Mergers and acquisitions spark ongoing controversy in the economics profession

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Mergers and acquisitions spark ongoing controversy in the economics profession"

Transcription

1 Economic Perspectives Volume 1, Number 2 Fall 1987 Pages 3 12 Symposium on Mergers and Antitrust Steven C. Salop Mergers and acquisitions spark ongoing controversy in the economics profession and in society at large. This is not surprising. Billion dollar deals not only involve a great deal of money, but they often raise economic issues implicating capital and labor markets as well as the markets for the products sold by the merger partners. Because of this, merger enforcement is probably the most widely known area of antitrust. However, economists who do not specialize in industrial organization generally have little understanding of the type of competitive analysis that forms the basis for merger enforcement by the antitrust authorities and the courts. This is unfortunate. Not only does this analysis have important social implications, but when formulated rigorously, the analytic model used in antitrust represents a simple, yet quite sophisticated, microeconomic model of competition. In the past ten years, economics and economists have become far more important in antitrust. The so-called "Chicago school" of antitrust has provided the intellectual rationale for a considerable loosening of antitrust law. Its intellectual leaders, for example, Robert Bork, Richard Posner, and Frank Easterbrook, have become judges and soon may ascend to (or already have joined) the Supreme Court. Economists like James Miller and George Douglas have become Federal Trade Commissioners, and the staff economists at the Commission and the Department of Justice have gained considerable influence. Steven C. Salop is Professor of Economics at the Georgetown University Law Center, Washington, D.C.

2 4 Economic Perspectives The Journal of Economic Perspectives organized this symposium to provide economists who do not specialize in industrial organization and policy makers now considering reform proposals with a better sense of the type of competitive analysis carried out in evaluating mergers and the controversies involved in proposals to reform merger law. The Journal asked three mainstream industrial organization economists to comment on both current merger enforcement and merger reform proposals: Lawrence White, Franklin Fisher, and Richard Schmalensee. Lawrence White was one of the authors of the 1982 Department of Justice Merger Guidelines that now provide the basic analytic framework for mergers, if not all of antitrust regulation. White was the Federal Trade Commission's expert economist in the recent litigation that blocked the proposed acquisition of Dr Pepper by Coca-Cola. He is currently a board member of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board. Franklin Fisher is a former Clark Award recipient in econometrics who now specializes in industrial organization. In antitrust, he is probably best known for his spirited defense of IBM in the various antitrust cases brought against it. Richard Schmalensee has written extensively about industrial organization and antitrust, including important papers on advertising, brand reputation and market power. He has been an expert economist in a number of cases, including the Federal Trade Commission's case against Kellogg and other major cereal companies. U.S. Merger Policy United States merger policy is mainly carried out by the Department of Justice (DOJ) and Federal Trade Commission (FTC). Under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Pre- Merger Notification Act, an acquiring firm with assets or sales in excess of $100 million must report all proposed acquisitions of assets valued in excess of $15 million to these agencies. A merger cannot be consummated until one of the agencies has evaluated its likely effects on competition. If a problem is found, the merging parties can either withdraw the proposal, negotiate a method of alleviating the agency's concern (for example, by selling off a plant or an entire division), or litigate the acquisition's legality. Very few cases are litigated. Between 1982 and 1986, the FTC and DOJ brought enforcement actions against only 56 mergers out of the more than 7700 reported. 1 Mergers are evaluated under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. A merger is considered illegal if it "substantially decreases competition or tends to create a monopoly." Thus, Section 7 is concerned with market power in its incipiency. This "incipiency standard" is controversial because it could be, and in the past was, interpreted very broadly. For example, in the 1962 Brown Shoe case, the government blocked a merger 1 See Antitrust & Trade Regulation Reporter, March 5, 1987, vol. 52, page 452. Private parties (customers, suppliers or competitors) and states also can sue to block a proposed merger. Because of the federal government's primary role in the process, however, private and state litigation generally has little significance. However, more cases are being brought by private parties, often successfully, since the government has so relaxed its merger enforcement.

3 Salop 5 between Brown Shoe and Kinney Shoe. Brown and Kinney were ranked third and eighth in the industry. Although the firms' market shares were low, the Supreme Court was concerned that, "if a merger achieving 5% control were now approved, we might be required to approve future merger efforts by Brown's competitors seeking similar market shares. The oligopoly Congress sought to avoid would then be furthered and it would be difficult to dissolve the combinations previously approved." Both Brown and Kinney were retailers as well as manufacturers. The Court also was concerned about the trend to both horizontal consolidation and vertical integration and treated the potential efficiency benefits of the merger as a rationale for blocking it. Four years later in the Von's Grocery case, the Supreme Court held illegal the merger of Von's Grocery and Shopping Bag, the third and sixth largest supermarket chains in the Los Angeles area. The firms had a combined market share of only 7.5 percent. Yet the Court was concerned with the "trend towards concentration" in the market, as indicated by the fact that the number of owners of single ("mom and pop") stores fell from approximately 5300 in 1950 to 3600 in In Justice Stewart's dissent, in which he concluded that there were no substantial entry barriers into grocery retailing, he wrote: "The sole consistency that I can find is that in litigation under Section 7, the Government always wins." Reflecting this concern about incipient market power, the 1968 Merger Guidelines stated the intention of the Department of Justice to attack mergers in concentrated markets where the combined share of the parties was as low as 8 percent. These market share standards were controversial even then. The trend cited by Justice Stewart was reversed beginning with the 1974 General Dynamics case. 2 In that decision, in permitting the merger, the Court opened the door to detailed analysis of variables other than concentration and market shares. In 1982, the Department of Justice issued new Merger Guidelines to reflect the current state of the law. However, the 1982 Guidelines made a more fundamental contribution than simply updating the market share standards. 3 They also set out a unified conceptual framework for analyzing the competitive effects of horizontal mergers, a framework that reflects industrial organization economics more closely. While important aspects of the Guidelines are quite controversial among economists, most economists agree that the basic framework is an exceedingly useful analytical tool, not just for merger policy, but for much of industrial organization economics. 4 2 This case involved the merger of two coal companies, one of which had already contractually committed itself to sell the bulk of its reserves. The coal companies argued that calculating market shares and concentration without taking into account the fact that most of the reserves already were committed gave a misleading impression of the power of the two firms. The Supreme Court agreed, holding that market share and concentration statistics may be rebutted with other evidence. 3 The Guidelines were revised again in 1984, although not dramatically. Some of the most significant revisions are discussed later in this introduction. 4 The Department of Justice's far more controversial Vertical Merger Guidelines, issued at the same time, are not discussed in the Symposium. For a recent critique of these standards, see Krattenmaker, Thomas, and Steven C. Salop, "Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Gain Power over Price," Yale Law Journal, December 1986, 96,

4 6 Economic Perspectives The Merger Guidelines only reflect Department of Justice enforcement policy, not the law itself. They do not represent legal precedent, even though they do influence courts. The Reagan Administration has proposed amending the Clayton Act to alter substantive merger law. The amendment would have two main effects. First, it would require analysis of variables other than concentration, notably entry barriers and efficiency benefits. This change is intended to mandate by statute the basic approach taken in the Merger Guidelines. Second, the amendment would eliminate the "incipiency standard" of illegality by deleting the "tend to create a monopoly" language of Section 7 of the Clayton Act. This change would raise the evidentiary standard for proving market power above the levels of Von's Grocery and Brown Shoe. The amendment is apparently also intended to mandate enforcement at the current or at a somewhat more permissive level. Perhaps most significantly, it is intended to permit potential cost savings to justify increases in market power. The purpose of this symposium is to evaluate current merger policy and reform proposals and to set out economists' "best practice" of merger evaluation. To this end, the symposium participants analyze the Department of Justice Guidelines and the proposals for reforming them. The symposium also highlights the issues on which policy makers should focus in judging reform proposals. Basic Merger Analysis The Department of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines are not concerned with aggregate industrial concentration as measured, for example, by the share of the economy's assets owned by the largest 500 corporations. They focus only on the likelihood that a merger may create or increase market power: that is, the ability to set price above the competitive level. The Guidelines are built on the premise that collusion, either in the form of a "hotel room" conspiracy or tacit coordination, is less likely to succeed in less concentrated markets, in markets where few entry barriers exist, and in markets where competitive price cuts are more difficult for rivals to detect rapidly. The Guidelines are premised on the recognition that significant cost savings can flow from mergers and acquisitions, and enforcement standards governing concentration and ease of entry should be set accordingly. The degree to which potential cost savings should count as an offset and therefore permit mergers that create or increase market power is more controversial. To evaluate the possible competitive impact of a horizontal merger, the Guidelines set out a five-part protocol. First, a relevant market is determined for evaluating competitive effects. Second, concentration in the market is calculated, using the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index (HHI). The HHI is defined as the sum of squared market shares of the firms in the market, where market shares are treated as whole numbers, not fractions. The possible values for the HHI range from zero for an industry with an infinite number of tiny firms to 10,000 for a single firm monopoly

5 Symposium on Mergers and Antitrust 7 market. 5 Third, the likelihood of entry into the market is evaluated. Fourth, other competitive factors that might affect the likelihood of successful collusion are evaluated, including producer information exchanges and contracting practices. Fifth, any efficiency benefits, primarily cost savings, are analyzed. These five elements then are balanced. Most economists agree that this five-part protocol is a reasonable way, in the words of Franklin Fisher, to organize the data. It is the weights the Guidelines place on these factors in this balancing, and the methodology by which to measure the factors, that are disputed. The Guidelines measure market concentration and ease of entry in the context of a "relevant antitrust market," defined on the basis of the own-price elasticity for a set of products (and geographic area). In particular, a relevant antitrust market is defined as a set of products and geographic area, such that if all the production capacity in the set were owned by a single firm (a "hypothetical monopolist"), that firm profitably could raise price by at least some percentage (for example, 5 percent or 10 percent) above the current (not necessarily competitive) level for a "significant non-transitory" time period. This methodology is referred to as the "5 percent (or 10 percent) test" and is the key concept of the Guidelines. In evaluating the profitability of a price rise, the Guidelines evaluate the potential for substitution by buyers to other products ("demand substitution") and capacity switchovers by sellers of other products ("supply substitution"), as well as substitution to producers whose plants are located in other places ("geographic diversion") that would occur within 12 months in response to the price increase. The Guidelines evaluate "ease of entry" in a similar way. Entry is considered "easy" if, in response to the hypothetical price increase, enough new capacity would be brought on line within 24 months to render the price rise unprofitable. By defining market power as the ability to raise prices, the administration reform proposal would support this approach to market definition and ease of entry. According to the Guidelines, ease of entry and market concentration are given the most weight. Indeed, in the 1982 Guidelines, efficiencies and other factors were treated as "tiebreakers" that only came into play in otherwise "close" cases. Ease of entry could be considered the primary variable, in that "easy entry" can justify even merger to an apparent monopoly, where the "monopolist" is actually constrained by many potential entrants; consider a merger between the only two taxicab companies in a town where no medallion or reputation is required to compete. If entry is not "easy," primary focus then is placed on market concentration. Once markets are defined, concentration is relatively easy to measure, and according to many economists, higher concentration raises the likelihood of successful (tacit or 5 For example, if an industry is comprised of one firm with 80 percent and two firms with 10 percent each, the HHI would equal 6600 (that is, (80) 2 + (10) 2 + (10) 2 ). For an industry comprised of N equal-sized firms, the HHI = 10,000 N. The Herfindahl-Hirshman Index replaced the Four- and Eight-Firm Concentration Ratios (that is, the aggregate market share held by the top four or eight firms) used in the 1968 Guidelines and major court decisions. In practice, these concentration indices are highly correlated.

6 8 Economic Perspectives express) collusion. According to the DOJ Guidelines, if the post-merger HHI remains below 1000, the DOJ threshold for an "unconcentrated" market, all mergers are permitted, despite entry barriers or other factors. In the parlance of enforcers, the HHI of 1000 is a "safe harbor." A post-merger HHI of 1800 defines the threshold of a "highly concentrated" market. If the post-merger HHI exceeds 1800 and entry is not "easy," the DOJ "generally" will attempt to block mergers that increase the HHI by at least 50 points, and will attempt to block mergers that increase the HHI by more than 100 points, except in "extraordinary cases." 6 Mergers with HHI's in the "gray area" between 1000 and 1800 will only be blocked if they would raise the HHI by at least 100 points. In this gray area, ease of entry and other factors are given the most weight. Even if concentration and entry barriers both are high, noncompetitive pricing is not a certainty. Sophisticated buyers may utilize long term contracts to destabilize collusive agreements, and product heterogeneity and the potential for secret price cuts may reduce the likelihood of successful collusion. On the other hand, information exchanges among producers and (ironically named) "buyer protection" clauses such as most-favored-customer and meeting competition provisions may increase the likelihood that oligopolistic pricing coordination will succeed. In the Guidelines, these "plus" and "minus" factors are taken into account in "close" cases. Some observers claim that, in recent practice, merger policy has been made some what more permissive by giving more weight to those "minus" factors that reduce the likelihood of successful coordination. The administration bill, by eliminating the "incipiency standard," would tend to increase further the weight placed on the "minus" factors. Finally, under the 1984 revisions of the Guidelines, mergers likely to raise prices will be permitted nonetheless if the parties can demonstrate by "clear and convincing evidence" that the merger is "reasonably necessary" to create significant cost savings or other efficiency benefits. These benefits include achieving economies of scale as well as direct technological improvements. By the "reasonably necessary" standard, the Guidelines will not consider efficiencies achievable by means short of merger. In that case, a competitively troublesome merger need not be permitted because the cost savings will be achieved anyway. Where a merger is reasonably necessary for achieving efficiencies, the Guidelines do not state how cost savings and monopoly price increases should be balanced. This balancing issue is important and quite controversial. Even modest cost decreases would swamp any short run deadweight losses from monopoly pricing, if the Department of Justice were indifferent to the distribution of the gains between consumers and stockholders and cared only about total social welfare. In the parlance of antitrust, the issue is a matter of interpreting "consumer welfare" (and "competition") either to mean the welfare of purchasers of the products or to mean aggregate 6 The Guidelines also contain a "leading firm proviso." No acquisition of a firm with a market share exceeding 1 percent is permitted for the leading firm in the industry, if the market share of the leading firm exceeds 35 percent.

7 Salop 9 economic efficiency. 7 The controversy has become sharper because the administration leans to the latter interpretation, while most courts seem generally to favor the former. Issues for Analysis This conceptual framework raises two difficult questions. How should these variables be measured and, once measured, how should they be weighted? In practice, what might appear initially to be purely a measurement issue also may imply an enforcement standard, which creates a significant problem for the policy maker. For example, by defining a relevant antitrust market according to the degree of substitution within twelve months rather than six months, markets will be defined more broadly and this expansion of the market definition will, as a general matter, tend to permit more mergers. 8 That permissiveness can be offset, of course, by tightening either the concentration or entry standards. This choice raises a difficult balancing issue. What is the correct mix: to define markets tightly and set high concentration thresholds or vice versa? These basic issues are the ones that face economists and policy makers in evaluating merger enforcement and merger reform. These are the controversies the participants were asked to address. To focus their analysis, we also posed a number of specific questions. These questions provide a framework for analysis. They may well be useful to readers in forming their own opinions and organizing their own thoughts. 9 Market Definition 1. How should relevant antitrust markets be defined? What initial price should be used as the benchmark in the test? The Guidelines' use of the current price as the benchmark has been criticized as preventing deterioration of the competitive environment, but placing no weight at all on the potential for increased competition in the future. 10 This issue also forms part of the question of the appropriate legal standard for evaluating the likelihood of anticompetitive effects. 7 By training, economists might lean to the aggregate efficiency standard, at least initially. After all, economics purports to have little insight into the "proper" distribution of wealth. But simply because economic theory has little to contribute does not mean that society should be indifferent to the distribution, where losers are not compensated for their losses by winners. For example, consider a worker who steals $100 from a capitalist and invests the proceeds at a higher return than the capitalist earned. Would the higher social return justify the involuntary transfer? 8 Lawrence White stresses the exceptions to this generalization in his article. 9 Also, teachers may wish to use these questions to organize class discussion or formulate examination questions. 10 In this regard, the Guidelines are accused of committing the "cellophane fallacy." In the 1956 case against Du Pont, the Supreme Court held that cellophane was not a relevant market, and Du Pont had no market power, because at current prices, any further cellophane price rises would be constrained by competition from other flexible wrappings. This conclusion was fallacious, of course. The fact that no further price rises were possible does not mean that the market was competitive. Rather, perhaps Du Pont could raise price no further because it already was charging the monopoly price. The DOJ's use of the current price as the benchmark arises from a policy judgment that merger policy only should prevent

8 10 Economic Perspectives 2. Some commentators claim that while the "5 percent test" approach looks good on paper, it has failed in practice for two reasons. First, it is so hypothetical (hypothetical buyers and competitors with perfect information responding to a price rise by a hypothetical monopolist) that the result generally will be entirely subjective. As a result, it gives the agency enormous discretion. This is, of course, in striking contrast to the concreteness of the HHI levels. Put another way, the apparent concreteness of the HHIs is dissolved by the mushiness of the 5 percent test. Second, and based on the first point, critics have claimed that the agencies have administered the test in practice to broaden markets far beyond practical boundaries by accepting weak subjective evidence of potential substitution instead of insisting on "hard evidence" of actual substitution. Have the DOJ and the FTC been defining markets too narrowly or too broadly? Has the evidentiary standard been too low? Should the agencies be constrained to use only "hard evidence" of actual or very likely substitution? 3. The 1982 Guidelines specified a 5 percent price test. The 1984 Guidelines contemplate larger price increases as well. It has been suggested that, in practice, the Department of Justice has now increased the price percentage to 10 percent, instead of 5 percent. In general, this change would broaden markets and lead to less enforcement. Which is the better test, 10 percent or 5 percent? 4. How should foreign competition be included in the merger analysis? At one extreme, some commentators would ignore foreign capacity altogether on the grounds that the potential for exogenous exchange rate changes and the chance of tariffs and quotas make the prospects for increased foreign competition too risky. At the other extreme, some argue that if the domestic market has any imports at all, then the entire foreign capacity could be diverted to the United States if prices rose to noncompetitive levels. Should imports be treated identically with domestic capacity, if no quotas exist? If quotas do exist, how should foreign capacity be included in the analysis? Market Concentration 5. Some economists conclude that the "new industrial organization learning" demonstrates that although market concentration may be easy to calculate, it has no predictive value. They say that absolutely no weight should be placed on concentration, that it should be ignored in evaluating mergers. How should concentration enter the analysis? 6. Market definition and concentration are related, of course. As a practical matter, the broader the market definition, the lower market concentration will tend to be. What threshold concentration levels for enforcement guidelines are implied by the optimal market definition? 7. Some evidence suggests that the enforcement agencies in the current administration have brought almost no cases where the HHI is below 1800, the threshold defining "highly concentrated" markets. Is this a beneficial policy change? additional market power and not serve also to preserve the possibility of dissipating already exercised market power.

9 Symposium on Mergers and Antitrust 11 Ease of Entry 8. The DOJ Guidelines do not discuss the determinants of ease of entry in any detail. How should ease of entry be measured in merger analysis? George Stigler defined an entry barrier as limited to costs that entrants (but not incumbents) must bear, while Joe Bain's definition includes the potential entry-deterring effects of "post-entry" price competition. In particular, should the presence of significant scale economies and sunk costs that are identical for all firms be treated as impediments or barriers to entry? What about advertising and reputation? 9. Similarly, despite the weight placed on ease of entry in the Guidelines, the Justice Department did not attempt to devise a method for grading ease of entry into categories (such as low, moderate and high barriers), comparable to the current grading system for market concentration. Should such a grading system be designed to facilitate quantitative analysis of this crucial variable? 10. In evaluating the likelihood of unilateral output reductions and tacit collusion, how much weight should be placed on ease of entry? Should merger to monopoly be permitted in those situations where entry is "very" easy? "Plus" and "Minus" Factors 11. Should evidence about competitive factors relating to contracting practices and information be used as "tiebreakers," or should these factors be weighted more or less heavily? In the extreme, could it be argued that the use of long term contracts by industrial buyers should make any merger short of a true single firm monopoly permissible, regardless of concentration or even ease of entry, on the grounds that sophisticated buyers can devise means of maintaining competition even if only two firms are bidding? Efficiencies 12. How should cost savings and other efficiency benefits be reckoned into merger analysis, if at all? Should cost savings be evaluated in each case or should likely cost savings (on average) be used only in setting overall enforcement thresholds? Can sufficiently credible cost savings information be generated during the short pre-merger screening period to make case-by-case evaluation useful? What should be the evidentiary standard on the merger partners? What should be the benchmark for defining when a merger is "reasonably necessary" to achieve cost efficiencies a comparison with the unmerged status quo or some less restrictive hypothetical alternative like licensing, alternative merger partners, or a joint venture? 13. In specifying the general standard for evaluating claims of cost savings, should the criterion be indifferent to wealth transfers from purchasers to stockholders? That is, should a merger likely to produce cost savings be permitted even if it also leads to market power and higher prices, if the cost savings exceed the deadweight loss triangle? How should considerations of dynamic rent-seeking and innovation incentives be included in the analysis?

10 12 Economic Perspectives Balancing 14. In summary, do the DOJ Guidelines place the correct relative weights on the five factors? Should more or less weight be placed on some of the variables? What are the appropriate enforcement thresholds? Stated another way, what are optimal Merger Guidelines? Should the "incipiency standard" be eliminated altogether or simply interpreted less expansively than in Brown Shoe and Von's Grocery? 15. Current merger policy clearly is more permissive than in previous administrations. As a general matter, has the current administration gone too far or not far enough in loosening merger enforcement? Using these questions as a basic framework, each participant was asked to set out his own analysis. The drafts then were circulated among the participants so they could sharpen their disagreements or achieve consensus in their revisions. Note Many economists may be unfamiliar with the court cases and legal citations that recur throughout this introduction and symposium. Probably the easiest way to collect the relevant material is by using an antitrust casebook. One good example is Handler, et al., Trade Regulation: Cases and Materials. 2nd ed. Mineola, NY: Foundation Press, This book (like other such casebooks), contains the text of the Clayton Act, the Department of Justice Merger Guidelines, and key court cases like Brown Shoe, Von's Grocery, General Dynamics, and Du Pont. Thomas Krattenmaker and the symposium participants provided helpful comments.

How Antitrust Agencies Analyze M&A

How Antitrust Agencies Analyze M&A practicallaw.com PLC Corporate & Securities PLC Finance PLC Law Department CONTENTS Horizontal Mergers Market Definition Market Shares and Concentration Competitive Effects Powerful Buyers Entry Analysis

More information

1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration

1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration 1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration 1.0 Overview A merger is unlikely to create or enhance market power or to facilitate its exercise unless it significantly increases concentration and

More information

Merger Review in the United States and the European Union. Jeffrey I. Shinder Constantine & Partners

Merger Review in the United States and the European Union. Jeffrey I. Shinder Constantine & Partners Merger Review in the United States and the European Union Jeffrey I. Shinder Constantine & Partners What is Antitrust? Fairness Law Protect smaller firms from larger firms Disperse business power Distribute

More information

Merger Analysis and Anti-Trust

Merger Analysis and Anti-Trust Merger Analysis and Anti-Trust Merger: The process in which two or more independently owned firms join under the same ownership. This process could be a merger, takeover, integration, or acquisition. It

More information

LESSON FIVE MAINTAINING COMPETITION

LESSON FIVE MAINTAINING COMPETITION LESSON FIVE MAINTAINING COMPETITION LESSON DESCRIPTION This lesson introduces the rationale for maintaining and strengthening competition, and illustrates the U.S. experience with antitrust laws and other

More information

Any antitrust policy that tries to put some restrictions on mergers must have a

Any antitrust policy that tries to put some restrictions on mergers must have a Economic Perspectives Volume 1, Number 2 Fall 1987 Pages 13 22 Antitrust and Merger Policy: A Review and Critique Lawrence J. White Any antitrust policy that tries to put some restrictions on mergers must

More information

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E PEARSON PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft 2of 37 PART III MARKET IMPERFECTIONS AND THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT Monopoly

More information

PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER. PEARSON Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft

PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER. PEARSON Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N CASE FAIR OSTER PEARSON Prepared by: Fernando Quijano w/shelly Tefft 2 of 25 PART III MARKET IMPERFECTIONS AND THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT Monopoly

More information

Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits

Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits Global Antitrust Institute Hawaii November 2015 October 30, 2012 1 The Economics of Vertical Restraints 2 Vertical Restraints Definition:

More information

Overview of ECO410H and Introduction to Horizontal Merger Assessment ECO410H1F. Organizing Questions for Today. Class 1

Overview of ECO410H and Introduction to Horizontal Merger Assessment ECO410H1F. Organizing Questions for Today. Class 1 Overview of ECO410H and Introduction to Horizontal Merger Assessment Class 1 1 ECO410H1F Mergers and Competition Policy Prof. Murdock Syllabus Take a moment to skim through section titles Highlight some

More information

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK 201[ ] ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS (GUIDELINES ON MARKET ANALYSIS AND THE ASSESSMENT OF SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER FOR NETWORKS AND SERVICES) (ARRANGEMENT OF GUIDELINES) Table of Contents 1. [Short Title]

More information

Proposed Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Economists Comment

Proposed Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Economists Comment Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin June 3, 2010 Proposed Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Economists Comment Michael R. Baye, Indiana University Aaron S Edlin, University of California - Berkeley

More information

Aditya Bhattacharjea Delhi School of Economics

Aditya Bhattacharjea Delhi School of Economics Aditya Bhattacharjea Delhi School of Economics Allocative efficiency (P > MC: deadweight loss). BUT it may not be feasible to have competition with P = MC where there are strong economies of scale (natural

More information

ICN Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis and Model ICN Guides. MICHELE PACILLO, AGCM ITALY MWG Workshop Washington DC February 16, 2017

ICN Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis and Model ICN Guides. MICHELE PACILLO, AGCM ITALY MWG Workshop Washington DC February 16, 2017 ICN Recommended Practices for Merger Analysis and Model ICN Guides MICHELE PACILLO, AGCM ITALY MWG Workshop Washington DC February 16, 2017 Model ICN Guides Work Products on Notification & Procedures Guiding

More information

Session 6: Market Analysis tools and cases

Session 6: Market Analysis tools and cases Session 6: Market Analysis tools and cases Training on Competition and Changing Market Conditions: Impact on ICT Regulation Addis Ababa, 6 th 9 th November, 2007 By Dr Chris Doyle Warwick Business School

More information

Mergers and Acquisitions: Primer on Economic Considerations in the FTC and DOJ Horizontal Merger Approval Process

Mergers and Acquisitions: Primer on Economic Considerations in the FTC and DOJ Horizontal Merger Approval Process Order Code RS22606 February 15, 2007 Mergers and Acquisitions: Primer on Economic Considerations in the FTC and DOJ Horizontal Merger Approval Process Summary Edward Vincent Murphy Analyst in Financial

More information

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Besanko, Dranove, Shanley, and Schaefer Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition Slides by: Richard Ponarul, California State University, Chico Copyright 2010 John Wiley

More information

Doing Deals: Avoiding Antitrust Pitfalls During Due Diligence and Transition Planning

Doing Deals: Avoiding Antitrust Pitfalls During Due Diligence and Transition Planning Doing Deals: Avoiding Antitrust Pitfalls During Due Diligence and Transition Planning 5 When competitors start considering a merger, they should involve their antitrust counsel from the beginning. Managing

More information

Analysis of the effects of a merger

Analysis of the effects of a merger Merger control Introduction First merger regulation in the the EU : 1989 Revised in 2004 (EC merger regulation 139/2004) Under the 1999 regulation, merger test = «creation or reinforcement of a dominant

More information

COMPETITION AUTHORITY OF KENYA GUIDELINES ON RELEVANT MARKET DEFINITION I. INTRODUCTION

COMPETITION AUTHORITY OF KENYA GUIDELINES ON RELEVANT MARKET DEFINITION I. INTRODUCTION COMPETITION AUTHORITY OF KENYA GUIDELINES ON RELEVANT MARKET DEFINITION I. INTRODUCTION 1. The purpose of these guidelines is to provide guidance as to how the Authority applies the concept of relevant

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RS22606 Mergers and Acquisitions: Primer on Economic Considerations in the FTC and DOJ Horizontal Merger Approval Process

More information

Chapter 14 Oligopoly and Monopoly

Chapter 14 Oligopoly and Monopoly Economics 6 th edition 1 Chapter 14 Oligopoly and Monopoly Modified by Yulin Hou For Principles of Microeconomics Florida International University Fall 2017 Oligopoly: a very different market structure

More information

competition policy r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 1

competition policy r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 1 Definition Competition policy, also known as antitrust policy in the United States, is a body of legislated law designed to promote and maintain competition in markets. Abstract This article discusses

More information

Basic Microeconomics. Basic Microeconomics 1

Basic Microeconomics. Basic Microeconomics 1 Basic Microeconomics Basic Microeconomics 1 Efficiency and Market Performance Contrast two polar cases perfect competition monopoly What is efficiency? no reallocation of the available resources makes

More information

Takeovers and Industry Competition

Takeovers and Industry Competition Takeovers and Industry Competition Professor B. Espen Eckbo 2010 US antitrust enforcement (1) 1890: The Sherman Act 1950: Celler-Kefauver amendment to Section 7 of the Clayton Act Since 1950, the DOJ and

More information

Lessons from the evolution of merger guidelines in the United States. Mark A. Jamison a & Janice A. Hauge b * November 15, 2014

Lessons from the evolution of merger guidelines in the United States. Mark A. Jamison a & Janice A. Hauge b * November 15, 2014 Lessons from the evolution of merger guidelines in the United States Mark A. Jamison a & Janice A. Hauge b * a. Director, Public Utility Research Center PO Box 117142 205 Matherly Hall University of Florida

More information

Competition Bureau Issues New Merger Guidelines What They Mean For Canadian Businesses

Competition Bureau Issues New Merger Guidelines What They Mean For Canadian Businesses Competition Bureau Issues New Merger Guidelines What They Mean For Canadian Businesses October 14, 2011 On October 6, 2011, Canada's Competition Bureau released newly revised Merger Enforcement Guidelines

More information

Executive Briefing on Revised Merger Guidelines: What Every Hospital Executive Needs to Know. Mark Mattioli Post & Schell, PC Philadelphia, PA

Executive Briefing on Revised Merger Guidelines: What Every Hospital Executive Needs to Know. Mark Mattioli Post & Schell, PC Philadelphia, PA Executive Briefing on Revised Merger Guidelines: What Every Hospital Executive Needs to Know. Mark Mattioli Post & Schell, PC Philadelphia, PA Summary On August 19, 2010, the Federal Trade Commission and

More information

Antitrust Law Update

Antitrust Law Update April 5, 2001 Antitrust Law Update The FTC Staff s Report on Slotting Allowances: Doctrinal Indecision With a Mandate to Dig Deeper In late February, the FTC staff issued its long-anticipated Report on

More information

Antitrust in Friday, January 29, 2016

Antitrust in Friday, January 29, 2016 Antitrust in 2016 Challenges and Conundrums for the West Coast in 2016 Friday, January 29, 2016 2016 Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP. All rights reserved. Throughout this presentation, Cleary Gottlieb

More information

Part III: Market Structure 12. Monopoly 13. Game Theory and Strategic Play 14. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Part III: Market Structure 12. Monopoly 13. Game Theory and Strategic Play 14. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition and Part III: Structure 12. Monopoly 13. Game Theory and Strategic Play 14. and 1 / 38 and Chapter 14 and 2015.12.25. 2 / 38 and 1 2 3 4 5 3 / 38 and Q:How many firms are necessary to make a market competitive?

More information

Oligopoly C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

Oligopoly C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Oligopoly CHAPTER17 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Describe and identify oligopoly and explain how it arises. 2 Explain the dilemma

More information

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By Break-even point : the point at which price equals the minimum of average total cost. Externalities : the spillover effects of production or consumption for which no

More information

Antitrust Policy in Health Care: Searching for a Strategy That Works Roger Feldman July 16, 2009

Antitrust Policy in Health Care: Searching for a Strategy That Works Roger Feldman July 16, 2009 Antitrust Policy in Health Care: Searching for a Strategy That Works Roger Feldman July 16, 2009 Outline of Presentation Brief outline of antitrust tools Discuss recent developments in horizontal mergers

More information

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. Understanding UPP Roy J. Epstein and Daniel L. Rubinfeld Published Version, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Policies and Perspectives, Volume 10, Issue 1, 2010 Introduction The standard economic

More information

Revisiting the hypothetical monopolist test, and the role of common sense market definitions

Revisiting the hypothetical monopolist test, and the role of common sense market definitions Revisiting the hypothetical monopolist test, and the role of common sense market definitions Bea Pros and Cons conference 2017 3 November 2017 Professor Amelia Fletcher Centre for Competition Policy University

More information

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry Mergers Types of Mergers Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry Vertical Merger this is a merger between two firms at different stages of the production

More information

Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry

Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry A Report by Federal Trade Commission Staff February 2001 INTRODUCTION AND EXECUTIVE

More information

Name: Class: Date: 2. Patents, quotas, tariffs, and government licensing can all create barriers to entry into oligopoly industries. a.

Name: Class: Date: 2. Patents, quotas, tariffs, and government licensing can all create barriers to entry into oligopoly industries. a. Indicate whether the statement is true or false. 1. Import tariffs in the United States are likely to reduce U.S. exports, both because of the resulting decrease in foreign earnings of dollars from exports

More information

A Paper Prepared for ABRACE by Ashley C. Brown, June 10, Advice on the Brazilian Natural Gas Market

A Paper Prepared for ABRACE by Ashley C. Brown, June 10, Advice on the Brazilian Natural Gas Market A Paper Prepared for ABRACE by Ashley C. Brown, June 10, 2014 Advice on the Brazilian Natural Gas Market The natural gas market in Brazil is largely dysfunctional and constitutes a major barrier to the

More information

The hypothetical world with which the concept of perfect competition is concerned is one in which markets have the following characteristics:

The hypothetical world with which the concept of perfect competition is concerned is one in which markets have the following characteristics: Competition From Citizendium, the Citizens' Compendium Competition is a means by which limited resources can be allocated among rival bidders. The degree to which it is present in a market has a strong

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Implications of E-commerce for Competition Policy - Note by Chinese Taipei

Implications of E-commerce for Competition Policy - Note by Chinese Taipei Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development DAF/COMP/WD(2018)43 DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE English - Or. English 4 May 2018 Implications of E-commerce

More information

Session 2: Competition Policy Fundamentals

Session 2: Competition Policy Fundamentals Session 2: Competition Policy Fundamentals Training on Competition and Changing Market Conditions: Impact on ICT Regulation Addis Ababa, 6 th 9 th November, 2007 By Dr Chris Doyle Warwick Business School

More information

Market power in antitrust analysis

Market power in antitrust analysis Market power in antitrust analysis Eric Emch ABA Brownbag: Fundamentals of Economics Series January 17, 2017 Agenda Definitions Structural indicators of market power Direct indicators of market power Summary/conclusion

More information

Response to Gopal Das Varma s Market Definition, Upward Pricing Pressure, and the Role of Courts: A Response to Carlton and Israel

Response to Gopal Das Varma s Market Definition, Upward Pricing Pressure, and the Role of Courts: A Response to Carlton and Israel theantitrustsource www.antitrustsource.com December 2010 1 Response to Gopal Das Varma s Market Definition, Upward Pricing Pressure, and the Role of Courts: A Response to Carlton and Israel Dennis W. Carlton

More information

Platforms in the Spotlight at the FTC Hearings

Platforms in the Spotlight at the FTC Hearings CPI s North America Column Presents: Platforms in the Spotlight at the FTC Hearings By Joshua D. Wright and John M. Yun (George Mason University) 1 November 2018 The Spotlight on Platforms Over a series

More information

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

Chapter 15 Oligopoly Goldwasser AP Microeconomics Chapter 15 Oligopoly BEFORE YOU READ THE CHAPTER Summary This chapter explores oligopoly, a market structure characterized by a few firms producing a product that mayor may

More information

Welfare Loss due to Concentration in the food industry By: Matthew Rousu

Welfare Loss due to Concentration in the food industry By: Matthew Rousu Welfare Loss due to Concentration in the food industry By: Matthew Rousu Introduction Throughout history, there has been opposition to big businesses and large corporations. In 1776, in his classic book

More information

Excerpts on Competitive Effects Horizontal Merger Guidelines

Excerpts on Competitive Effects Horizontal Merger Guidelines Excerpts on Competitive Effects Horizontal Merger Guidelines U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission Issued: August 19, 2010 6. Unilateral Effects The elimination of competition between

More information

WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION

WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION KEELEY, KUENN & REID WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION Prepared by the Law Firm of KEELEY, KUENN & REID 150 North Wacker Drive, Suite 1100 Chicago, IL 60606 (312) 782-1829 FAX

More information

2013 sample MC CH 15. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

2013 sample MC CH 15. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. Class: Date: 2013 sample MC CH 15 Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1. Monopolistic competition is identified by a. many firms producing a slightly

More information

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly Market Structures The classification of market structures can be arranged along a continuum, ranging from perfect competition, the most competitive market, to monopoly, the lease competitive: Perfect competition

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Session 7: Concentration, Mergers, and Entry Barriers Jiangli Dou School of Economics Jiangli Dou (School of Economics) Industrial Organization 1 / 100 Introduction The study of

More information

THE EU MERGER REGULATION: SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES

THE EU MERGER REGULATION: SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES THE EU MERGER REGULATION: SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES FOURTH EDITION By ALISTAIR LINDSAY Barrister, Monckton Chambers ALISON BERRIDGE Barrister, Monckton Chambers MAXWELL THOMSON REUTERS PAGE Preface v Dedication

More information

MEASURING MARKET POWER IN MULTI-SIDED MARKETS

MEASURING MARKET POWER IN MULTI-SIDED MARKETS MEASURING MARKET POWER IN MULTI-SIDED MARKETS 1 BY KATE COLLYER, HUGH MULLAN & NATALIE TIMAN 1 I. INTRODUCTION Digital markets are becoming an increasingly important feature of every economy. Online platforms

More information

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 1

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 1 Part 1: Introduction to this course Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 1 1. What is Industrial Organization? Industrial organization is concerned with

More information

Antitrust Considerations in Healthcare. Cory A. Talbot ( )

Antitrust Considerations in Healthcare. Cory A. Talbot ( ) Antitrust Considerations in Healthcare Cory A. Talbot (10 26 17) What are we going to talk about? The basics of antitrust enforcement How antitrust enforcement works in some areas of the healthcare arena

More information

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition?

Joven Liew Jia Wen Industrial Economics I Notes. What is competition? Industrial Economics I Notes What is competition? Competition in markets is generally considered a good thing (welfare economics) Competition authorities look at whether change in market structure or firm

More information

CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making. Study Unit 9 - Decision Analysis and Risk Management Ronald Schmidt, CMA, CFM

CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making. Study Unit 9 - Decision Analysis and Risk Management Ronald Schmidt, CMA, CFM CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making Study Unit 9 - Decision Analysis and Risk Management Ronald Schmidt, CMA, CFM Objectives of the Class Use Marginal Analysis for Decision Making Calculate effect on

More information

THE 2008 ACCC MERGER GUIDELINES: HOW AND WHY HAVE THEY CHANGED?

THE 2008 ACCC MERGER GUIDELINES: HOW AND WHY HAVE THEY CHANGED? 2009 Forum: The 2008 ACCC Merger Guidelines: How and Why Have They Changed? 263 THE 2008 ACCC MERGER GUIDELINES: HOW AND WHY HAVE THEY CHANGED? STEPHEN P KING * I INTRODUCTION In November 2008, the Australian

More information

Monopoly Building Why the Justice Department Must Block the Ticketmaster/LiveNation Deal

Monopoly Building Why the Justice Department Must Block the Ticketmaster/LiveNation Deal Monopoly Building Why the Justice Department Must Block the Ticketmaster/LiveNation Deal By David Balto April 20, 2009 Reposted courtesy of Pollstar. The purpose of antitrust laws is to protect consumers

More information

PROVIDER MERGERS: THE NEED FOR EARLY ANTITRUST ADVICE [OBER KALER]

PROVIDER MERGERS: THE NEED FOR EARLY ANTITRUST ADVICE [OBER KALER] PROVIDER MERGERS: THE NEED FOR EARLY ANTITRUST ADVICE Publication PROVIDER MERGERS: THE NEED FOR EARLY ANTITRUST ADVICE [OBER KALER] Author John J. Miles 2016 Given the Federal Trade Commission's (FTC's)

More information

Chapter 1: Introduction to Quantitative Techniques for Competition Policy. Quantitative Methods for Competition and Regulation Albert Banal-Estanol

Chapter 1: Introduction to Quantitative Techniques for Competition Policy. Quantitative Methods for Competition and Regulation Albert Banal-Estanol Chapter 1: Introduction to Quantitative Techniques for Competition Policy Quantitative Methods for Competition and Regulation Quantitative Techniques in Competition Policy The use of QT has a longer tradition

More information

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!! ! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!! the story so far Natural monopoly: Definitions (Ideal) Pricing solutions Regulation in practice Regulation under asymmetric information Competition policy: Introduction

More information

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division 1 COLLUSION AND MARKET TRANSPARENCY Greater transparency in the market is generally

More information

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction:

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction: S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key Instruction: Exam 3 Student Name: Microeconomics, several versions Early May, 2011 Instructions: I) On your Scantron card you must print three things: 1) Full name

More information

The Role of the Circle Principle in Market Definition

The Role of the Circle Principle in Market Definition theantitrustsource w w w. a n t i t r u s t s o u r c e. c o m A p r i l 2 0 1 8 1 The Role of the Circle Principle in Market Definition Bryan Keating, Jonathan Orszag, and Robert Willig T The current

More information

Eco 403: Industrial Organization Economics, Fall Dr. Abdel-Hameed H. Nawar. Preliminaries

Eco 403: Industrial Organization Economics, Fall Dr. Abdel-Hameed H. Nawar. Preliminaries Eco 403: Industrial Organization Economics, Fall 2012 Dr. Abdel-Hameed H. Nawar Preliminaries What is Industrial organization economics? Industrial organization economics is the field in economics which

More information

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Chapter 27. Oligopoly and Strategic Behavior

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Chapter 27. Oligopoly and Strategic Behavior Chapter 27 Oligopoly and Introduction On a typical day, United Parcel Service will transport over 10 million packages. UPS and its main rival, FedEx Ground, earn more than three-fourths of total revenue

More information

The Handbook of Competition Economics

The Handbook of Competition Economics The Handbook of Competition Economics 2009 A Global Competition Review special report published in association with: www.globalcompetitionreview.com Should Competition Policy Prohibit Price Discrimination?

More information

CH 17 sample MC Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CH 17 sample MC Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. Class: Date: CH 17 sample MC - 80 Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1. Deregulation is defined as the a. use of government rules to regulate

More information

Strategy is the way a business operates in order to achieve its aims and objectives.

Strategy is the way a business operates in order to achieve its aims and objectives. Chapter 6 Strategy and implementation Business objectives and strategy Strategy is the way a business operates in order to achieve its aims and objectives. There are two sides to strategy - the first is

More information

Hart-Scott-Rodino and the Revised Merger Guidelines

Hart-Scott-Rodino and the Revised Merger Guidelines Hart-Scott-Rodino and the Revised Merger Guidelines Robert A. McTamaney May 2013 Hart-Scott-Rodino Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976 Eliminated Midnight Mergers Pre-Closing Filing with

More information

University of Miami Law Review

University of Miami Law Review University of Miami Law Review Volume 69 CAVEAT March 2015 RESPONSE The E-Books Conspiracy: Crossing the Line Between Applying and Creating Law TOM CAMPBELL * In response to John B. Kirkwood, Collusion

More information

Chapter 7: Market Structures

Chapter 7: Market Structures SCHS SOCIAL STUDIES What you need to know UNIT THREE 1. Describe 4 conditions that are in place for a perfectly competitive market 2. Describe and give characteristics of a monopoly 3. Describe and give

More information

A NEW STANDARD FOR ANTITRUST

A NEW STANDARD FOR ANTITRUST A NEW STANDARD FOR ANTITRUST THE EFFECTIVE COMPETITION STANDARD: IN PRACTICE ISSUE BRIEF BY MARSHALL STEINBAUM AND MAURICE E. STUCKE SEPTEMBER 2018 Today s economy has a market power problem. Consumers

More information

Lesson-29. Monopoly. We have seen that p-competition has some remarkable results. It defines an ideal market structure in two senses:

Lesson-29. Monopoly. We have seen that p-competition has some remarkable results. It defines an ideal market structure in two senses: Lesson-29 Monopoly We have seen that p-competition has some remarkable results. It defines an ideal market structure in two senses: 1. In p-competition, price competition dominates all other forms of competition

More information

Barriers to Entry in Antitrust Analysis. (Barrières à l'entrée dans l Analyze Antitrust)

Barriers to Entry in Antitrust Analysis. (Barrières à l'entrée dans l Analyze Antitrust) Barriers to Entry in Antitrust Analysis (Barrières à l'entrée dans l Analyze Antitrust) R. Preston McAfee and Hugo M. Mialon 1 October 20, 2004 The existence of barriers to entry is a central subject of

More information

Chapter 7. Section 3: Monopolist Competition & Oligopoly

Chapter 7. Section 3: Monopolist Competition & Oligopoly Chapter 7 Section 3: Monopolist Competition & Oligopoly Monopolist Competition Many companies compete in an open market to sell products that are similar but not identical Each firms hold a monopoly over

More information

Economic Fundamentals:

Economic Fundamentals: Economic Fundamentals: Vertical and Coordinated Effects in Mergers Debra J. Aron, Ph.D. Navigant Economics Northwestern University May 27, 2016 Disclaimer This presentation covers only a sampling of the

More information

A Rational Approach towards Abuse of Collective Market. Dominance in Antitrust Law. Zhan Hao, Song Ying &Tian Chen

A Rational Approach towards Abuse of Collective Market. Dominance in Antitrust Law. Zhan Hao, Song Ying &Tian Chen A Rational Approach towards Abuse of Collective Market Dominance in Antitrust Law Zhan Hao, Song Ying &Tian Chen 1. Introduction The concept of abuse of collective market dominance ( Collective Abuse )stems

More information

Market Structure. Oligopoly

Market Structure. Oligopoly Market Structure Oligopoly Characteristics of Oligopoly The government does not intervene into the operations of the oligopolistically competitive firm in the market unless the oligopolist violates the

More information

Econ Microeconomics Notes

Econ Microeconomics Notes Econ 120 - Microeconomics Notes Daniel Bramucci December 1, 2016 1 Section 1 - Thinking like an economist 1.1 Definitions Cost-Benefit Principle An action should be taken only when its benefit exceeds

More information

CH short answer study questions Answer Section

CH short answer study questions Answer Section CH 15-16 short answer study questions Answer Section ESSAY 1. ANS: There are a large number firms; each produces a slightly different product; firms compete on price, quality and marketing; and firms are

More information

Regional Competition Center for Latin America presents: Guidelines on exchanges of information among competitors

Regional Competition Center for Latin America presents: Guidelines on exchanges of information among competitors Regional Competition Center for Latin America presents: Guidelines on exchanges of information among competitors Rosa M. Abrantes-Metz* NYU Stern School of Business 1 One of the main objectives of the

More information

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin Frontier Economics Bulletin Water Energy Retailing Transport Financial services Healthcare Telecoms Media Post Competition Policy Policy analysis and design Regulation Strategy Contract design and evaluation

More information

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level Edexcel (B) Economics A-level Theme 4: Making Markets Work 4.2 Market Power and Market Failure 4.2.1 Market failure Notes Significance of market power: o Cartels, collusion, restrictive practices and tacit

More information

Antitrust Issues Involving Mergers, Acquisitions & Exclusive Licensing in Pharma and Biotech

Antitrust Issues Involving Mergers, Acquisitions & Exclusive Licensing in Pharma and Biotech Antitrust Issues Involving Mergers, Acquisitions & Exclusive Licensing in Pharma and Biotech Michael S. McFalls Jones Day ACI Pharmaceutical Antitrust Conference May 21, 2008 *These views are those of

More information

MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Chapter 17 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Chapter Summary Now that you understand the model of a perfectly competitive market, this chapter complicates

More information

Analysis Group vguppi Online Tool Detailed User Guide. Revised August 13, 2014

Analysis Group vguppi Online Tool Detailed User Guide. Revised August 13, 2014 Analysis Group vguppi Online Tool Detailed User Guide Revised August 13, 2014 1. Detailed user guide 2 Introduction 2 The vguppi Methodology 2 1. vguppi U 2 2. vguppi R 3 3. vguppi D 3 Input Parameters

More information

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition Name: Class: Date: ID: A Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1. In the quasi-competitive model a. firms believe

More information

ECON 2100 (Fall 2018 Section 11) Exam #3B

ECON 2100 (Fall 2018 Section 11) Exam #3B ECON 21 (Fall 218 Section 11) Exam #3B Multiple Choice Questions: (3 points each) 1. I am taking of the exam. B. Version B 2. Market Power refers to a situation in which A. a firm charges different consumers

More information

ECON 2100 (Fall 2018 Section 11) Exam #3A

ECON 2100 (Fall 2018 Section 11) Exam #3A ECON 21 (Fall 218 Section 11) Exam #3A Multiple Choice Questions: (3 points each) 1. I am taking of the exam. A. Version A 2. Market Power refers to a situation in which A. a firm has some control over

More information

Submission to the Senate inquiry into Trade Practices Amendment (Guaranteed Lowest Prices - Blacktown Amendment) Bill 2009.

Submission to the Senate inquiry into Trade Practices Amendment (Guaranteed Lowest Prices - Blacktown Amendment) Bill 2009. Submission to the Senate inquiry into Trade Practices Amendment (Guaranteed Lowest Prices - Blacktown Amendment) Bill 2009 Sinclair Davidson September 2009 Executive Summary This paper argues that the

More information

Market Equilibrium, Price Floor, Price Ceiling

Market Equilibrium, Price Floor, Price Ceiling Porters 5 Forces: 1. Entrants sunk costs, switching costs, speed of adjustment, economies of scale, sunk costs, network effects, reputation, government restraints 2. Power of input suppliers supplier concentration,

More information

15 OLIGOPOLY. Chapter. Key Concepts. Prisoners Dilemma Payoff Matrix. A s strategies. Deny. Confess. 4 years. 12 years. Confess.

15 OLIGOPOLY. Chapter. Key Concepts. Prisoners Dilemma Payoff Matrix. A s strategies. Deny. Confess. 4 years. 12 years. Confess. Chapter 15 OLIGOPOLY Key Concepts Prisoners Dilemma Payoff Matrix What Is Oligopoly? Oligopoly is a market structure in which natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms and in which a small

More information

Eco201 Review Outline for Final Exam, Fall 2018, Prof. Bill Even

Eco201 Review Outline for Final Exam, Fall 2018, Prof. Bill Even Note: The outline is intended to provide the student with a list of the major topics that will be on the final exam. The instructor is not limited to questions that fit into one of these precise categories,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DID ROBERT BORK UNDERSTATE THE COMPETITIVE IMPACT OF MERGERS? EVIDENCE FROM CONSUMMATED MERGERS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DID ROBERT BORK UNDERSTATE THE COMPETITIVE IMPACT OF MERGERS? EVIDENCE FROM CONSUMMATED MERGERS NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DID ROBERT BORK UNDERSTATE THE COMPETITIVE IMPACT OF MERGERS? EVIDENCE FROM CONSUMMATED MERGERS Orley C. Ashenfelter Daniel Hosken Matthew C. Weinberg Working Paper 19939 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19939

More information

The E-Books Conspiracy: Crossing the Line Between Applying and Creating Law

The E-Books Conspiracy: Crossing the Line Between Applying and Creating Law Chapman University Dale E. Fowler School of Law From the SelectedWorks of Tom Campbell 2015 The E-Books Conspiracy: Crossing the Line Between Applying and Creating Law Tom Campbell Available at: https://works.bepress.com/tom_campbell/28/

More information