanent and Transitory Variance

The Role of Occupational Structure in Changes of Permanent and Transitory Variance The Role of Occupational Structure in Changes of Permanent and Transitory Variance Anna Blank Boston College March 16, 2011 Abstract Numerous papers study the empirical dynamics of wages inequality by

More information

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp 1 Introduction Investments in energy efficiency are seen by many as a low-cost or even no-cost measure to curb greenhouse gas emissions, slow down growth in energy demand and increase energy security.

More information

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION BRENT HUETH AND TIGRAN MELKONYAN Abstract. This papers analyzes efficient regulatory design of a polluting firm who has two kinds

More information

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay I. Theoretical Model In this paper, I define skill-biased technological change as the technological shock that began in the 1970s with

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 8 - Labor markets: The search and matching model Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Last week an overview of some labor market facts a brief reminder of dynamic programming

More information

An Alternative to Signaling: Directed Search and Substitution

An Alternative to Signaling: Directed Search and Substitution An Alternative to Signaling: Directed Search and Substitution Matthew Levy and Balázs Szentes November 23, 2015 Abstract This paper analyzes a labor market, where (i) workers can acquire an observable

More information

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Indrani Roy Chowdhury* and Sandwip K. Das** Abstract We provide a new formulation of the Porter hypothesis that we feel is in the spirit of the hypothesis. Under this

More information

Bargaining with Commitment between Workers and Large Firms

Bargaining with Commitment between Workers and Large Firms Bargaining with Commitment between Workers and Large Firms William B. Hawkins University of Rochester This version: February 10, 2011 First version: March 2010 Abstract I study bargaining between workers

More information

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Alex John London Carnegie Mellon University Kevin J.S. Zollman Carnegie Mellon

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

MIGRATION AND POLLUTION *

MIGRATION AND POLLUTION * IGRTION ND POLLUTION * Raghbendra Jha, ustralian National University and John Whalley, University of Western Ontario and NBER January 2003 bstract We explore the links between migration of labour and location

More information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Tracy Lewis Duke University Li, Hao University of British Columbia Matching Problems in Chicago 2012 Lewis and Li Endogenous Matching 1 Introduction: Motivation

More information

Symmetric Information Benchmark Begin by setting up a comparison situation, where there is no information asymmetry. Notation:

Symmetric Information Benchmark Begin by setting up a comparison situation, where there is no information asymmetry. Notation: ECO 37 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 009 Notes for Lectures 7. Job Market Signaling In this market, the potential employee s innate skill or productive capability on the job matters to an employer

More information

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1 Review of Economics & Finance Submitted on 30/03/2015 Article ID: 1923-7529-2015-04-78-14 Fang Wei Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1 Dr. Fang Wei

More information

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I)

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I) The 2x2 Exchange Economy Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I) Road Map for Chapter 3 Pareto Efficiency Allocation (PEA) Cannot make one better off without hurting others Walrasian (Price-taking)

More information

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I)

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I) The 2x2 Exchange Economy Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I) Road Map for Chapter 3 Pareto Efficiency Cannot make one better off without hurting others Walrasian (Price-taking) Equilibrium

More information

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account Index: 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account... 8. Introduction... 8. The deterministic case...3 8.3 Optimal consumption under uncertainty...4

More information

CS 486/686 Lecture 17 2-Player Normal-Form Games 1. Determine dominant-strategy equilibria of a 2-player normal form game.

CS 486/686 Lecture 17 2-Player Normal-Form Games 1. Determine dominant-strategy equilibria of a 2-player normal form game. CS 486/686 Lecture 17 2-Player Normal-Form Games 1 Learning goals: By the end of the lecture, you should be able to Determine dominant-strategy equilibria of a 2-player normal form game. Determine pure-strategy

More information

SEQUENTIAL DECISIONS IN THE COLLEGE ADMISSIONS PROBLEM. Jose Alcalde and Antonio Romero-Medina *

SEQUENTIAL DECISIONS IN THE COLLEGE ADMISSIONS PROBLEM. Jose Alcalde and Antonio Romero-Medina * Working Paper 99-14 Economics Series 08 February 1999 Departamento de Economia Universidad Carlos ITI de Madrid CalIe Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (341) 624-98-75 SEQUENTIAL DECISIONS IN THE COLLEGE

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today s Plan 1 2 3 4 Revisiting New Trade Theory with firm heterogeneity Multiple

More information

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market Summary The discussion in Chapter 11 of the complex relationship between pay and productivity drew on a wide array of material from Chapters 5,

More information

Two Blades of the Scissors Supply, Demand and Changing Industry Structures

Two Blades of the Scissors Supply, Demand and Changing Industry Structures 1 Ronald Schettkat November 2004 Two Blades of the Scissors Supply, Demand and Changing Industry Structures 6.1 Potential and Actual Growth: Relaxing the Full-Employment Assumption 6.2 Summary 6.1 Potential

More information

Targeted vs. Collective Information Sharing in Networks

Targeted vs. Collective Information Sharing in Networks Targeted vs. Collective Information Sharing in Networks Alexey Kushnir Alexandru Nichifor First draft: October 11, 2013 This version: February 14, 2014 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We introduce

More information

Spatial versus Social Mismatch

Spatial versus Social Mismatch Spatial versus Social Mismatch Yves Zenou May 5, 2012 (Revised September 6, 2012) Abstract: The aim of this paper is to provide a new mechanism based on social interactions explaining why distance to jobs

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L3: The labour market

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L3: The labour market Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201 L3: The labour market Anna Seim Department of Economics, Stockholm University Spring 2017 1 / 58 Contents and literature Labour market facts and developments. Labour

More information

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION BACHELOR OF BUSINESS Sample FINAL EXAMINATION Subject Code : ECO201 Subject Name : LABOUR ECONOMICS This examination carries 50% of the total assessment for this subject. Examiner(s) Moderator(s) Joyce

More information

The Assignment of Workers to Jobs In an Economy with Coordination Frictions

The Assignment of Workers to Jobs In an Economy with Coordination Frictions The Assignment of Workers to Jobs In an Economy with Coordination Frictions Robert Shimer Department of Economics University of Chicago shimer@uchicago.edu First Version: September 7, 2001 Current Version:

More information

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Learning Objectives: Students should learn to:. The student will understand the ideas of strategic interdependence and reasoning strategically and be able

More information

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information.

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information. Part I Money IN PART I we develop and learn to work with our most basic model of money, applying it to the study of fiat and commodity monies, inflation, and international monetary systems. In studying

More information

Culture, Community and Segregation

Culture, Community and Segregation Culture, Community and Segregation Bryony Reich January 27, 2013 Abstract We use economic theory to examine the possible outcomes facing a culturally diverse population. We ask which cultures emerge and

More information

A Theory of Consumer Referral

A Theory of Consumer Referral A Theory of Consumer Referral Tackseung Jun Kyung Hee University Jeong-Yoo Kim Kyung Hee University March 13, 2004 Abstract In this paper, we consider the network as an alternative communication channel

More information

Why Are Similar Workers Paid Differently? The Role of Social Networks

Why Are Similar Workers Paid Differently? The Role of Social Networks DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1786 Why Are Similar Workers Paid Differently? The Role of Social Networks François Fontaine September 2005 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intermediate Macroeconomics Intermediate Macroeconomics Lecture 6 - Capital Utilisation and Unemployment Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2011 October 12 Preview of today s lecture Last week: baseline business cycle model in response

More information

Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany

Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany Social Networks, Job Search Methods and Reservation Wages: Evidence for Germany Marco Caliendo Ricarda Schmidl Arne Uhlendorff Working Paper February 1, 2010 Abstract In this paper we analyze the relationship

More information

Quasi-Fixed Labor Costs and Their Effects on Demand

Quasi-Fixed Labor Costs and Their Effects on Demand CHAPTER 5 Quasi-Fixed Labor Costs and Their Effects on Demand In addition to the questions below, solve the following end of chapter problems: Review questions 1,3-6, 8; Problems 1-3 1. Suppose that workers

More information

Burdett-Mortensen Model of On-the-Job Search with Two Sectors

Burdett-Mortensen Model of On-the-Job Search with Two Sectors Burdett-Mortensen Model of On-the-Job Search with Two Sectors Florian Hoffmann (florian.hoffmann@ubc.ca) Vancouver School of Economics 997 1873 East Mall, Vancouver, BC Canada, V6T 1Z1 Shouyong Shi (sus67@psu.edu)

More information

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services.

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services. Chapter 3 Labour Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-2 Introduction Firms hire workers because consumers want to

More information

Economic models of innovation, growth and development

Economic models of innovation, growth and development Economic models of innovation, growth and development TIK, UiO 2016 Bart Verspagen UNU-MERIT, Maastricht verspagen@merit.unu.edu Some questions on economic growth GDP pc in Japan in 1900 was 1180, in Argentina

More information

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence Mariya Neycheva * 1. Introduction The economics of growth is one of the most popular fields of study in both theoretical and empirical

More information

The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014

The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014 The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014 David Jaume June 2017 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract Most developing countries invest increasing shares of

More information

Social Capital in the Labor Market

Social Capital in the Labor Market Ted Mouw tedmouw@email.unc.edu Department of Sociology University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill October 24, 2007 Outline Overview My research The basic problem Example from ARS paper Background/Theory

More information

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012. 1 A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET April 2012 Bralind Kiri bralind.kiri@gmail.com PhD Student, Department of Economic Theory and

More information

INFORMATION EXCHANGE IN PREDICTION MARKETS: HOW SOCIAL NETWORKS PROMOTE FORECAST EFFICIENCY

INFORMATION EXCHANGE IN PREDICTION MARKETS: HOW SOCIAL NETWORKS PROMOTE FORECAST EFFICIENCY INFORMATION EXCHANGE IN PREDICTION MARKETS: HOW SOCIAL NETWORKS PROMOTE FORECAST EFFICIENCY Completed Research Paper Liangfei Qiu University of Texas at Austin Austin, Texas 78712 liangfeiqiu@utexas.edu

More information

Sponsored Search Markets

Sponsored Search Markets COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Sponsored Search Markets Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Sponsored Search Markets

More information