Barriers to Price Convergence

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Barriers to Price Convergence"

Transcription

1 Barriers to Price Convergence Marina Glushenkova Andros Kourtellos Marios Zachariadis This Draft: August 4, 2016 Abstract This paper investigates the existence of convergence clubs in the cross-country price mechanism for 96 individual goods retail price levels across 40 countries available semiannually for , using a nonlinear factor model and threshold regression tools. To our knowledge, this is the first paper to find strong evidence for club convergence of retail prices. These clubs emerge due to the interaction of traded and non-traded factors. For example, countries that are physically closer to potential trade partners converge faster than countries in the high distance regime as long as they have low initial labor productivity or low initial income. Moreover, we find an asymmetry in the extent that arbitrage opportunities related to international trade are exploited, with low initial price regime countries exhibiting faster convergence from below than high initial price regime countries exhibit from above, consistent with less resistance to exporting than to importing due to political economy considerations. We interpret our findings as evidence of a local law of one price due to barriers to price convergence that influence the duration of the effect of price shocks. Keywords: convergence clubs, micro prices, nonlinear factor model, threshold regression, law of one price, local convergence. JEL Classification Codes: F4 Department of Economics, P.O. Box 537, CY 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus, Department of Economics, P.O. Box 537, CY 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus, andros@ucy.ac.cy. Department of Economics, P.O. Box 537, CY 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus, zachariadis@ucy.ac.cy.

2 1 Introduction This paper contributes to the long-standing debate about price convergence by investigating the existence of club convergence in prices using semi-annual micro price level data for 40 countries and 96 goods and services over the period To our knowledge, this is the first study to find evidence of meaningful convergence clubs in the cross-country price mechanism. This means that there exists a tendency for prices across countries with identical structural characteristics to converge to one another if their initial prices are in the basin of attraction of the same steady-state equilibrium. 1 In our context, we find that this tendency is induced by the interaction of traded and non-traded input components of retail prices. Hence, our goal is to answer the following set of questions. Do retail prices for individual goods across countries globally converge to a single price or diverge? Do countries form price convergence clubs? If yes, how do these convergence clubs vary across industries? What are the factors that determine these clubs and act as barriers to global price convergence? At the heart of the debate about price convergence is the Law of One Price (LOP) which asserts that, as a result of arbitrage, identical goods sold in different locations will have identical prices when expressed in terms of the same currency. Empirical evidence in favor of the LOP is mixed. According to one strand of the literature the LOP does hold in the long run, conditional on cross-country structural heterogeneity including transport costs and other barriers to trade. During the last decade, a number of studies have utilized micro price levels to assess the rate of price convergence and understand the mechanisms that determine cross-country price convergence and real exchange rate dynamics. This includes Goldberg and Verboven (2005) who use European car prices, Crucini and Shintani (2008) who use Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) annual price level data for , Burstein and Jaimovich (2009) who use barcode prices, and Andrade and Zachariadis (2016) who find relatively low half-lives in part due to the use of semi-annual EIU prices. Typically, the micro-prices literature provides evidence of faster convergence rates than the ones in older studies using aggregate data and finding half-lives of several years as described in the survey by Obstfeld and Rogoff (2001). This recent evidence suggests that the persistence of LOP deviations is sharply reduced and convergence across countries appears to be relatively fast when based on micro prices with higher comparability across locations. 1 By structural characteristics we usually mean preferences, technology, institutions, and government policies, etc., see, Galor (1996). 1

3 One particular line of empirical research departs from the linear model and draws on Dumas (1992) and Sercu, Uppal, and Van Hulle (1995) who suggest the presence of threshold nonlinearities in the cross-country good price process. The threshold nonlinearities may arise due to transactions costs in international arbitrage that create a band of inaction within which the marginal cost of arbitrage exceeds the marginal benefit and hence prices behave as a random walk. In contrast, outside the no-arbitrage band, arbitrage acts as a convergence force to the LOP. These transaction costs should be interpreted more broadly as market frictions which capture sunk costs of international arbitrage so that traders enter the market only when large enough opportunities arise (Dixit (1989), Krugman (1989)), or costs associated with changes in preferences and technology (O Connell and Wei (2002)). Lee and Shin (2010) argue that the introduction of non-traded goods can magnify the effect of transaction costs. Finally, Midrigan (2007) builds and empirically tests a model where the inaction bands are not only functions of the trade cost and the elasticities of substitution, but also of the volatility of the environment. 2 However, nonlinearities can occur for other reasons. For example, they can occur due to heterogeneity in agents expectations because of differences in factors such as risk aversion and constraints due to laws, regulations and institutions (e.g., Brock and Hommes (1997)), or due to incomplete or gradual reforms since individuals or local governments can engage in rent-seeking behavior leading to market fragmentation (Young (2000)). Furthermore, multiple equilibria can arise due to asset market imperfections (Corsetti and Dedola (2005)), search frictions (Alessandria (2009) and Alessandria and Kaboski (2011)), 3 or endogenous currency choice with price stickiness (Gopinath (2015)). While it is easy to see that the price theory that departs from the LOP naturally implies 2 As the volatility of the nominal exchange rate increases, firms find it optimal to pay the menu cost and reprice more frequently, whereas in environments in which this volatility is small, prices adjust infrequently. Here, the firm allows its price to deviate away from its optimum, as long as the deviation is within the S-s bounds, and charges a price that approximately ensures that the LOP holds otherwise. 3 Alessandria (2009) builds a model where international price dispersion arises in the presence of costly non-traded non-market search effort that leads firms to price-to-market based on the opportunity cost of their customers time which in turn depends on local wages, so that the distribution of prices will differ across countries whenever local wage differs. Along similar lines, Alessandria and Kaboski (2011) develop a model where costly consumer search generates a role for local wages in the price-setting behavior of firms as the latter endogenize the fact that consumers in low-income countries have a comparative advantage in producing non-traded non-market search activities and are thus more price elastic than consumers in highincome countries. This complements the Balassa-Samuelson story as it relies on low-income countries having a comparative advantage in producing non-traded goods (shopping activities) that in this case affect the prices of all goods. 2

4 threshold-like structures for price convergence, the existing empirical literature is silent as to whether lack of global convergence to the LOP is associated with convergence clubs (groups of countries that converge locally but not globally) and if it is, what factors generate those clubs. Most empirical studies that depart from linear models employ threshold-type autoregressive models to uncover the band of inaction within which no trade takes place. Specifically, these studies have focused on a particular form of threshold regression model, namely the three regime threshold autoregressive (TAR), to uncover threshold effects of the lagged log price on log price differences when the lagged log price is above or below a particular lagged price threshold value; Obstfeld and Taylor (1989), Michael, Nobay, and Peel (1997), Taylor, Peel, and Sarno (2001), Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn, and Rey (2003), Sarno (2004), and Choi, Murphy, and Wu (2015). The hypothesis is that, inside the band, price deviations from the LOP are persistent while above or below this band arbitrage takes place and deviations from the LOP are mean-reverting. The alternative hypothesis that has been considered is simply that there is no nonlinearity and hence, ignores other possible reasons for nonlinearities. Therefore, in this paper, we contribute to the literature of price convergence by testing for convergence clubs and providing estimates of convergence rates to a Local Law of One Price (LLOP). By local, we refer to the idea that the LOP applies to meaningful subsets of countries and varies across these groups due to group-specific structural heterogeneity. 4 In particular, considering any final good as being comprised of a traded and a non-traded input component as in the retail pricing model of Crucini, Telmer, and Zachariadis (2005), the price level for any individual final good should be determined by a variety of factors pertaining to its respective traded and non-traded components. Its traded component is influenced by trade costs and the ability to exploit arbitrage opportunities, while its nontraded component by local input costs and productivity. Thus, theory would suggest that, in addition to productivity and local input costs, physical distance from potential trade partners and initial price levels might characterize different regimes. In this sense, we posit that countries which converge to different LLOPs depending on differential degrees of physical remoteness from potential trade partners, could belong in different price level regimes. Similarly, countries with differences in local input costs or productivity would be expected to form different price level regimes. 5 4 The identification of meaningful clubs is not a trivial issue as it requires countries to remain in a club for a long-enough time. 5 In the latter case, however, price level regimes would plausibly be similar to income level regimes that 3

5 Our work is closely related to Chen, Choi, and Devereux (2008) who test for σ- convergence, β-convergence, and stochastic-convergence allowing for club convergence using a clustering algorithm originally proposed by Hobijn and Franses (2000). This algorithm identifies groups of converging countries based on a multivariate test for stationarity. Using historical price levels since 1890 for eleven developed economies, they find that global σ- convergence and β-convergence of price levels occurs later and to a lesser extent than is the case for income. Importantly, they do not find any evidence of price convergence within meaningful clubs, in contrast to what has been found in the empirical growth literature regarding income convergence. Our paper differs in several important dimensions including data and methods. Notably, we employ a large panel of disaggregate data for a large number of goods and countries at the semi-annual frequency in order to alleviate cross-sectional aggregation biases (Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn, and Rey (2005)). 6 In spirit, our work is also related to the recent empirical economic growth literature. This literature has provided ample evidence of multiple regimes and nonlinearities in the crosscountry growth process, consistent with the existence of club convergence (e.g., Durlauf and Johnson (1995), Liu and Stengos (1999), Durlauf, Kourtellos, and Minkin (2001), Masanjala and Papageorgiou (2004), Canova (2004), Tan (2010)). If price convergence clubs were solely driven by economic development, there would be limited scope for investigating price convergence clubs given the large existing literature on club convergence in economic growth. However, as argued by Chen, Choi, and Devereux (2008), income and price levels convergence differ in a number of ways. Importantly, certain factors that determine different price regimes might be distinct from those that determine income regimes. This makes price convergence clubs a potentially distinct and interesting topic of study. We start by investigating the existence of convergence clubs using the nonlinear timevarying heterogeneous factor model proposed by Phillips and Sul (2007, 2009). An appealing feature of this nonlinear factor model is that it distinguishes between economies that have converged and economies that are converging, by explicitly addressing the question of invariance of the time-series process for prices. Moreover, as argued byphillips and Sul (2009), this methodology circumvents various problems associated with the validity of conventional price convergence tests. Using the concept of relative convergence, we find have been the focus of the relevant growth literature. 6 Moreover, our data do not suffer from the type of temporal aggregation shown by Taylor (2001) to introduce severe biases in the estimation of convergence parameters. 4

6 ample evidence of lack of global convergence in the form of convergence clubs for nearly all 96 goods. This heterogeneity in the cross-country price process generally carries over to the industry level. Interestingly, the results suggest that the latent factor that determines these clubs is associated with differences in the traded and non-traded components of the goods. Next, we proceed to examine the evidence for convergence clubs further in order to shed more light on the determinants of convergence clubs using the threshold regression model proposed by Hansen (2000). In this context, differences in the degree of price convergence between regimes are interpreted as evidence of convergence within regimes rather than across regimes. The threshold regression model provides an appealing way to study the determinants of convergence clubs because it classifies observations into regimes depending on whether the value of an observed (rather than latent) threshold variable is above (or below) a data-driven sample split value. We consider a range of threshold variables that influence the traded and non-traded components of a final good. Using income or labor productivity as threshold variables, we examine whether poorer countries behind the technology frontier tend to exhibit faster price convergence leading to price convergence via the non-traded component of final prices, consistent with the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis. Using physical distance as a threshold variable we examine whether countries with smaller distance from potential trade partners exhibit relatively faster price convergence via the traded inputs channel. Similarly, using initial prices as a threshold variable we investigate whether countries that are more able to exploit arbitrage opportunities, 7 exhibit relatively faster price convergence via the traded inputs channel. We find no evidence of global conditional β-convergence, yet importantly, we find strong evidence for club convergence as implied by the presence of local β-convergence of countries within meaningful groups in our sample. Our results show that countries are organized into price convergence clubs according to traded factors such as physical distance from potential trade partners and non-traded factors such as labor productivity, local input costs, and economic development. In particular, we find that clubs are formed due to the interaction of these traded and non-traded factors. For example, lower trade costs appear to be conducive to price convergence for countries that also have the non-traded Balassa-Samuelson catch up process operating in full force given low initial productivity, labor cost or income. This 7 Intuitively, we would expect less resistance to exporting (the case of initially cheap countries) than to importing (the case of initially expensive countries) so that resistance to international trade and the resulting ability to arbitrage away price differences could be asymmetric, with countries in the low initial price regime facing less resistance and thus better able to exploit arbitrage opportunities via international trade. 5

7 might be due to the fact that at an early stage of development, industries stand to gain more from proximity to potential international trade partners whereas this does not appear to matter for industries in advanced economies producing highly differentiated products whose demand is not as sensitive to higher trade costs as compared to exports of less differentiated goods from less developed countries. Moreover, being behind the technology frontier appears to be more conducive to price convergence for countries with small physical distance from potential trade partners as compared to countries in the high-distance regime. This is consistent with economic growth theory models where the growth advantage of initial economic backwardness is greatly facilitated by the ability to trade more cheaply. In addition, we find an asymmetry in the extent that arbitrage opportunities related to international trade are exploited, with low initial price regime countries exhibiting faster convergence from below than high initial price regime countries exhibit from above. This is consistent with less resistance to exporting than to importing due to political economy considerations. Finally, convergence is significantly faster for countries with low initial productivity (income) as compared to high initial productivity (income) countries, in the case of countries associated with high control of corruption but not for those associated with low corruption control. This suggests that the catch up process operating via the Balassa-Samuelson channel is present for countries that are successful in controlling corruption via appropriate institutions but not for countries with low control of corruption. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we describe the data we use. Section 3 describes the nonlinear factor model of prices that we use to identify price convergence clubs, and reports the corresponding results. Section 4 describes the threshold regression methodology and discusses the findings. Section 5 briefly concludes. 2 Data The retail price data are drawn from the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) and described extensively in Bergin, Glick, and Wu (2013) and Andrade and Zachariadis (2016). The price data for each item is collected for supermarkets or chains, and for mid-priced outlets. To alleviate possible measurement error, we choose to average prices across stores where 6

8 possible and obtain one representative price per item. The EIU survey covers 140 cities in 90 countries, but availability of data varies across locations. In order to analyze price convergence across countries, we choose the city with the largest available set of data for each country. Moreover, to be able to apply the Phillips and Sul (2007) analysis we utilize only prices of items that are available in all time periods. For the purpose of comparability, we use goods available in more than two-thirds of the countries. We end up with a sample of 96 unique product items in 40 countries available semiannually from 1990H1 to 2010H1. A list of the 96 product items is available in Table 1, while the 40 countries are shown in Table 3. We organize goods in groups using industry classification ISIC rev 2. Our price dataset contains different numbers of items for different industries, with the largest number in food manufacturing (a total of 41 items) and the smallest number of items in tobacco manufactures (just 3 items). To allow sufficient cross-industry variation, we exclude countries with less than two thirds of the goods of an industry available. At the same time, we exclude industries with small numbers of goods (less than 5 items). The excluded industries are Tobacco Manufactures (3 items), Soft Drinks (4 items), Manufacture of Motor Vehicles (4 items), and Electricity, Gas and Steam (4 items). Similarly, we exclude Manufacture of Alcohol Beverages, Transport, Storage and Communication, and Real Estate, since retention of these would lead to the exclusion of nine countries 8 with insufficient data for these items. In Section 4 we utilize data for control of corruption and democratic accountability to detect the institutional determinants of price convergence. These data were obtained from the International Country Risk Guide from the PRS group for For these variables, higher score means lower risk. As a measure of initial economic performance of the country we use lagged log real GDP per capita and lagged labor productivity data, obtained from the Penn World Tables 7.1 for We calculate average distance from each city to all other cities in the sample as a measure of geographic isolation from potential trade partners. We also utilize data for labor cost obtained from the EIU for , available for only 31 countries. More details about all data are given in Table A10 of the Online Appendix. 8 Canada, Germany, Guatemala, Kenya, Mexico, New Zealand, Philippines, Poland and the U.S.. 7

9 3 Price convergence clubs 3.1 A Nonlinear factor model for prices We assume that for each good j the logarithm of prices p ijt in country i at time t is described by a nonlinear factor model proposed by Phillips and Sul (2007). This model includes a price growth component and a time varying idiosyncratic component that allows for general heterogeneity across countries and over time and takes the form of p ijt = δ ijt µ jt, (1) where µ jt is a good specific common trend, which can be deterministic and/or stochastic, with time-varying factor loading coefficients δ ijt that include both country and good specific permanent and transitory components. 9 δ ijt is a vector of weights that describes the transition path of good j in economy i to the common steady state price growth path determined by µ jt. Put differently, these weights can be interpreted as the price gap between the price p ijt and the common trend µ jt. Following Phillips and Sul (2007) we define the concept of relative long-run equilibrium or convergence between two series as follows. 10 each good j means lim k Specifically, relative price convergence for p ijt+k p ljt+k = 1, for all i and l. (2) In the case of the nonlinear factor model in equation (1) the above condition can be expressed in terms of the factor loading coefficients lim δ ijt+k = δ j. (3) k Relative convergence is related to standard convergence definitions used in the empirical growth literature (e.g., Bernard and Durlauf (1995, 1996) and Evans and Karras (1996)). While relative convergence in the discrete time series implies price growth convergence in 9 Equation (1) can be derived from an additive panel model, δ ijt = gij+εijt µjt,, where g ij and ε ijt are the permanent and transitory components, respectively. 10 While the cointegration literature considers the difference or linear combinations between the variables of interest, the idea here is to use their ratio to define a convergence statistic. 8

10 the long-run, it does not generally imply level convergence. Specifically, when the weight δ ijt converges faster than the divergent rate of the common component µ jt in equation (1), then relative convergence implies absolute or level convergence, but otherwise relative convergence does not imply level convergence. 3.2 Transition curves One difficulty is the presence of deterministic and stochastic elements in δ jt that makes its modeling impossible. Phillips and Sul (2007) proposed the relative transition curve, h ijt, that eliminates the common growth component by standardizing the transition element by the cross sectional average h ijt = p ijt N 1 N i=1 p ijt = δ ijt N 1 N i=1 δ. (4) ijt The relative transition curve is a useful tool in understanding the transition dynamics. While these curves may exhibit heterogeneity across countries in the short-run, they allow for convergence in the long-run. In particular, a transition curve measures the price behavior of country i for good j in relation to other economies, and at the same time describes the relative departures of economy i from the common steady-state price growth path µ jt. 11 This means that the presence of divergence from µ jt is reflected in the transition paths h ijt. For example, in the case of global convergence, the price of good j in all countries moves towards the same trend, h ijt 1 for all i as t and the cross-sectional variance of h ijt converges to zero so that the sample transition distance D jt = 1 N N (h ijt 1) 2 0, as t. (5) i=1 By contrast, when an economy diverges from others the transition path can measure the extent of the divergent behavior and assess whether or not this is transient. 11 Following Phillips and Sul (2007, 2009) we first use the Whittaker-Hodrick-Prescott smoothing filter to remove the business cycle component before we apply the log t test. 9

11 3.3 The log t test For each good j, we test for the null of relative convergence versus the alternative of norelative convergence using the log t test of Phillips and Sul (2009) based on the auxiliary least-squares regression log ( D1j D tj ) 2 log log t = λ 0j + λ 1j log t + u tj, (6) for t = [rt ], [rt ] + 1,..., T with some trimming percentage r > 0. For the null of global convergence the test takes the form of a sign restriction on the slope coefficient of log t, H 0 : λ 1j 0 vs. H 1 : λ 1j < 0, which can be tested using a conventional one-sided t-test constructed with a heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation-consistent (HAC) estimator from the residuals of equation (6). The magnitude of the coefficient λ 1j = 2α j measures the convergence speed of δ ijt since the parameter denotes the rate at which the cross-sectional variation across the transition paths decays to zero over time. 12 Under the condition that the common component δ ijt follows a random walk with drift or a trend stationary process, we have growth convergence if 0 λ 1j < 2 and level convergence in log prices if λ 1j Club convergence procedure Rejecting the null of global convergence leaves open the possibility of convergence within some clubs of countries. Following Phillips and Sul (2009), we employ the above test sequentially in subgroups of observations to uncover multiple price regimes. The procedure comprises of four steps: (1) observations are sorted from the latest to the earliest time period of the panel; (2) using the log t test, a primary convergence club is formed against which other countries may be compared; (3) sieving through countries one at a time to check for possible membership of the primary convergence club using the log t regression; (4) repeat steps 2 and 3 and if no further convergence clubs emerge, classify the remaining observations as displaying divergent behavior. In the Online Appendix we provide a detailed description 12 To see this, note that under the null of growth convergence, Phillips and Sul (2007) showed that the (sample) mean square transition distance D jt converges to A/(log(t)) 2 t 2a, where A > 0 is a positive constant. This yields auxiliary equation (6). 10

12 of this clustering procedure. 3.5 Results Price convergence clubs We first document the substantial evidence for lack of global convergence and provide evidence for club convergence by investigating 96 individual goods. Table 1 presents results for the log t-test and for the club convergence procedure, described in sections 3.3 and 3.4 respectively. 13 The first column of Table 1 shows the global convergence coefficient for the whole sample of countries. We find that the null hypothesis of global convergence is rejected for 92 of the 96 goods. 14 In the next four columns of Table 1 we present results of the local convergence coefficients for each club. Our results show the existence of up to four different convergence clubs and that this number varies across goods. 15 For some goods there is a set of countries that do not form any club. We label such subsets of countries for particular goods as divergent, and report the estimated coefficient for such divergent groups of countries in the last column of Table 1. Using the definition of relative convergence, for the majority of goods we find evidence for price growth convergence within clubs since 0 λ 1j < 2. Price level convergence occurs only within the third club and for merely three goods: White rice, Tea bags and Socks, wool mixture, for which the third club is comprised of just two countries. 16 Next, we qualify the above convergence clubs in three alternative ways. First, in the first column of Table 2, we present average prices by good across all countries in the sample, followed by average prices across countries within each club in the remaining columns of the 13 Phillips and Sul (2009) suggest the log t test for t = [rt ], [rt ] + 1,..., T and show that the choice of a trimming percentage r equal to 0.3 is appropriate for samples less than 50 time-series observations. Thus, we start from the 13th time-series observation which leaves 29 time-series observations for the log t test. 14 The exceptions are Personal computer, Peanut or corn oil, Potatoes and Olive oil. For Personal computer, λ 1j exceeds two thus we can infer that price level, not just price growth, convergence occurs. 15 The fourth club exists for nine items: Peas, canned, Instant coffee, Dry cleaning, trousers, Laundry detergent, Toothpaste with fluoride, Men s business shirt, Laundry, Kodak color film, and Razor blades. For razor blades we actually find a fifth club but opt to ignore this in the Tables since it does not arise for any other good or service in our sample. 16 A detailed description of convergence club classifications for every good in our sample is available upon request from the authors, and will also be made available in an Online Appendix. 11

13 table. As we can see, the first club is characterized by the highest price level for each good, the second club by the second highest price and so on. Hence, in what follows, we will refer to the first, second, third, and fourth clubs as high-price, medium-price, low-price, and cheap clubs, respectively. Second, in Table 3 we present the frequency of belonging to each club for each country, i.e., the share of goods for which the country lies in the high-, medium-, low-price, and cheap clubs. We find that a number of developed economies e.g., Denmark, Germany, Finland, Spain, Switzerland, Norway, Belgium, Luxembourg, Australia, Japan, France, UK, Italy, Austria, Sweden, and the US lie in the high-price club for the great majority (for more than 60%) of the goods while lying in the low-price club for less than ten percent of the goods. This is also the case for Turkey and Poland. Figure 1 shows a heatmap for these shares for each country. Here, color defines club (blue for the high-price club, orange for the mediumprice club, green for the low-price club, red for the cheap club, and grey for the divergent group) and depth of color represents frequency of belonging in a certain club. Third, in Table A1 of the Online Appendix we take a closer look at the high-price club, distinguishing between low, medium, and high income countries forming the first club, and present average prices over the period across the subset of countries in each of these three income groups for each good. We observe that average prices vary substantially for some goods within the same club depending on income group. For the sake of brevity we do not provide similar information for the medium, low-price and cheap clubs for each individual good but do undertake this at the industry-level in the next subsection Industry level analysis We now discuss our findings using aggregated prices at the industry level as a way to summarize the information across the various goods. This type of analysis will also allow us to discern whether convergence patterns observed at the individual good level carry over to the industry level. In particular, we aggregate prices up to the industry level and proceed to define clubs for eight separate industries. We organize goods in groups using industry classification ISIC rev 2, calculate the median price across goods in each industry for every country, and use these data to define clubs at the industry level. Then, as in the good level analysis, for each industry we test for global convergence and club convergence. 12

14 Table 4 shows that the industry level results are generally consistent with the goodlevel analysis. Specifically, while the null hypothesis of global convergence is rejected for all industries, we do find evidence of club convergence. For half of the industries, the maximum number of formed clubs equals two (manufacture of food, textile, chemicals and metal products), and for other industries this number equals three (agriculture, paper products, hotel and restaurants, and other services). Moreover, for agriculture and manufacture of paper products there is a set of countries that do not form any club with any other country, thus we also have a divergent group for these industries. Figure 2 presents the set of countries in each convergence club by industry. Table A2 of the Online Appendix provides a detailed description of the convergence club classification for each industry. Figure 3 presents the transition path for each industry and club over time. The relative transition path shows the time variation of the average transition coefficient defined by equation (4) across the countries forming each club for each industry over the period Overall, we find no evidence of global convergence, since we do not observe monotonic convergence to unity for all three clubs for any industry. On the contrary, there is an apparent divergent path for clubs at the end of the period. Moreover, the transition curves shown in Figure 3 illustrate that the first club, irrespective of industry, includes countries with relatively higher prices, while the second and third clubs have smaller prices. For some industries, countries forming different clubs have similar initial states, e.g., agriculture (the second and third club), manufacture of food (the first and second club) and hotel and restaurants (the first and second club), but exhibit transitional divergence starting at some later point in time. For other industries like manufacture of textile or community, social and personal services, transitional divergence appears from the beginning of the period. Interestingly, for most industries, clubs are characterized by converging transitional paths till the middle of the period after which transition paths start to diverge. These time series patterns could then be used to identify factors behind the existence and formation of clubs, e.g., due to specific physical or technological events related to certain industries, that occur at some point in time and affect countries and industries differently. Moreover, the results are consistent with the good-level transition curves presented in Figure A1 of the Online Appendix, albeit the latter are a lot more noisy. The convergence clubs formed at the industry level generally appear to share the same 17 The average transition curve for each club k and each industry h is calculated as ĥkht = 1 where h iht = p iht N 1 N. i=1 p iht Nk N k i=1 h iht, 13

15 characteristics as the ones formed using the individual good level data. For example, the first club is always associated with the highest average price and the third club with the lowest price, as we show in Table A3 of the Online Appendix where we present average prices over the countries and period under study, for each industry in each club. Furthermore, when we distinguish between low, medium, and high income countries that form each club we have identified, we now see that average prices over the period across the subset of countries in each of these three income groups for each industry do not always decline with income. Evidently, for some industries, price convergence clubs are highly associated with country income level while it is clearly not the case for other industries. Figure 4 shows the relationship between average prices and average real GDP per capita (averaged over the period of study) for each of the eight industries. We mark the clubs different countries belong in by different colors. Once again, blue is for the first club, orange for the second club, and green for the third club. We can see that for some industries like agriculture and social and personal services, price convergence clubs are highly associated with country income level, while it is clearly not the case for other industries, e.g., manufacture of food or chemicals. We can infer that income might potentially play a role in the formation of different clubs, at least in the case of some categories of goods. In the next section, we investigate more systematically the role income and other factors might play in determining the convergence clubs. 4 Determinants of convergence clubs 4.1 Threshold regressions and club convergence In this section, we investigate the factors that sort the countries into price convergence clubs. While the nonlinear factor model in equation (1) allowed us to identify convergence clubs using very weak assumptions, it did not allow us to identify the sources of this heterogeneity as this is latent. To do so, we use a threshold regression model, which classifies the countries into price convergence clubs depending on whether the observed value of a threshold variable is above or below a sample split value estimated from the data. 14

16 As threshold variables q sit, s = 1,..., p we use a set of variables that relate to the nontraded or traded components of final goods prices. As proxies for the non-traded component we use initial log real GDP per capita, initial labor productivity, control of corruption and democracy, while for the traded component we use distance and initial prices. The first set of threshold variables, helps us examine whether poorer countries behind the technology frontier tend to exhibit faster price convergence leading to price convergence via the non-traded component of final prices in line with the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis. The second set of threshold variables helps us examine whether countries with smaller distance from potential trade partners or more able to exploit arbitrage opportunities due to lower resistance to trade, exhibit relatively faster price convergence via the traded inputs channel. Using the growth of price in period t for good j in country i, g ijt = p ijt p ijt 1, we specify the following threshold model, which is based on a panel of semiannual price data for 96 goods from 1990 to 2010 across 38 countries. 18 g ijt = µ s1t + α s1i + η s1j + β s1 p ijt 1 + π s1z it + ε ijt = θ s1x ijt + ε ijt, q sit γ s, (7) g ijt = µ s2t + α s2i + η s2j + β s2 p ijt 1 + π s2z it + ε ijt = θ s2x ijt + ε ijt, q sit > γ s, (8) where x ijt = (d i, d j, d t, p ijt 1, z it), with d i, d j and d t country, good, and time dummies. γ s is the scalar threshold parameter or sample split value, µ 1st, α 1si, and η s1j are time, country and good fixed effects respectively, p ijt 1 is the lagged price level, q sit, s = 1,.., p, are threshold variables, and z it is a vector of observable traded and non-traded related explanatory variables that belong to the vector q = [q 1it,..., q pit ] of threshold variables, z it q. This vector includes initial income, initial productivity, distance, control of corruption, democracy, and initial prices. The term ε ijt is the regression error. The slope coefficients β s1 and β s2 are related to the idea of conditional β-convergence or catching up in terms of prices, i.e., the higher the initial absolute price level the lower the price growth rate. Specifically, when β s1 < 0 and β s2 < 0 we say that we have club β-convergence for both regimes. It is convenient to write the above threshold regression model in a single equation using the indicator variable I(q sit γ s ) = 1 if q sit γ s and I(q sit γ s ) = 0 if q sit > γ s. This 18 Hong Kong and Singapore are excluded as data on our threshold variables are not available for these. In models with labor cost as threshold variable, the sample of countries is down to 31 due to limited labor cost data availability. 15

17 yields g ijt = θ sx ijt + δ sx ijt I(q sit γ s ) + e ijt, (9) where δ s = θ s1 θ s2 is the threshold effect and θ s = θ s2. When δ s = 0, the threshold regression model in equation (9) yields the linear model, which Chen, Choi, and Devereux (2008) use to test for β-convergence. The statistical theory for the above model is provided by Hansen (2000) who proposed a concentrated least squares method for the estimation of the threshold parameter. Our test for club convergence involves testing for the presence of threshold effects and unit roots. First, we test for threshold effects using the hypothesis H 0 : δ s = 0 vs. H 1 : δ s 0, i.e., the null hypothesis of a linear model (no threshold effects) against the alternative of a threshold regression model. To do so, we use a heteroskedasticity-autocorrelation consistent Lagrange multiplier (LM) test and compute the p-values by a bootstrap method proposed by Hansen (1996). Second, we test whether the countries converge or diverge using a threshold autoregressive unit root test proposed bycaner and Hansen (2001) and extended for the panel-data model by Beyaert and Camacho (2008). In model (9), if β s1 = β s2 = 0 then we say that the countries diverge. If both parameters are negative, then we have club β- convergence for both regimes. If the countries converge under one regime but not under the other then partial convergence occurs. Finally, we employ the above tests sequentially by testing for threshold effects and unit roots within each of the two subsamples. 4.2 Evidence from threshold regression models Testing for threshold effects and unit root Consistent with the evidence from the non-linear factor model in section 3, we proceed to investigate the presence of up to four convergence clubs using our baseline threshold model which includes initial prices as well as country-, good-, and time-fixed effects as explanatory variables in Table 5. The first two columns of Table 5 describe the threshold variables that define the threshold regression models. In particular, level 1 threshold variables (q 1 ) are used in the two-regime model while level 2 threshold variables (q 2 ) are used in the second-level of the four-regime model. The next six columns present the estimated threshold parameters and the corresponding 95% confidence intervals for the two-regime and four-regime models. 16

18 The results of the threshold and unit root tests are presented as superscripts to the threshold estimate by a significance star and dagger, respectively. The last column reports the Akaike information criterion (AIC). We start by documenting the global divergence of prices, which emerges as a result of the interaction of traded and non-traded factors in the form of threshold effects. Specifically, using sequential testing for the presence of threshold effects as in Hansen (1999), we uncover the presence of four regimes, which we call clubs, in almost all models by rejecting the linear model most of the times at the 1% and in some cases at the 5% significance level. The only exception is when democracy is used as a threshold variable for both levels. Nevertheless, even in this case we find strong evidence for a three-regime model. We also reject the null of unit roots in the context of the threshold regression in all cases at the 1% significance level. According to AIC the strongest evidence for a threshold split occurs when distance is one of the threshold variables. Specifically, the top three models with the lowest AIC values use democracy/distance, distance/initial productivity, and distance/initial income as level 1/level 2 threshold variables. For example, the second best model organizes the countries in four clubs: (C1) distance below and initial productivity below ; (C2) distance below and initial productivity above ; (C3) distance above and initial productivity below ; and (C4) distance above and initial productivity above The distance threshold value corresponds to Turkey, the 18th least distant country in our sample. The initial productivity threshold values and correspond to Spain and Mexico in 1997, the 16th and 21st most productive country in our sample in 1997, respectively Local convergence rates Next, in Table 6, we present the estimated β-coefficients for each club that correspond to the threshold regression models presented in Table 5. The first column ranks the threshold models according to their AIC values and the next two columns describe their corresponding threshold variables. The models are ordered by AIC. The next eight columns show estimates of the β-coefficients and the corresponding speed of price convergence within each club In Table A4 of the Appendix, we present the results of the test for the equality of β-coefficients for each pair of regimes in each model. 17

19 The speed of convergence shows the percentage semi-annual movement of the country to its local steady state relative to the remaining distance. 20 The last column reports the AIC value. We note that we only present unique threshold regression models chosen by AIC. That is, for each pair of threshold variables q 1 and q 2 in Table 5, the sequential testing procedure gives rise to two four-regime threshold models depending on the order with which the threshold variables were chosen to split the sample. We select the model that yields the lowest AIC value and present it in Table 6. This limits the number of models to 21. Consistent with the predictions of theories on multiple steady states, we find strong evidence of club convergence consistent with our earlier unconditional results that were based on the nonlinear factor model. That is, the β-coefficient is always estimated to be negative and strongly significant, implying the presence of club β-convergence in all regimes. This finding holds regardless of the choice of threshold variable. We find a number of theory-relevant results. 21 First, the findings in models 2 and 3 in Table 6 are of particular theoretical interest as these models account for the effect of distance and labor productivity (or income) on price convergence, which respectively capture the traded and non-traded components of final prices on price convergence. These models are respectively ranked as the 2nd and 3rd best according to the AIC. Based on the model with distance and initial labor productivity as threshold variables (model 2), countries in the low distance regime converge faster than countries in the high distance regime as long as they have low initial labor productivity. This suggests that lower distance-related trade costs are conducive to price convergence only for countries that also have the non-traded Balassa-Samuelson catch up process operating in full force given low initial productivity. This might be due to the fact that at an early stage of development, industries stand to gain more from proximity to potential international trade partners whereas this does not appear to matter for industries in advanced economies. This plausibly relates to the fact that the latter produce differentiated products whose demand is not as sensitive to higher transport costs as compared to exports of less differentiated goods from less developed countries. The latter type of goods is characterized by relatively high demand elasticities so that the degree of distance-related trade costs relative to other 20 We calculate the speed of convergence using the coefficient for the initial price level in equations (7) and (8): (1 e λ kt ) = β k, for regime k = 1, 2 and t = 1, where λ k denotes the speed of price convergence. 21 Given that the AIC values are for the most part close to each other, we use the AIC merely as a guidance for the relative strength of each model, emphasizing theory-relevant results. 18

20 potential exporters or domestic producers in a given destination market would play an important role in this case. In addition, we find that within the low distance regime, countries with low initial productivity converge significantly faster than those in the high productivity regime. In the high-distance regime, implied convergence is not significantly higher in the low productivity regime as compared to the high productivity one. This suggests, again, an interaction between the non-traded and traded channels via which price convergence occurs. Being behind the technology frontier appears to be conducive to price convergence, presumably via the Balassa-Samuelson channel, for countries with relatively small physical distance from potential trade partners that have easier access to international trade but not for countries in the high-distance regime. This finding is consistent with economic growth theory models where the growth advantage of initial economic backwardness is greatly facilitated by the ability to trade more cheaply. It points to theories where trade is assigned a key role as facilitator of economic growth, which in turn would lead to faster price convergence rates for initially backward economies as they catch up to the frontier. The finding that price convergence depends on the interaction between the traded and non-traded channels is also preserved when we replace the level 2 threshold variable initial productivity with initial income (model 3 in Table 6). We find that countries in the low distance regime converge faster than those in the high distance regime as long as they have low initial income. We also find that convergence is faster in the low-income regime as compared to the high-income regime irrespective of whether a country lies in the low or high distance regimes. However, the difference in the speed of convergence coefficients is much greater for low versus high income countries in the low distance regime (0.151 versus 0.065) as compared to within the high distance regime (0.090 versus respectively for low and high income regime countries). In any case, the implication is that poorer countries behind the frontier tend to exhibit faster inflation leading to price convergence. This effect is consistent with the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis, according to which prices will increase (and thus converge) faster in poorer countries as they catch-up by growing faster over the period. This form of price convergence occurs via convergence in the non-traded component of final prices. We find similar evidence consistent with this notion in other threshold models we consider with initial income or labor productivity as first or second level threshold variables. That is, the typical finding from such models (models 2, 3, 7, 8, 9, and 11 to 16) is that countries in the low initial income or initial labor productivity regimes are associated with higher implied 19

21 convergence than countries in the respective high regimes. Second, based on the model with distance and initial prices as first and second thresholds respectively (model 10 in Table 6), countries in the low distance regime tend to converge faster than countries in the high distance regime irrespective of initial price regime. The basic result that the low distance regime is associated with faster implied convergence than the high distance regime, is quite common amongst the models we consider with distance as a first or second-level threshold variable (models 1, 2, 3, 5, 6 and 10 in Table 6). Importantly, based on model 10, countries in the low initial prices regime converge faster than those in the high initial prices regime, irrespective of whether they are in the low or high distance regime. In fact, looking at other models with initial prices as second threshold variable (such as models 11, 13, 18, 19 and 21 in Table 6) we see that the coefficients of initial prices are always higher (and significantly so, except for model 21 in the high regime) for low initial price level regime countries as compared to high-regime ones. This implies that countries in the low initial price regime exhibit faster catch up than countries in the high initial price regime. That is, there appears to be an asymmetry in the extent that arbitrage opportunities related to international trade are exploited, with low initial price regime countries exhibiting faster convergence from below than high initial price regime countries exhibit from above. This could be related to the fact that we would typically expect less resistance to exporting (the case of initially cheap countries) than to importing (the case of initially expensive countries) where some local producers and workers stand to lose out. Thus, resistance to international trade and the resulting ability to arbitrage away price differences would be asymmetric, with countries in the low initial price regime facing less resistance and thus better able to exploit arbitrage opportunities via international trade. Furthermore, the results in models 11 and 13 are of particular theory interest as these models capture the effect on price convergence of two variables in each case (labor productivity or income versus initial prices) that map onto the respective non-traded versus traded components of final prices. In the model with labor productivity and initial prices as threshold variables (model 11), countries in the low labor productivity regime converge faster than those in the high productivity regime, irrespective of whether they are in the low or high initial price regime. Furthermore, as we already noted above, countries with lower initial prices converge faster than countries with high initial prices, irrespective of whether a country lies in the low or high productivity regime. Similarly, in the model with initial 20

22 income and initial prices as threshold variables (model 13), countries with low initial income converge faster than countries with high initial income irrespective of the initial price regime they lie in, and countries with lower initial prices converge faster than countries with high prices irrespective of whether they lie in the low or high initial income regime. These results are then consistent with a retail pricing model where final goods prices have a non-traded and traded component related to income (or labor productivity) and initial prices respectively. Third, the institutions-related variable control of corruption appears to be conducive to price convergence. This is evident in model 4 in Table 6 where we use control of corruption with democracy as first and second threshold variables respectively, and in model 5 where we use control of corruption and distance as first and second threshold variables. Using control of corruption and labor productivity as first and second threshold variables respectively (model 7 in Table 6), convergence in the high control of corruption regime is higher than in the low regime as long as the country has low productivity. In addition, for the high but not for the low control of corruption regime, convergence is faster for low initial productivity as compared to high productivity countries. This suggests that being behind the technology frontier appears to be conducive to price convergence, presumably via the Balassa-Samuelson channel, for countries that have good institutions successful in controlling corruption but not for countries in the low control of corruption regime. Similarly, using control of corruption and initial income as the respective first and second threshold variables (model 14), convergence in the high control of corruption regime is higher than in the low regime as long as the country has low initial income. Interestingly, for the high but not for the low control of corruption regime, convergence is significantly faster for low initial income as compared to high income countries, suggesting again that the catch up process operating via the Balassa-Samuelson channel is present for countries that are successful in controlling corruption but not for countries with low control of corruption. In the model with control of corruption and initial prices as threshold variables (model 19 in Table 6), countries with high control of corruption converge faster as long as they have low initial prices. Thus, control of corruption is likely to affect the ability to arbitrage away existing price differences. We would expect that countries with higher control of corruption can more readily rip the benefits of international trade and as a result would tend to exhibit relatively more rapid price convergence. In addition, higher values of this variable could be associated with higher competition in the local market that in turn reinforces price 21

23 convergence. Finally, the basic finding that control of corruption facilitates convergence comes out in model 20 as well, where corruption control enters as both a first and second level threshold variable. Fourth, we find that the best model according to the AIC is the one that splits with democratic accountability and distance. We find that convergence in low democracy regimes is greater than in high democracy regimes irrespective of distance regime. Moreover, within the low democracy regime, countries with smaller distance from potential trade partners converge faster. Typically, in the models with democratic accountability as first threshold variable (models 1, 17 and 18) or as second threshold variable (models 4, 8, 9 and 17) reported in Table 6, convergence in the low democracy regime is higher than in the highdemocracy regime. Models 8 and 9 with initial productivity or income as the respective first threshold variable and democracy as second threshold variable, are of particular interest. For these models, the result that low democracy leads to convergence holds only for the low initial productivity or for the low income regime and is not the case for high productivity or rich countries. The explanation could lie in political pressures that limit Central Bank independence and lead to more expansionary monetary policies resulting in higher inflation in initially backward (proxying for poor institutions that limit the degree of Central Bank independence) countries. Here, faster convergence would not coincide with higher market integration but would just be an unintended consequence of policies leading to higher inflation in initially poor countries with initially lower prices. 4.3 Further results In addition to our baseline results presented above, we consider two further exercises using alternative samples and model specifications. First, we present threshold regression estimation results that use labor cost as a threshold variable in Table 7. This variable, however, restricts the sample to 31 countries due to data unavailability. 22 As for our baseline sample, we reject the null hypothesis of global β-convergence and find strong evidence for club convergence. The best model according to the AIC, is the model that splits with labor cost (level 1) and democracy (level 2). In this case, we can see that countries in the low labor cost regime exhibit faster implied convergence than those in the high labor cost 22 For brevity, we show the threshold tests in Table A7 of the Online Appendix. 22

24 regime. Moreover, we can see that countries in the low democracy regime exhibit faster implied convergence than those in the high democracy regime, but only as long as they are in the low labor cost regime. This finding resembles the result discussed earlier regarding low democracy regime countries with low initial income or low initial labor productivity. The second best model shown in Table 7 which splits using distance (level 1) and labor cost (level 2) is, however, the most theoretically appealing one. This model shows that within the low distance regime, countries with lower labor cost converge significantly faster than countries with high labor cost. This resembles the result for labor productivity in model 2 of Table 6, and is again suggestive of an interaction between the non-traded and traded channels via which price convergence occurs. Moreover, countries with low distance tend to converge faster than those with high distance from potential trade partners as long as they have lower labor cost. This result resembles the findings for labor productivity and initial income in models 2 and 3 from Table 6. It makes good sense as distance matters for trade and countries with lower labor costs might be more able to engage successfully in international trade. For example, countries with lower labor costs might face less political resistance in engaging in international trade than countries with high labor costs where some local players would lose out from engaging in international trade. The remaining theoretically interesting models in Table 7 are models 5 and 7, which include labor cost as second threshold with control of corruption or initial prices as the respective first threshold variables. Results for model 5 in Table 7 suggest that control of corruption helps convergence for countries with low labor cost, and that countries with low labor costs converge significantly faster than those with high labor cost as long as they have high control of corruption. Both of these results resemble what we saw in the case of initial productivity and initial income in models 7 and 14 respectively shown in Table 6. Results for model 7 in Table 7 where labor cost enters as second threshold variable and initial prices as first threshold variable, resemble those from models 11 and 13 in Table 6 where initial prices enter as second threshold variable with initial productivity and initial income as the respective first threshold variables. That is, countries with low labor costs converge faster than countries with high labor costs irrespective of the initial price regime they lie in, and countries with lower initial prices converge faster than countries with high prices irrespective of whether they lie in the low or high labor cost regime. These findings are again consistent with a retail pricing model where final goods prices have a non-traded 23

25 and traded component related to labor cost and initial prices, respectively. In the second exercise further to our baseline results, we use our baseline sample to estimate the threshold regression model in equations 7 and 8 by including initial income, control of corruption and democracy in addition to initial prices and fixed effects. 23 We present the estimation for the augmented threshold regressions in Table In general, we find that for factors related to the non-traded component of final prices, high values of initial income, labor productivity and democratic accountability hinder convergence, while high control of corruption reinforces convergence. Similarly, factors related to the traded component of final prices such as distance and initial prices have a suppressing effect on price convergence, i.e., countries with higher distance or higher initial prices tend to have lower convergence rates Classification of countries in convergence clubs In this section we attempt to classify the countries in various convergence clubs using information from threshold regressions based on our baseline sample. In the four panels of Figure 5, we present the countries that belong to the various regimes using cross-plots between the two threshold variables q 1 and q 2 for four of the best models from Table 6 that include pairs of variables capturing respectively each of the two theoretically distinct components of final prices. These four models include distance to capture the traded component in each case, and labor productivity, initial income or institutions to capture the non-traded component of final prices. Specifically, we consider Model 1 with q 1 =Democracy and q 2 =Distance in Panel (a); Model 2 with q 1 =Distance and q 2 =Initial Productivity in Panel (b); Model 3 with q 1 =Distance and q 2 =Initial Income in Panel (c); and Model 5 with q 1 =Control of Corruption and q 2 =Distance in Panel (d). We calculate the share of years for which the country lies in one of the regimes and obtain frequencies of forming a regime for each country in each model. If the country lies in one of the regimes for more than 50% of the period, then it is classified in that regime. 23 Initial productivity was excluded from the vector z it due to multicollinearity issues. Distance is also not included since it is a country-specific variable and the model includes country fixed effects. 24 Threshold tests and tests for the equality of the -coefficients for each pair of the regimes in each model are given in Tables A5 and A6 of the Online Appendix, respectively. 25 We also estimate the augmented threshold regression models using the restricted sample of countries that include labor cost. The results are similar and can be found in Tables A7 and A8 of the Online Appendix. 24

26 There are four possibilities marked by different colors: blue denotes dismal conditions in both variables; orange denotes bad conditions in q 1 but good conditions in q 2 ; green denotes good conditions in q 1 and bad q 2 conditions; and red denotes good conditions for both q 1 and q The size of the circles shows speed of convergence within each regime. Overall, the results verify at the country level the findings described in Table 6. The best regime, that is, the regime with the most favorable economic conditions in both threshold variables, typically includes most of the European countries while the bad regime typically comprises Latin American and South East Asian countries. Interestingly, other high income countries such as the US, Canada and Japan appear to belong to intermediate regimes, which are only partially characterized by favorable conditions. Moreover, these regimes exhibit substantial differences in their convergence rates to their local long run equilibria. In particular, Panel (a) shows that countries with low democracy and low distance (in orange) appear to have the highest convergence pace. Panels (b) and (c) exhibit similar patterns. They show that countries (in green) with low distance and low initial income or productivity converge faster than other countries. Finally, Panel (d) shows that countries (in red) with high control of corruption and low distance converge faster than the rest. In general, our results in this section imply a similar classification of countries to the one based on the nonlinear factor model in Table For example, countries that lie in the threshold regime described by the best conditions (both threshold variables reflecting good conditions) for more than 50% of models, i.e., the Netherlands, Norway, Luxembourg, Switzerland, Sweden, Finland, Denmark, Austria, Germany, UK, Belgium, France, Spain and Australia, are countries that lie in the high-price club for more than 50% of the goods in our sample. Similarly, the majority of countries that lie in the threshold regime with worst conditions for more than 50% of the estimated models, i.e., Panama, Philippines, Guatemala, Thailand, Colombia, Peru, South Africa, Uruguay, Venezuela, Brazil, Paraguay and Kenya, are countries that lie in the medium or low price clubs for more than 50% of the goods in 26 Except for distance and initial prices, for most threshold variables low values reflect bad economic conditions and high values good economic conditions. Thus, good conditions for q i typically correspond to the high q i regime obtained in the threshold models, except in the case of distance and initial prices where good conditions correspond to the low q i regime in the threshold models. 27 This is shown in Table A9 of the appendix where we present country-specific frequencies of forming a regime based on the 36 estimated threshold regression models from Table 6. As in Figure 5, we calculate the share of years for which the country lies in one of the regimes and obtain frequencies of forming each regime for each country in each model. Then, using these frequencies we compute the share of models for which the country lies in each of the regimes. 25

27 our sample. 5 Conclusion We have investigated the existence of convergence clubs in the cross-country mechanism of retail prices using a sample of 96 goods in 40 countries for 1990 to 2010 at the semi-annual frequency, by doing two things. First, we employ a nonlinear factor model that distinguishes between economies that have converged and those that are converging. While we do not find evidence of global price convergence, we do find strong evidence of convergence clubs. Second, we examine the factors that determine price convergence clubs using a threshold regression methodology which allows us to model the determinants of convergence clubs using observed threshold variables related to traded and non-traded factors, and to estimate regime-specific β-coefficients common within regimes. These regime-specific estimated coefficients map onto local rates of convergence consistent with a local law of one price. In line with our findings based on the nonlinear factor model, we find strong evidence of club convergence. We reject the null of global β convergence, typically in favor of four convergence clubs which are due to traded and non-traded factors and the interaction between these. These factors can be viewed as barriers to global price convergence that organize countries into price convergence clubs. Here, different price convergence regimes arise both due to factors associated with convergence in the non-traded component of final prices related to non-traded input cost differences across countries (e.g., income, labor productivity or labor cost) and due to convergence in the traded component of final prices (e.g., physical distance or initial prices), consistent with a retail pricing model where traded and non-traded inputs comprise the final good. Our results are suggestive of the economic mechanisms that are at work here. With either initial income or initial productivity as one of the threshold variables, implied convergence rates for the low regime are typically higher than for the high regime, consistent with the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis and convergence via the non-traded component of final prices. With physical distance or initial prices as thresholds, implied convergence is typically higher in the low regime than in the high regime, suggesting that countries with smaller distance from potential trade partners and those more able to exploit arbitrage opportunities experience faster convergence Future work would do well to focus on structural threshold regression models that account for 26

28 Importantly, our findings point to interactions between the non-traded and traded channels via which price convergence occurs. First, countries in the low distance regime converge faster than countries in the high distance regime if they have low initial labor productivity, low labor input costs or low initial income. Second, countries with low initial productivity or low labor input costs converge significantly faster than those in the respective high productivity or high labor cost regimes, if characterized by low average distance from trade partners. In the first instance, lower trade costs appear to be conducive to price convergence for countries that have the non-traded Balassa-Samuelson catch up process operating given low initial productivity, labor cost or initial income levels. This might be due to the fact that at an early stage of development, industries stand to gain more from proximity to potential international trade partners whereas this does not appear to matter for industries in advanced economies producing highly differentiated products whose demand is not as sensitive to higher trade costs as compared to exports of less differentiated goods from less developed countries. In the second instance, being behind the technology frontier appears to be more conducive to price convergence for countries with relatively small physical distance from potential trade partners that have easier access to international trade than for countries in the high-distance regime. This finding is consistent with economic growth theory models where the growth advantage of initial economic backwardness is greatly facilitated by the ability to trade more cheaply. It points to theories where trade is assigned a key role as facilitator of economic growth, which in turn would lead to faster price convergence rates for initially backward economies as they catch up to the frontier. In addition, we find an asymmetry in the extent that arbitrage opportunities related to international trade are exploited, with low initial price regime countries exhibiting faster convergence from below than high initial price regime countries exhibit from above. This can be explained by lower resistance to exporting (the case of initially cheap countries) than to importing (the case of initially expensive countries) where some local producers and workers stand to lose out, so that resistance to international trade and the resulting ability to arbitrage away price differences is rendered asymmetric, with countries in the low initial price regime facing less resistance and thus better able to exploit arbitrage opportunities via international trade. endogeneity, e.g. Kourtellos, Stengos, and Tan (2015), and can potentially be used to identify such mechanisms. 27

29 Our results are important for two different strands of the literature. First, they relate to the price convergence literature where no previous study has shown the presence of multiple regimes we find here. Second, our results relate to the literature on club convergence which has focused on assessing economic growth regimes. Our detection of multiple regimes and the relevance of a number of factors in determining these shown here, suggest that there is much to be learned regarding club convergence by focusing on prices in addition to real GDP per capita. 28

30 References Alessandria, G., 2009, Consumer Search, Price Dispersion and International Relative Price Fluctuations, International Economic Review 50, , and J. P. Kaboski, 2011, Pricing-to-Market and the Failure of Absolute PPP, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3, Andrade, P., and M. Zachariadis, 2016, Global Versus Local Shocks in Micro Price Dynamics, Journal of International Economics 98, Bergin, P., R. Glick, and J. Wu, 2013, The Micro-Macro Disconnect of Purchasing Power Parity, Review of Economics and Statistics 95, Bernard, A.B, and S. N. Durlauf, 1995, Convergence in International Output, Journal of Applied Econometrics 10, , 1996, Interpreting Tests of the Convergence Hypothesis, Journal of Econometrics 71, Beyaert, A., and M. Camacho, 2008, TAR Panel Unit Root Tests and Real Convergence, Review of Development Economics 12, Brock, W., and C. Hommes, 1997, A Rational Route to Randomness, Econometrica 65, Burstein, A., and N. Jaimovich, 2009, Understanding Movements in Aggregate and Product- Level Real Exchange Rates, unpublished manuscript Stanford and UCLA. Caner, M., and B. Hansen, 2001, Threshold Autoregression with a Unit Root, Econometrica 69, Canova, F., 2004, Testing for Convergence Clubs in Income Per Capita: A Predictive Density Approach, International Economic Review 45, Chen, L., S. Choi, and J. Devereux, 2008, Have Absolute Price Levels Converged for Developed Economies? The Evidence since 1870, The Review of Economics and Statistics 90,

31 Choi, C.-Y., A. Murphy, and J. Wu, 2015, Segmentation of Consumer Markets in the U.S.: What Do Intercity Price Differences Tell Us?, Working Paper, University of Texas. Corsetti, G., and L. Dedola, 2005, Macroeconomics of International Price Discrimination, Journal of International Economics 67, Crucini, M., and M. Shintani, 2008, Persistence in Law of One Price Deviations: Evidence from Micro-Data, Journal of Monetary Economics 55, Crucini, M., C. Telmer, and M. Zachariadis, 2005, Understanding European Real Exchange Rates, American Economic Review 95, Dixit, A., 1989, Hysteresis, Import Penetration and Exhange Rate Pass-Through, Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, Dumas, B., 1992, Dynamic Equilibrium and the Real Exchange Rate in a Spatially Separated World, The Review of Financial Studies 5, Durlauf, S., and P. Johnson, 1995, Multiple Regimes and Cross-Country Growth Behavior, Journal of Applied Econometrics 10, Durlauf, S., A. Kourtellos, and A. Minkin, 2001, The Local Solow Growth Model, European Economic Review 45, Evans, P., and G. Karras, 1996, Convergence Revisited, Journal of Monetary Economics 37, Galor, O., 1996, Convergence? Inferences from Theoretical Models, The Economic Journal 106, Goldberg, P., and F. Verboven, 2005, Market Integration and Convergence to the Law of One Price: Evidence from the European Car Market, Journal of International Economics 65, Gopinath, G., 2015, The International Price System, Jackson Hole Symposium Proceedings (forthcoming). Hansen, B., 2000, Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation, Econometrica 68, Hansen, B. E., 1996, Inference When a Nuisance Parameter Is Not Identified Under the Null Hypothesis, Econometrica 64,

32 Hobijn, B., and P. H. Franses, 2000, Asymptotically Perfect and Relative Convergence of Productivity, Journal of Applied Econometrics 15, Imbs, J., H. Mumtaz, M. Ravn, and H. Rey, 2003, Nonlinearities and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of the European Economic Association 1, , 2005, PPP Strikes Back: Aggregation and the Real Exchange Rate, Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, Kourtellos, A., T. Stengos, and C. M. Tan, 2015, Structural Threshold Regression, Econometric Theory (forthcoming). Krugman, P. R., 1989, Exchange Rate Instability (MIT: Cambridge). Lee, I., and J. Shin, 2010, Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in the Presence of Nontraded Goods and Transaction Costs, Economics Letters 106, Liu, Z., and T. Stengos, 1999, Non-linearities in Cross Country Growth Regressions: A Semiparametric Approach, Journal of Applied Econometrics 14, Masanjala, W., and C. Papageorgiou, 2004, The Solow Model with CES Technology: Monlinearities and Parameter Heterogeneity, Journal of Applied Econometrics 19, Michael, P., R. Nobay, and A. Peel, 1997, Transaction Costs and Non-linear Adjustment in Real Exchange Rates: An Empirical Investigation., Journal of Political Economy 105, Midrigan, V., 2007, International Price Dispersion in State-Dependent Pricing Models, Journal of Monetary Economics 54, Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff, 2001, The Six Major Puzzles in International Macroeconomics: Is There a Common Cause?, in B. S. Bernanke, and K. Rogoff, ed.: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000,vol. 15. pp (MIT Press: Cambridge). Obstfeld, M., and A.M. Taylor, 1989, Hysteresis, Import Penetration and Exhange Rate Pass-Through, Journal of Japanese and International Economics 11, O Connell, P.G.J., and S.-J. Wei, 2002, The Bigger They Are, the Harder They Fall: Retail Price Differences across US Cities, Journal of International Economics 56,

33 Phillips, P., and D. Sul, 2007, Transition Modeling and Econometric Convergence Tests, Econometrica 75, , 2009, Economic Transition and Growth, Journal of Applied Econometrics 24, Sarno, L. Taylor, M. P. Chowdhury I., 2004, Nonlinear Dynamics in Deviations from the Law of One Price: a Broad-Based Empirical Study, Journal of International Money and Finance 23, Sercu, P., R. Uppal, and C. Van Hulle, 1995, The Exchange Rate in the Presence of Transaction Costs: Implications for Tests of Purchasing Power Parity, The Journal of Finance 50, Tan, C., 2010, No One True Path: Uncovering the Interplay Between Geography, Institutions, and Fractionalization in Economic Development, Journal of Applied Econometrics 25, Taylor, M. P., D. A. Peel, and L. Sarno, 2001, Nonlinear Mean-Reversion in Real Exchange Rates: Toward a Solution to the Purchasing Power Parity Puzzles, International Economic Review 42, Young, A., 2000, The Razor s Edge: Distortions and Incremental Reform in the People s Republic of China, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115,

34 Figure 1: Heatmap for Clubs by Country This figure shows a heatmap of the frequency of a country to form a club for the countries in our sample. Color defines club with blue, orange, green and red colors standing respectively for the high-price, medium-price, low-price and cheap clubs. Depth of color represents frequency of belonging in a certain club. 33

35 Figure 2: Price Convergence Clubs by Industry This figure shows a geographical map of countries that belong to the various convergence clubs by industry. Color defines club: blue, orange, green and red colors stand respectively for the high-price, medium-price, low-price and cheap clubs. 34

Convergence in consumption habits: what goods and services are more likely to experience growth in Spain in the future?

Convergence in consumption habits: what goods and services are more likely to experience growth in Spain in the future? February 18, 2010 Convergence in consumption habits: what goods and services are more likely to experience growth in Spain in the future? The growing international integration of the markets in goods and

More information

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Preliminary version Abstract This paper

More information

Trend inflation, inflation targets and inflation expectations

Trend inflation, inflation targets and inflation expectations Trend inflation, inflation targets and inflation expectations Discussion of papers by Adam & Weber, Slobodyan & Wouters, and Blanco Argia Sbordone ECB Conference Understanding Inflation: lessons from the

More information

Price-Level Convergence: New Evidence from U.S. Cities

Price-Level Convergence: New Evidence from U.S. Cities Price-Level Convergence: New Evidence from U.S. Cities by M. Ege Yazgan Hakan Yilmazkuday Department of Economics DETU Working Paper 10-11 September 2010 1301 Cecil B. Moore Avenue, Philadelphia, PA 19122

More information

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria Mariya Neycheva Burgas Free University April 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/55633/ MPRA Paper

More information

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many THE HOUSEHOLD SECTOR IN THE SMETS-WOUTERS DSGE MODEL: COMPARISONS WITH THE STANDARD OPTIMAL GROWTH MODEL L. Tesfatsion, Econ 502, Fall 2014 Last Revised: 19 November 2014 Basic References: [1] ** L. Tesfatsion,

More information

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence Mariya Neycheva * 1. Introduction The economics of growth is one of the most popular fields of study in both theoretical and empirical

More information

International Price Dispersion and the Direction of Trade

International Price Dispersion and the Direction of Trade International Price Dispersion and the Direction of Trade Ozlem Inanc Department of Economics Louisiana State University Baton Rouge, LA 70803 oinanc1@lsu.edu Marios Zachariadis Department of Economics

More information

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Beyond balanced growth 11 PartA Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Uwe Sunde and Thomas Vischer Abstract: Human capital plays a central role in theoretical

More information

A note on power comparison of panel tests of cointegration An application on. health expenditure and GDP

A note on power comparison of panel tests of cointegration An application on. health expenditure and GDP A note on power comparison of panel tests of cointegration An application on health expenditure and GDP Giorgia Marini * This version, 2007 July * Centre for Health Economics, University of York, YORK,

More information

Managing Trade: Evidence from China and the US

Managing Trade: Evidence from China and the US Managing Trade: Evidence from China and the US Nick Bloom, Stanford Kalina Manova, Stanford and Oxford Stephen Sun, Peking University John Van Reenen, LSE Zhihong Yu, Nottingham SCID / IGC : Trade, Productivity,

More information

Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs

Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs Sustainable Development and Planning V 947 Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs M. Asali Petroleum Studies Department, Research Division, OPEC,

More information

Communication Costs and Agro-Food Trade in OECD. Countries. Štefan Bojnec* and Imre Fertő** * Associate Professor, University of Primorska, Faculty of

Communication Costs and Agro-Food Trade in OECD. Countries. Štefan Bojnec* and Imre Fertő** * Associate Professor, University of Primorska, Faculty of The 83rd Annual Conference of the Agricultural Economics Society Dublin 30th March to 1st April 2009 Communication Costs and Agro-Food Trade in OECD Countries Štefan Bojnec* and Imre Fertő** * Associate

More information

The Decision to Import

The Decision to Import March 2010 The Decision to Import Mark J. Gibson Washington State University Tim A. Graciano Washington State University ABSTRACT Why do some producers choose to use imported intermediate inputs while

More information

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping *

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping * Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping * Francisco A. Gallego Christian A. Johnson December Abstract This article generates innovative

More information

FACTOR-AUGMENTED VAR MODEL FOR IMPULSE RESPONSE ANALYSIS

FACTOR-AUGMENTED VAR MODEL FOR IMPULSE RESPONSE ANALYSIS Nicolae DĂNILĂ, PhD The Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies E-mail: nicolae.danila@fin.ase.ro Andreea ROŞOIU, PhD Student The Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies E-mail: andreea.rosoiu@yahoo.com FACTOR-AUGMENTED

More information

Structural versus Reduced Form

Structural versus Reduced Form Econometric Analysis: Hausman and Leonard (2002) and Hosken et al (2011) Class 6 1 Structural versus Reduced Form Empirical papers can be broadly classified as: Structural: Empirical specification based

More information

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010 Technical Appendix Resolution of the canonical RBC Model Master EPP, 2010 Questions What are the causes of macroeconomic fluctuations? To what extent optimal intertemporal behavior of households in a walrasssian

More information

Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1

Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1 Submitted on 19/Jan./2011 Article ID: 1923-7529-2011-03-46-06 Claudia Kurz and Jeong-Ryeol Kurz-Kim Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1 Claudia Kurz University of Applied Sciences

More information

Regional Relative Price Disparities and Their Driving Forces

Regional Relative Price Disparities and Their Driving Forces PISSN 2508-1640 EISSN 2508-1667 an open access journal East Asian Economic Review vol. 21, no.3 (September 2017) 201-230 http://dx.doi.org/10.11644/kiep.eaer.2017.21.3.329 Regional Relative Price Disparities

More information

Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series. No Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path

Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series. No Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series No. 2007-7 Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path Yukio Fukumoto December 2007 Reexamination of Dornbusch

More information

Seminar Master Major Financial Economics : Quantitative Methods in Finance

Seminar Master Major Financial Economics : Quantitative Methods in Finance M. Sc. Theoplasti Kolaiti Leibniz University Hannover Seminar Master Major Financial Economics : Quantitative Methods in Finance Winter Term 2018/2019 Please note: The seminar paper should be 15 pages

More information

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2011

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2011 Technical Appendix Resolution of the canonical RBC Model Master EPP, 2011 1. Basic real business cycle model: Productivity shock and Consumption/saving Trade-off 1.1 Agents behavior Set-up Infinitively-lived

More information

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow, Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Guelph, Canada and Lecturer, WFP

More information

A THRESHOLD COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS OF ASYMMETRIC ADJUSTMENTS IN THE GHANAIAN MAIZE MARKETS. Henry de-graft Acquah, Senior Lecturer

A THRESHOLD COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS OF ASYMMETRIC ADJUSTMENTS IN THE GHANAIAN MAIZE MARKETS. Henry de-graft Acquah, Senior Lecturer A THRESHOLD COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS OF ASYMMETRIC ADJUSTMENTS IN THE GHANAIAN MAIZE MARKETS ABSTRACT Henry de-graft Acquah, Senior Lecturer University of Cape Coast, Cape Coast, Ghana Phone: +00233245543956,

More information

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture Jody L. Campiche Henry L. Bryant Agricultural and Food Policy Center Agricultural and Food Policy Center Department

More information

SECTORAL GDP CONVERGENCE OF SELECTED RCEP COUNTRIES: LEAD OR LAGS?

SECTORAL GDP CONVERGENCE OF SELECTED RCEP COUNTRIES: LEAD OR LAGS? International Journal of Business and Society, Vol. 18 S2, 2017, 669-676 SECTORAL GDP CONVERGENCE OF SELECTED RCEP COUNTRIES: LEAD OR LAGS? Md. Mahbubur Rahman Universiti Malaysia Sarawak Dayang Affizah

More information

Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth

Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth Methodology to estimate the effect of energy efficiency on growth Report prepared for The Climate Institute March 2013 2 Contents 1 Introduction... 5 2 Energy efficiency and economic growth... 7 3 Data...

More information

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence ECB - BoC Workshop : Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment 15-16 June 2011 Christiane Baumeister Ehsan U. Choudhri Lawrence Schembri

More information

U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics

U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics U.S. Trade and Inventory Dynamics By GEORGE ALESSANDRIA, JOSEPH P. KABOSKI, VIRGILIU MIDRIGAN We examine the substantial drop and rebound in international trade by the U.S. 1 in the period 2008 to 2010,

More information

ISSN Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports. Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology

ISSN Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports. Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology ISSN 1835-9728 Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports Modelling the Global Diffusion of Energy Efficiency and Low Carbon Technology David I. Stern Research Report No. 20 February 2009 About

More information

The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach

The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach The Impact of Building Energy Codes on the Energy Efficiency of Residential Space Heating in European countries A Stochastic Frontier Approach Aurélien Saussay, International Energy Agency, Paris, France

More information

Higher Education and Economic Development in the Balkan Countries: A Panel Data Analysis

Higher Education and Economic Development in the Balkan Countries: A Panel Data Analysis 1 Further Education in the Balkan Countries Aristotle University of Thessaloniki Faculty of Philosophy and Education Department of Education 23-25 October 2008, Konya Turkey Higher Education and Economic

More information

Exchange Rate Determination of Bangladesh: A Cointegration Approach. Syed Imran Ali Meerza 1

Exchange Rate Determination of Bangladesh: A Cointegration Approach. Syed Imran Ali Meerza 1 Journal of Economic Cooperation and Development, 33, 3 (2012), 81-96 Exchange Rate Determination of Bangladesh: A Cointegration Approach Syed Imran Ali Meerza 1 In this paper, I propose and estimate a

More information

Supplementary Materials for. Reckoning wheat yield trends

Supplementary Materials for. Reckoning wheat yield trends Supplementary Materials for Reckoning wheat yield trends Marena Lin and Peter Huybers Department of Earth and Planetary Sciences Harvard University Oxford St., Cambridge MA, 8 Contents Replicating interannual

More information

Multiple Equilibria and Selection by Learning in an Applied Setting

Multiple Equilibria and Selection by Learning in an Applied Setting Multiple Equilibria and Selection by Learning in an Applied Setting Robin S. Lee Ariel Pakes February 2, 2009 Abstract We explore two complementary approaches to counterfactual analysis in an applied setting

More information

Has the Euro Shrunk the Band? Price Convergence in a Currency Union

Has the Euro Shrunk the Band? Price Convergence in a Currency Union Has the Euro Shrunk the Band? Price Convergence in a Currency Union Luca Macedoni Aarhus University January 2018 Abstract I study the effects of the European Monetary Union (EMU) on price convergence using

More information

FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED?

FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED? Interdisciplinary Description of Complex Systems 16(3-B), 504-523, 2018 FORECASTING LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER STATES: IS LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY CHANGING AS EXPECTED? Berislav Žmuk*,

More information

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK. University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics Field Exam January 2017 Labor Economics There are three parts of the exam. Please answer all three parts. You should plan to spend about one hour

More information

Price level convergence and competition in the euro area

Price level convergence and competition in the euro area Price level convergence and competition in the euro area This article provides an overview of the extent of price level differences in the euro area and outlines the main factors behind them. While a degree

More information

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Jan Van Hove, Sophie Soete and Zuzanna Studnicka University of Leuven Document Identifier D5.10 Case Study on Belgian business succession practices

More information

Microeconomic Flexibility in India and Pakistan: Employment. Adjustment at the Firm Level

Microeconomic Flexibility in India and Pakistan: Employment. Adjustment at the Firm Level The Lahore Journal of Economics 14: SE (September 2009): pp. 17-27 Microeconomic Flexibility in and Pakistan: Employment Theresa Chaudhry * Abstract Adjustment at the Firm Level In this paper, we look

More information

The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries

The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries The Effect of Information and Communication Technology on Energy Consumption in the European Union Countries Çiğdem Börke TUNALI Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics, Istanbul University, Merkez

More information

How do different exporters react to exchange rate changes? Theory, empirics and aggregate implications

How do different exporters react to exchange rate changes? Theory, empirics and aggregate implications How do different exporters react to exchange rate changes? Theory, empirics and aggregate implications Nicolas Berman Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies (Geneva) Philippe Martin

More information

Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita?

Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita? Do cognitive skills Impact Growth or Levels of GDP per Capita? March 2, 2017 Abstract The Great Recession has raised concerns about future economic growth. A possible remedy that was suggested was an educational

More information

The Law of One Price and the Role of Market Structure

The Law of One Price and the Role of Market Structure The Law of One Price and the Role of Market Structure Mustafa Caglayan University of Sheffield, UK Alpay Filiztekin Sabanci University, Turkey February 27, 2012 Abstract This paper examines the role of

More information

Internet, gravity model, international trade, margins of trade, linguistic distance, religious distance

Internet, gravity model, international trade, margins of trade, linguistic distance, religious distance Title: The effect of the internet on the margins of trade Abstract This paper investigates the effect of internet use on the extensive and intensive margins of trade, and assesses whether the internet

More information

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China Auburn University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China Liping Gao and Hyeongwoo Kim Georgia Southern University; Auburn University

More information

Does the Color of the Collar Matter? Firm Specific Human Capital and Post-Displacement Outcomes

Does the Color of the Collar Matter? Firm Specific Human Capital and Post-Displacement Outcomes DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3617 Does the Color of the Collar Matter? Firm Specific Human Capital and Post-Displacement Outcomes Guido Schwerdt Andrea Ichino Oliver Ruf Rudolf Winter-Ebmer Josef

More information

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services By Ian Small of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. This article (1) reviews how price-cost mark-ups

More information

A simple model for low flow forecasting in Mediterranean streams

A simple model for low flow forecasting in Mediterranean streams European Water 57: 337-343, 2017. 2017 E.W. Publications A simple model for low flow forecasting in Mediterranean streams K. Risva 1, D. Nikolopoulos 2, A. Efstratiadis 2 and I. Nalbantis 1* 1 School of

More information

THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DOMESTIC PRIVATE CONSUMPTION AND WHOLESALE PRICES: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN UNION

THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DOMESTIC PRIVATE CONSUMPTION AND WHOLESALE PRICES: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN UNION THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DOMESTIC PRIVATE CONSUMPTION AND WHOLESALE PRICES: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN UNION Nikolaos Dritsakis, Antonios Adamopoulos Abstract The purpose of this paper is to investigate

More information

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Karoll GOMEZ kgomezp@unal.edu.co http://karollgomez.wordpress.com Primer semestre 2016 I. Introduction Content: 1. General overview 2. Times-Series vs Cross-section

More information

Web Appendix. Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets

Web Appendix. Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets Web Appendix Oligopolistic Markets with Sequential Search and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Retail Gasoline Markets Maarten Janssen Paul Pichler Simon Weidenholzer 28th July 2010 Department of

More information

7. The contribution of human capital to growth: some estimates

7. The contribution of human capital to growth: some estimates Bas van Leeuwen Human Capital and Economic Growth 7. The contribution of human capital to growth: some estimates 1. INTRODUCTION So far we have noted that human capital seems to affect economic growth

More information

The energy consumption-gdp nexus: Panel data evidence from 88 countries

The energy consumption-gdp nexus: Panel data evidence from 88 countries MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The energy consumption-gdp nexus: Panel data evidence from 88 countries Dipendra Sinha Ritsumeikan Asia Pacific University, Japan and Macquarie University, Australia

More information

What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact?

What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact? What STIRPAT tells about effects of population and affluence on environmental impact? Taoyuan Wei 1 July 21, 2010 Abstract In the literature of STIRPAT application to environmental impacts of population

More information

ARE MALAYSIAN EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? A COMMENT

ARE MALAYSIAN EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? A COMMENT Sunway Academic Journal 2, 101 107 (2005) ARE MALAYSIAN EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? A COMMENT TANG TUCK CHEONG a Monash University Malaysia ABSTRACT This commentary aims to provide an insight on

More information

Chapter 8.B. Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications. Robert A. McDougall

Chapter 8.B. Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications. Robert A. McDougall Chapter 8.B Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications Robert A. McDougall 8.B.1 Overview Some local modifications were made to the agricultural and food products (AFP) dataset described in chapter

More information

A rm s-length transfer prices for the remuneration of

A rm s-length transfer prices for the remuneration of 1164 (Vol. 25, No. 20) BNA INSIGHTS Cost Plus Markups for Manufacturing Entities: The Effect of Size on Fully Loaded Versus Variable Costs The authors analyze the statistical and economic significance

More information

Pass-Through Effects of Global Food Prices on Consumer Prices in Iran

Pass-Through Effects of Global Food Prices on Consumer Prices in Iran Iran. Econ. Rev. Vol. 21, No.1, 2017. pp. 169-180 Pass-Through Effects of Global Food Prices on Consumer Prices in Iran Ebrahim Javdan* 1, Jafar Haghighat 2, Esmaeil Pishbahar 3, Phillip Kostov 4, Rassul

More information

Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong

Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong Vehicle Controls and Petrol Demand in Hong Kong W. David Walls School of Economics and Finance University of Hong Kong Pokfulam Road Hong Kong Tel: 852 2859 1049 Fax: 852 2548 1152 Email: wdwalls@hkusub.hku.hk

More information

The US dollar exchange rate and the demand for oil

The US dollar exchange rate and the demand for oil The US dollar exchange rate and the demand for oil Selien De Schryder Ghent University Gert Peersman Ghent University BoE, CAMA and MMF Workshop on Understanding Oil and Commodity Prices" 25 May 2012 Motivation

More information

THE ROLE OF NESTED DATA ON GDP FORECASTING ACCURACY USING FACTOR MODELS *

THE ROLE OF NESTED DATA ON GDP FORECASTING ACCURACY USING FACTOR MODELS * Andrejs Bessonovs University of Latvia, Latvia THE ROLE OF NESTED DATA ON GDP FORECASTING ACCURACY USING FACTOR MODELS * Abstract The paper studies an impact of nested macroeconomic data on Latvian GDP

More information

BEHAVIORAL ANALYSIS OF NON-DURABLE CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES: A CASE STUDY OF WAH CANTT

BEHAVIORAL ANALYSIS OF NON-DURABLE CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES: A CASE STUDY OF WAH CANTT BEHAVIORAL ANALYSIS OF NON-DURABLE CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES: A CASE STUDY OF WAH CANTT Salma Bibi Lecturer university of Wah, Wah Cantt Pakistan Salma_uw@yahoo.com Irum Nawaz BS(Hons) University of Wah,

More information

Nord Pool data overview

Nord Pool data overview Nord Pool data overview Contents Prices, consumption, production, flow, price spikes. Prices and price log-returns.............................. Consumption, production and flow.........................

More information

Structural Change and Growth in India. Orcan Cortuk + Nirvikar Singh *

Structural Change and Growth in India. Orcan Cortuk + Nirvikar Singh * Structural Change and Growth in India Orcan Cortuk + Nirvikar Singh * February 10, 2010 Abstract This paper examines the link between structural change and growth in India. It constructs indices of structural

More information

Engaging Supply Chains in Climate Change

Engaging Supply Chains in Climate Change Online Supplement to: Engaging Supply Chains in Climate Change Chonnikarn (Fern) Jira Harvard Business School Wyss House Boston MA 02163 cjira@hbs.edu Michael W. Toffel Harvard Business School Morgan Hall

More information

Trade in Intermediate Goods, Armington Elasticity and Exchange Rate Pass-through. Fumihide TAKEUCHI Tokai University (Japan)

Trade in Intermediate Goods, Armington Elasticity and Exchange Rate Pass-through. Fumihide TAKEUCHI Tokai University (Japan) Trade in Intermediate Goods, Armington Elasticity and Exchange Rate Pass-through Fumihide TAKEUCHI Tokai University (Japan) 1 What is an exchange rate pass-through (ERPT)? Effect of exchange rate changes

More information

Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis

Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis Effects of Human Capital and Openness on Economic Growth of Developed and Developing Countries: A Panel Data Analysis Fatma Didin Sonmez, Pinar Sener Abstract Technology transfer by international trade

More information

Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02)

Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02) Appendix to Gerlagh, Mathys and Michielsen, Energy Abundance, Trade and Specialization (ej371_02) Appendix 1. Data Description Table A. Countries in the sample. Abbreviation Country AUS* Australia BEL

More information

The Dynamics of Trade and Competition

The Dynamics of Trade and Competition The Dynamics of Trade and Competition July 2007 Natalie Chen Warwick & CEPR Jean Imbs HEC Lausanne, SFI & CEPR Andrew Scott LBS & CEPR Globalization and the Macroeconomy, ECB 23-24 July 2007 Romer s Figure

More information

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Summary Freeing up resources so that they can be used more productively in other industries is the logic behind international

More information

INVESTIGATING THE STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND IN GHANA

INVESTIGATING THE STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND IN GHANA ACTA UNIVERSITATIS AGRICULTURAE ET SILVICULTURAE MENDELIANAE BRUNENSIS Volume 64 224 Number 6, 2016 http://dx.doi.org/10.11118/actaun201664062075 INVESTIGATING THE STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND IN GHANA Dennis

More information

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series 1. Analytical Notes. In search of greener pastures: improving the REINZ farm price index

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series 1. Analytical Notes. In search of greener pastures: improving the REINZ farm price index Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series 1 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes In search of greener pastures: improving the REINZ farm price index AN 2012/04 Ashley Dunstan and Chris

More information

Are Fluctations In Energy Consumption Transitory Or Permanent? Evidence From A Fourier Adf Unit Root Test

Are Fluctations In Energy Consumption Transitory Or Permanent? Evidence From A Fourier Adf Unit Root Test Are Fluctations In Energy Consumption Transitory Or Permanent? Evidence From A Fourier Adf Unit Root Test Ali Eren Alper, Asst. Prof. Nigde University, Turkey Abstract This study analysis the stationarity

More information

Macroeconomic Experiments (my take) Charles Noussair Tilburg University June 15, 2012

Macroeconomic Experiments (my take) Charles Noussair Tilburg University June 15, 2012 Macroeconomic Experiments (my take) Charles Noussair Tilburg University June 15, 2012 Outline of this lecture Four illustrations (examples of topics that one could study): Growth Models Multiple Equilibria

More information

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data Andreas Mueller 1 Stockholm University First Draft: May 15, 2009 This Draft: August 11, 2010 Abstract This paper provides new evidence

More information

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy Chapter 8 Firms in the Global Economy Summary 1. Introduction International trade is an important economic activity 2. General equilibrium model There are welfare gains from trade whenever relative prices

More information

Induced Innovation and Marginal Cost of New Technology

Induced Innovation and Marginal Cost of New Technology School of Economic Sciences Working Paper Series WP 2008-6 Induced Innovation and Marginal Cost of New Technology By Liu Y. and Shumway C.R. 2008 Induced Innovation and Marginal Cost of New Technology

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN DISCUSSION PAPER 03/15. Conditional Convergence in US Disaggregated Petroleum Consumption at the Sector Level

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN DISCUSSION PAPER 03/15. Conditional Convergence in US Disaggregated Petroleum Consumption at the Sector Level DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 03/15 Conditional Convergence in US Disaggregated Petroleum Consumption at the Sector Level Hooi Hooi Lean a and Russell Smyth b Abstract: We test

More information

Tutorial Segmentation and Classification

Tutorial Segmentation and Classification MARKETING ENGINEERING FOR EXCEL TUTORIAL VERSION v171025 Tutorial Segmentation and Classification Marketing Engineering for Excel is a Microsoft Excel add-in. The software runs from within Microsoft Excel

More information

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE IMPORTANCE OF PARAMETER HETEROGENEITY FROM A NONSTATIONARY PANEL APPROACH

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE IMPORTANCE OF PARAMETER HETEROGENEITY FROM A NONSTATIONARY PANEL APPROACH THE JAMES A. BAKER III INSTITUTE FOR PUBLIC POLICY RICE UNIVERSITY SOCIAL CAPITAL, BARRIERS TO PRODUCTION AND CAPITAL SHARES; IMPLICATIONS FOR THE IMPORTANCE OF PARAMETER HETEROGENEITY FROM A NONSTATIONARY

More information

Choosing between time and state dependence: Micro evidence on firms price-reviewing strategies

Choosing between time and state dependence: Micro evidence on firms price-reviewing strategies Choosing between time and state dependence: Micro evidence on firms price-reviewing strategies Daniel A. Dias, Carlos Robalo Marques, and Fernando Martins January 24, 2011 Abstract Thanks to recent findings

More information

Industrial Policy and Competition: Antinomian or Complementary?

Industrial Policy and Competition: Antinomian or Complementary? 0 Industrial Policy and Competition: Antinomian or Complementary? P. Aghion, M. Dewatripont, L.Du A. Harrison, P. Legros December 30, 2010 P. Aghion, M. Dewatripont, L.Du, A. Harrison, Industrial P. Legros

More information

THE 2008 ROUND OF REVISIONS OF THE NON-MANUFACTURING REGULATION (NMR) AND REGULATORY IMPACT (RI) INDICATORS

THE 2008 ROUND OF REVISIONS OF THE NON-MANUFACTURING REGULATION (NMR) AND REGULATORY IMPACT (RI) INDICATORS THE 2008 ROUND OF REVISIONS OF THE NON-MANUFACTURING REGULATION (NMR) AND REGULATORY IMPACT (RI) INDICATORS The Non-Manufacturing Regulation (NMR) and Regulatory Impact (RI) indicators have been updated,

More information

CONVERGENCE OF EUROPEAN NATURAL GAS PRICES

CONVERGENCE OF EUROPEAN NATURAL GAS PRICES WORKING PAPER SERIES ISSN 1973-0381 WORKING PAPER N. 107 DECEMBER 2018 CONVERGENCE OF EUROPEAN NATURAL GAS PRICES This paper can be downloaded at www.iefe.unibocconi.it The opinions expressed herein do

More information

Economic Growth and Political Survival

Economic Growth and Political Survival Economic Growth and Political Survival Paul J. Burke July 2011 Arndt-Corden Department of Economics Crawford School of Economics & Government Australian National University paul.j.burke@anu.edu.au Research

More information

Unionization and Informal Economy

Unionization and Informal Economy Unionization and Informal Economy Ceyhun Elgin Bogazici University Abstract: In this paper I investigate the relationship between unionization and the size of the informal economy. Using a cross-country

More information

Chapter 3. Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics. Measuring Business Cycles. Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010

Chapter 3. Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics. Measuring Business Cycles. Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010 Chapter 3 Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics Measuring Business Cycles Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010 1. Traditional framework for Fluctuations Undergraduate textbook model Divide markets into

More information

Empirical Exercise Handout

Empirical Exercise Handout Empirical Exercise Handout Ec-970 International Corporate Governance Harvard University March 2, 2004 Due Date The new due date for empirical paper is Wednesday, March 24 at the beginning of class. Description

More information

Modelling Competitiveness. Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi

Modelling Competitiveness. Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi Modelling Competitiveness Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi biswajit@iift.ac.in biswajit.nag@gmail.com Content Theoretical Models to asses International Competitiveness Empirical

More information

Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries

Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries July 2003 TP TP OECD, The issue of broadband internet access is an important one for public policy makers in

More information

on Firm-Level Price Data

on Firm-Level Price Data The Pro-Competitive Effect of Imports from China: an Analysis on Firm-Level Price Data Matteo Bugamelli, Silvia Fabiani and Enrico Sette (Bank of Italy, Economic Research Department) Brown Bag Lunch Meeting,

More information

Web Appendix (not for publication)

Web Appendix (not for publication) Web Appendix (not for publication) Online Appendix B. The Model Setup We consider a country consisting of two regions, which we call coast ( c ) and interior ( i ) for exposition. Workers in each region

More information

Price Cointegration Analyses of Food Crop Markets: The case of Wheat and Teff Commodities in Northern Ethiopia

Price Cointegration Analyses of Food Crop Markets: The case of Wheat and Teff Commodities in Northern Ethiopia Price Cointegration Analyses of Food Crop Markets: The case of Wheat and Teff Commodities in Northern Ethiopia Moti Jaleta and Berhanu Gebermedhin International Livestock Research Institute, P.O.Box 5689,

More information

Okun s law and its validity in Egypt

Okun s law and its validity in Egypt Okun s law and its validity in Egypt Hany Elshamy The British University in Egypt (BUE) Email:hany.elshamy@bue.edu.eg Abstract Okun s law is a key relationship in microeconomics and finds that the relationship

More information

Seasonality in Revisions of Macroeconomic Data

Seasonality in Revisions of Macroeconomic Data Journal of Official Statistics, Vol. 26, No. 2, 2010, pp. 361 369 Seasonality in Revisions of Macroeconomic Data Philip Hans Franses 1 and Rene Segers 1 We analyze the revision history of quarterly and

More information

The Effects of Exchange Rate on Trade Balance in Vietnam: Evidence from Cointegration Analysis

The Effects of Exchange Rate on Trade Balance in Vietnam: Evidence from Cointegration Analysis (Research note) 地域経済研究第 27 号 2016 The Effects of Exchange Rate on Trade Balance in Vietnam: Evidence from Cointegration Analysis Abstract LE, Thuan Dong * ISHIDA, Miki There has been many researchers studied

More information