In-house capabilities or cooperation? The effect of innovation methods on innovation outputs

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "In-house capabilities or cooperation? The effect of innovation methods on innovation outputs"

Transcription

1 In-house capabilities or cooperation? The effect of innovation methods on innovation outputs Anthony Arundel and Catalina Bordoy ( * ) MERIT, University of Maastricht, The Netherlands Abstract Widespread support within the European Union for cooperative R&D and for innovation networks between firms is founded on the belief that these types of knowledge flows improve innovation outputs. The general consensus, based on previous survey research, is that more innovative firms tend to use an above average number of external knowledge sources. However, most of these studies have not evaluated measures of the relative importance of inhouse research versus the use of external information sources, particularly via collaboration. The KNOW survey results permits a closer look at these issues. We evaluated the effect of the share of product innovations developed in-house and via collaboration on the share of innovative products or services in the firm s total sales (innovative sales share). The regression results show that the share of innovations developed in-house has a positive and statistically significant effect on the innovative sales share, while the share of innovations developed via collaboration had no effect in a full data model. However, some collaboration increases the innovative sales share. Separate analyses by country show that German firms benefit more from collaboration, although this could be due to collaboration with other divisions within the same firm, and not from collaboration with independent partners. Introduction The role of collaboration in the creation and diffusion of innovations has received a considerable amount of interest in the past decade from both innovation economists and European policy makers. The European Commission, for example, requires collaboration for research funded under the Framework Programme and encourages national policies to increase the rate of collaboration between firms and between firms and public research institutes (PRIs) (Hagedoorn et al, 2000). Part of the increased attention given to collaboration is due to a shift in economic theories of innovation from a linear to an interactive model and to a recognition of the importance of tacit knowledge to innovation and technology transfer. The former shift places greater importance on information and knowledge flows, including via collaboration. This is partly because there are more linkages within an interactive or chain-link innovation system, and partly because modern innovation theories stress the diffusion of knowledge among many different actors (Kline and Rosenberg, 1986; Rothwell, 1992; Freeman, 1987; Nelson,1993; Lundvall, 1992; Edquist 1997; Asheim and Smith, 1999). Within this framework, the literature has focused on two types of linkages: inter-firm relationships such as networks of user-producers or * We would like to thank A. Marcos Vera for his helpful comments on an earlier draft. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 1

2 competing firms (von Hippel, 1988; Lundvall, 1991; 1992) and linkages between firms and PRIs such as universities, government laboratories, and technical institutes (Mansfield, 1991; 1996; Pavitt, 1991). One perspective is that collaboration has increased in importance over the past few decades and is becoming an essential method of producing new knowledge of value to innovation. As an example, Gibbons argues that knowledge production has shifted from a mode 1 model in which problems are identified and solved in academic and corporate research labs to a mode 2 model, in which knowledge is created in a great variety of networked organisations, including large firms, small high-technology based firms, government institutions, universities, research laboratories and institutes (Gibbons, 1994). Georghiou (1998) further develops Gibbon s mode 2 model of innovation and suggests that contract research, based on cooperation and oiled by intellectual property rights, plays a central role in the exchange and production of new knowledge among governmental, industry, and university participants. Furthermore, the new mode of knowledge production includes a wider and more heterogeneous set of actors that collaborate temporarily on specific problems. One feature is the development of a collaborative space that links PRIs, firms, and other institutions. Similarly, Antonelli (1999) refers to the systematic use of technological co-operation as the dominant form of producing new knowledge. A second theoretical development with implications for collaboration is derived from research on the nature of knowledge and information. This posits a continuum between highly codified knowledge that is widely accessible in publications and patents and highly tacit knowledge that is only held in the minds of science and engineering staff (Saviotti, 1998; Cowan et al, 2000). Much of the knowledge developed within companies, particularly those active at the technological frontier, results from learning-by-doing or learning-by-using and may not be available in a codified form. Compared to other forms of knowledge flows based on codified information, cooperation provides better opportunities for the transfer of non-codified and tacit knowledge through interpersonal interactions (Senker, 1995) 1. In addition to providing access to non-codified knowledge, cooperative research can have several other advantages, including a reduction in technological and market uncertainty, costsharing, risk spreading, reduced duplication of research, economies of scale, and an ability to combine different types of expertise. These advantages could improve the economic efficiency of innovation. Although there has been an increase in R&D partnerships over the 1980s (Hagedoorn and Schakenraad, 1992) and the percentage of business R&D in the UK that is spent on external 1. Scientific knowledge is by nature more formal and transmittable in systematic language. However, the assumption that the results of science are a public good (i.e. codified, published, easily reproduced) is increasingly questioned. The application of formal information needs to be complemented by relevant tacit knowledge and skills, especially in new areas of research (Senker, 1995). C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 2

3 sources has increased from 5% in 1985 to 10% in 1995 (Howells, 1999), this does not mean that various forms of cooperation will become the dominant method for knowledge production or that the external R&D share will reach 20% or 50% in the near future. There could be a limit to the proportion of R&D spent on external sources that is set by several disadvantages of cooperation. Furthermore, specific factors that have driven much of the increase in PRI-industry cooperation, such as the development of biotechnology and ICT, could cease to play a role once these technologies mature. Recent innovation surveys, based on guidelines set forth in the OECD s Oslo Manual, provide additional empirical data on the role of cooperation. Analyses of the 1993 and 1997 European Community Innovation Surveys (CIS) show that firms rate the contribution to their innovative activities of their internal knowledge sources more highly than external sources. This could also be reflected in a preference for innovating in-house. Results from the 1997 CIS for seven European countries show that only 28% of innovative firms developed one or more product innovations in conjunction with other enterprises or institutes during the three years between 1994 and However, the second CIS provides no indicators that can be used to assess the relative importance of in-house versus cooperative innovation, nor do we know if the importance of cooperation is increasing, as suggested by the results of Hagedoorn and Schakenraad (1992). A preference for developing innovations within the firm could be due to several major disadvantages of cooperation. One is the diversion of energy and talents (Geroski, 1995), while another is concerns over appropriating the results, plus the need to reveal information to a cooperation partner. The latter can be an essential benefit of collaboration when most knoweldge is in tacit form, but can be a serious disadvantage if one or both partners are concerned about revealing information that they would prefer to keep secret. The cost savings to a firm from collaboration could also be reduced by the cost of developing an appropriate level of absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990) to be able to successfully incorporate the results into new products and processes. The necessary economies of scale would favour large firms over small firms (Minne, 1996), although Mowery (1995) notes that economies of scale for R&D cannot always be necessary or only the largest firms would perform R&D. The need for firms to cooperate could also depend on characteristics of the technologies that are used to innovate. Well-understood technologies will probably be developed in house, while firms should be more likely to cooperate on innovations that are based on complex technologies that require a range of expertise or those at the technological frontier. An example of a complex technology is telecom equipment, which includes software, electronics, and computer parts. However, telecom equipment firms and firms in other sectors face three options for acquiring technologies outside their area of expertise. They can develop the 2 The six countries are Germany, France, Italy, Sweden, Norway., Portugal and Ireland. The rate of cooperation varies very little by firm size. Analyses by the author. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 3

4 necessary capabilities in-house, collaborate on their development with other organisations, or they can buy-in sub-components from other firms. Veugelers and Cassiman (1999) characterise these choices as a make or buy decision and find that most firms use several strategies. If the benefits of cooperation to a firm outweigh the disadvantages, as suggested by Antonelli (1999) and others, we should expect cooperation to influence innovation outcomes: either more cooperation should lead to more innovations, and/or more cooperation should lead to more economically valuable innovations. Only a few studies, mostly based on the CIS, provide information on the impact of cooperation on innovation outcomes. The most commonly used outcome is the share of product sales from new or improved products that had been introduced onto the market in the previous three years. This is termed here the innovative sales share. First, Bosworth and Stoneman (1997) report that more innovative firms tend to use an above average number of external knowledge sources 3. Autio et al (1997) report similar results for the pulp and paper sector. Although firms can use external sources without collaborating 4, these results suggest that an outward looking strategy can increase innovative success. Nas et al (1994) look directly at participation in cooperative R&D and report that such cooperation increases the innovative sales share. Albach et al (1997) report that R&D cooperation among CIS respondents in the chemical sector is most prevalent among the more innovative subsectors of this industry, such as pharmaceuticals and agrochemicals. Conversely, two studies of the CIS results for the telecom and office equipment sectors found that firms that participate in cooperative R&D have a lower innovative sales share compared to firms that did not cooperate (Arundel and Steinmueller, 1996; Malerba et al, 1996). This raises the possibility that firms in these two sectors cooperate as part of a catch-up strategy. Vonortas (1997) reports that firms that did not cooperate in research joint ventures had higher profits than firms that did participate, which raises many questions about the value of collaboration and the reasons why firms participate in such projects. This report uses the KNOW survey results from seven European countries to explore the effect of collaboration on the innovative sales share. The KNOW survey has several advantages over the CIS. The greatest advantage is that the KNOW survey obtains information on the percentage of each firm s new or improved product innovations that were developed in-house, through buying in, or via collaboration with other divisions of the same firm or with independent firms or PRIs. In contrast, CIS only asks if the firm cooperated, on a yes or no basis, and then obtains information on the types of cooperation partners. It does not collect any information on whether or not cooperation led to innovations or the share of 3 Part of this effect is probably because more innovative firms also tend to be larger and larger firms simply have more opportunities to form external contacts (Arundel et al, 1995). 4 Examples are scanning patent databases and the literature for useful information, attending trade fairs and exhibitions, and reverse engineering of products on the market. A firm can use all four methods without revealing any information to its competitors. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 4

5 innovations developed through cooperation. Second, the KNOW survey obtains information on each firm s use of three appropriation methods, secrecy, patents, and lead-times, and asks which method was the most important to the firm for protecting its innovations. Third, KNOW obtains data on the distribution of research spending by location: in-house, other divisions of the firm, and external to firm. Finally, the KNOW survey asks for the number of employees with an academic degree in science or engineering. This provides an alternative to R&D spending as a measure of the firm s innovative capacity. Methodology The KNOW survey was conducted in the Spring of 2000 in seven EU countries: the UK, Denmark, the Netherlands, France, Germany, Italy, and Greece. The choice of countries to include in the survey depended on the origin of the participants in the KNOW project, funded by the Framework Programme of the European Commission. Although the survey does not cover all EU countries due to funding limitations, the four largest EU economies were included plus two of the smaller, developed economies and one of the less developed economies. The survey was limited to five sectors: food and beverages (NACE 15), chemicals excluding pharmaceuticals (NACE 24 minus NACE 24.2), telecom equipment (NACE 32), telecom services (NACE 64.2), and computer services (NACE 72). These specific sectors were chosen to provide a range of low, medium and high technology manufacturing and to include two innovative service sectors. In addition, the survey was limited to small and mid-sized firms to avoid problems with defining the sector of activity of large firms, many of which are active in several sectors. In each country, a random sample of firms from two size classes ( employees and employees) within each of the five sectors was drawn from a national business registry. A standard survey protocol based on a telephone CATI technique with up to three call-backs was used in all countries with the exception of the UK, where a postal survey was used. Table 1 gives basic information on the number of firms surveyed, the number of responses, the response rates, and the number of useable responses for this paper. The latter is less than the number of responses because the analyses exclude non-innovative firms, firms that did not fit the sampling criteria for size and sector 5, and firms in one sector (see below). The response rates by country vary from 9.6% in the UK to 76.5% in Denmark, with an average of 25.3% if the UK is included and 33.2% if the UK is excluded. The KNOW survey asked a series of questions about the total innovative activities of the firm and a second series of questions on the firm s most economically important innovation. The analyses in this report are limited to the first question series. There are two key questions. The first obtains an estimate of the innovative sales share: the percentage of the firms sales, in the 5 For size, a maximum cut-off of 1,250 employees was used to allow for natural employment growth between the time that the data in the business registries were collected and the survey date. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 5

6 previous year, from products or services that were significantly improved or new to your firm in the last three years 6. The second key question obtains an estimate of the percentage of the firm s innovations in the last three years that were introduced through buying in, in-house development, or collaboration with external partners. Buying-in is defined as purchasing, licensing, or contracting out. External partners include other divisions of the same firm plus PRIs and other firms, while in-house activities are restricted to the site of the firm itself, or where relevant, to the site of the respondent s division or subsidiary. Table 1. Survey results by country Firms Surveyed Responses Response rate Useable responses UK % 44 Denmark % 78 Netherlands % 114 France % 65 Germany % 51 Italy % 75 Greece % 100 Total % 527 Total excluding UK % Other relevant questions obtain information on the ownership status of the firm (division, national subsidiary, or independent), the use of three appropriation methods (patents, secrecy and lead-time), number of employees, sector of activity, research projects with PRIs, the firm s R&D status, personnel employed in R&D, the division of R&D expenditures by location (in-house, other divisions or subsidiaries of the same firm, independent organisations), and the number of employees with an academic degree. Preliminary analyses of the distribution of the results for the two key questions by country and sector found that the results for telecom services (NACE 64.2) varied widely by country, whereas there was considerably less variation for the other four sectors. For example, the innovative sales share for telecom services ranged by 50 percentage points between countries, compared to 23 points for computer services, 19 points for food and beverages, and 12 points each for chemicals and telecom equipment. National differences in the date and degree to which telecom services were liberalised probably explains part of the differences by country and would distort the results for the innovative sales share. For this reason, all of the analyses given below exclude telecom service firms. Some of the firms did not complete all survey questions. Where possible, the value of missing variables for interval variables (except for the dependent variable in the regressions) were 6 This question has an equivalent in both CIS surveys. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 6

7 estimated using regression techniques based on the firm s sector, country, and size. These estimated values are included in the results given below. The descriptive results given below (with the exception of firm counts) are weighted by the number of employees in each firm, under the reasonable assumption that this provides a measure of the economic contribution of each firm to innovation outputs. As an example, a firm with 200 employees will contribute twice as much to a weighted average for the importance of patents as a protection method than a firm with 100 employees. The regression results are not weighted by employment because they include a variable to control for the effect of firm size. Descriptive Results 349 firms in the sample (68.8%) have less than 249 employees, while 158 (31.2%) firms are mid-sized, with between 250 and 1,250 employees. The mid-size firms account for 82.3% of total employment among the sample. Table 2 provides basic results for the characteristics of the firms for the two size classes. As shown in Table 2, the sample is mostly limited to innovative, R&D performing firms. The majority of both small and large firms have had one or more research projects with a PRI in the previous three years, over 77% perform R&D on a continuous basis, and over 63% report R&D spending outside of their division or firm. For both small and mid-size firms, patents are the least frequently cited most important method for protecting the firms innovations, while lead time advantages are cited by 36% of small firms and 44.9% of mid-size firms. (More small than large firms cite an other protection method or none of these three). Table 2. Characteristics of the respondent firms Measures of innovative capabilities Small (< 250 emps) Mid-size (250 1,250) At least one research project with a PRI in the previous 3 years 55.1% 74.4% Performs R&D continuously 78.5% 77.4% Occasionally 17.6% 17.4% Positive R&D spending in independent firms or PRIs 63.0% 75.1% Share of employees with an academic degree 21.8% 17.9% Appropriation methods Most important protection method is: Patents 12.1% 19.8% Secrecy 32.2% 26.8% Lead times 36.0% 44.9% Notes: Employment weighted within each size class. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 7

8 Table 3 provides the percentage of firms that report developing one or more product or process innovations in-house, via buying-in, or through collaboration. The most commonly used innovation method is in-house development, followed by buying-in. Slightly less than half of the firms report collaborating on the development of either a product or process innovation. There is very little difference in the percentage of firms that collaborate on process compared to product innovations, but slightly more firms develop product innovations in-house or via buying-in. Table 3. Percentage of firms making some use of each innovation method Products/services Processes Either products or processes In-house Buying-in Collaboration Notes: Employment weighted. The remaining results for innovation methods are limited to product/service innovations because the main variable of interest, innovative sales share, does not include process innovations. Table 4 gives, for each sector, the average percentage of all product/service innovations that are developed through each innovation method. In all sectors, over 63% of product/service innovations are developed in-house, between 9% and 13% are bought in, and around 20% are developed via collaboration. The highest rate of collaboration is in the telecom equipment sector (24.1%) while the lowest rate is in computer services (13.7%). Table 4. Percent of product/service innovations developed through each method N In-house Buying-in Collaboration Food & beverages % Chemicals % Telecom equipment % Computer services % Total % Notes: Employment weighted. The mean innovative sales share varies by country, from a low of 27% in Greece to a high of 44% in Germany (results not shown). This is partly due to differences in the industrial distribution in each country and the average firm size. Both factors influence the innovative sales share, as shown in Table 5. The share is higher among small compared to mid-size telecom equipment firms while lower among small compared to large computer service firms. The difference by firm size is negligible in food and beverages and in chemicals. By sector, the innovative sales share is highest in telecom equipment and computer services. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 8

9 Table 5. Innovative sales shares by sector and firm size Small (< 250 emps) Mid-size (250 1,250) Food & beverages 21.6% 20.2% Chemicals 29.5% 26.0% Telecom equipment 55.5% 43.5% Computer services 52.4% 72.6% Total 39.2% 44.4% Notes: Employment weighted within each size class. Regression Results The regression results investigate the effect of several factors on the innovative sales share. The main independent variable of interest is the percentage of products or services developed through collaboration (collaboration product share). Although the theoretical literature strongly supports a positive relationship between collaboration and the innovative product share, we do not predict the direction of the relationship because the empirical evidence is ambiguous. The alternatives to collaboration are to develop products in-house or via buying-in. Buying-in accounts for only 11% of all innovations developed by the sample firms. This means that the alternative to collaboration, for most firms, is to develop innovations in-house, which accounts for 71% of all innovations. Given the very high proportion of innovations developed in-house, it is not possible to develop a model that includes both in-house development and collaboration. For this reason, we construct two models. The first model includes a variable for the percentage of products developed in-house, plus a dummy variable that equals one when at least one innovation is developed via collaboration (positive value for the collaboration product share). The second model includes a variable for the percentage of products developed via collaboration, plus a dummy variable that equals one when at least one innovation is developed in-house. Other factors that could influence the innovative sales share are firm size, sector, internal innovative capabilities, an outward looking approach to innovation, ownership status, and appropriation conditions. Survey research consistently shows that larger firms are more likely to collaborate than small firms, but this could be because larger firms have more opportunities and more resources for collaboration. Firm size might have no affect on collaboration if the latter was measured in terms of a rate variable, such as the number of collaborations per employee or unit of R&D expenditure. Of course, the advantage of the KNOW data is that we can go a step further and evaluate the effect of firm size on the innovative sales share and how this is mediated by a C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 9

10 collaboration variable that is neutral in terms of firm size the percentage of innovations developed by collaboration. The firm s sector of activity could have a large impact on the innovative product share. Rapidly changing sectors such as telecom equipment and computer software should have a higher innovative product share than sectors, such as food and beverages, with slower rates of change. The chemical sector should have a higher innovative product share than food and beverages, but a lower share than telecom equipment. The firm s innovative capabilities should increase the innovative product share. Several measures of innovative capability are available from the KNOW survey. The model includes the percentage of personnel with an academic degree and whether or not the firm performs R&D on a continuous basis. Firms with an outward-looking approach to innovation could have a higher innovative sales share if these external contacts improve development efficiencies or provide access to new ideas. The model includes two relevant dummy variables: one or more research projects with PRIs (PRIPROJ) and positive R&D spending outside the firm in independent organisations (EXTR&D). Both variables also provide measures of potentially collaborative research with independent organisations. The KNOW survey includes independent firms (57.2% of the unweighted total), divisions of larger firms (26.4%), and national subsidiaries of foreign firms (15.6%). Both divisions and subsidiaries could have a higher innovation sales share, due to products obtained from other units within their firm. To control for this effect, the model includes a dummy variable (INDEPENDENT) that is equal to 1 if the firm is independent. We expect the coefficient for this variable to be negative. Finally, appropriation conditions could influence the innovative sales share. This would occur, for instance, if patents were an effective method of protecting markets from competitors. Alternatively, secrecy could reduce the innovative sales share if concerns over releasing information reduced a firm s willingness to collaborate and if collaboration had a positive effect on innovative sales. The importance of lead time advantages as an appropriation strategy is strongly correlated with the innovative sales share, but the cause and effect relationship here is complex. A strategy of competing on the basis of lead time advantages could explain the positive correlation with innovative sales shares, but highly innovative products could create lead-time advantages, without the firm adopting a lead time strategy. In contrast, firms will adopt a strategy of using secrecy or patents for appropriation before the product is on the market. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 10

11 Model specification The dependent variable, the proportion of sales from innovative products, can vary from 0 to 1, with all possible values falling within this range 7. Since the dependent variable cannot take a negative value or exceed unity, an OLS model will provide biased coefficients. The model used here is a non-linear which assumes a S shaped distribution in the dependent variable. This assumption is reasonable because firms will need to develop a minimum level of internal expertise before their innovative sales share can increase notably from zero. Conversely, several factors will constrain the innovative sales share from reaching 100%, such as sales from existing products and appropriation and competition effects that prevent firms from dominating the market with their innovative products. The model takes the following form: y i ' exp( β xi + ε i ) = ' 1 + exp( β x + ε ) i i where y i is the innovative sales share (ISSHARE) and x i is a vector of independent variables. This functional form guarantees that for any value of both the variables and the parameters, the value of the conditional mean lies between 0 and 1. The vectors of independent variables for each model are the following: Vector for model 1: ISSHARE = F( β + β INHOUSESHARE + β COLLPROD + β R & DEMPSHARE + β LOGEMP + β CHEMICALS + β TELECOMEQ + β COMPSER + β EXTR & D + 4 β PRIPROJ + β INDEPENDENT + β CONTR & D + β COMPETS + β β SECRECY 14 + γ COUNTRY j j + ε i ) SUBSIDY + Vector for model 2: ISSHARE = F( β + β COLLABSHARE + β INHOUSE + β R & DEMPSHARE + β LOGEMP + β CHEMICALS + β TELECOMEQ + β COMPSER + β EXTR & D + 4 β PRIPROJ + β INDEPENDENT + β CONTR & D + β COMPETS + β β SECRECY 14 + γ COUNTRY j j + ε i ) SUBSIDY + The full models for all countries combined are unweighted and include dummy variables for country (results not shown), with the Netherlands as the reference category. The models for each country are weighted by the sample fraction in each sampling cell, defined by firm size and sector. 7 We favour this specification against a Tobit model since the Tobit model assumes that values outside the observed range are possible but are unobserved due to truncation or censoring. In our case, by construction of the dependent variable, values outside the range are not possible. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 11

12 Results Table 6 provides the results for equation 2 (Model 1) and equation 3 (Model 2) for all countries combined. Model 1 shows that there is a positive relationship between the percentage of products developed in-house and the innovative sales share. Conversely, the percentage of products developed through collaboration has no statistically significant effect on the innovative sales share. Furthermore, in both models the variable for external R&D spending (EXTR&D), which could involve collaboration, has no effect on the innovative sales share. The variable for collaboration with PRIs (PRIPROJ) is unexpectedly negative, although only significant with p <.1. The only variable that shows a positive effect for collaboration is the variable COLLPROD (some innovations developed via collaboration) in model 1. These results indicate that in-house development has the greatest positive impact on the innovative sales share, but that some experience with collaboration will also positively increase the innovative sales share. Table 6. Non-linear logistic model results for innovative sales share 1 2 B Std. Error P B Std. Error P Constant *** *** In-house product share *** COLLPROD ** Collaboration product share INHOUSE ** R&D employee share * Log employees Dummy variables for sector Chemicals ** ** Telecom equipment *** *** Computer services *** *** EXTR&D PRIPROJ * * INDEPENDENT CONTR&D ** ** COMPETS SUBSIDY SECRECY N Model F R Notes: Although not shown, both regressions include dummy variables for country, with the Netherlands as the reference category. The reference category for the sector dummies is Food and Beverages. The reference categories for the other dummy variables are: INHOUSE: zero products developed in-house, COLLPROD: zero products developed via collaboration; PRIPROJ: no research projects with public research institutes; INDEPENDENT: a division or subsidiary of another firm; CONTR&D: performs R&D occasionally or never; C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 12

13 COMPETS: less than 10 competitors; SUBSIDY: does not report government subsidies for R&D, SECRECY: secrecy is not the most important appropriation method. *** p <.01; **.01 <p <.05; *.05 < p <.1 The number of employees has no notable impact on the innovative sales share in both models. In contrast, the coefficient for the share of R&D personnel is not significant in model 1, although it increases the innovative sales share in model 2. As expected, firms that perform R&D on a continuous basis have a higher innovative sales share. The dummy variable for secrecy as the firm s most important appropriation method has no effect on the innovative sales share, nor does having over 10 competitors (COMPETS), or the receipt of government subsidies for R&D. Independent firms could have a lower innovation sales share, since they cannot obtain new products from other divisions or their head office. However, the coefficient for INDEPENDENT is not significant in either model. Both models were also run after limiting the cases to 286 independent firms. Neither the in-house product share nor COLLPROD was significant in model 1. In model 2, the collaboration product share was not significant, but INPROD is positive and of borderline significance (p <.1). Other than sector effects, the most important variables for both models for independent firms only were CONTR&D and SECRECY, which had a positive and a negative effect on the innovation sales share, respectively. Results by sector As expected, the firm s sector of activity has a significant effect on the innovative sales share. Compared to the reference category of food and beverages, all other sectors have significantly larger innovative sales shares. The difference is greater for telecom equipment and computer service firms than for chemical firms. The two regressions were run separately for each sector. An acceptable model fit was obtained only for 140 firms in the computer services sector (a lack of fit in the other sectors is likely to be due to the small sample size combined with low variability in the dependent variable). The results for computer services are similar to the results given in Table 6 for all firms. The in-house product share and some collaborative activity increase the innovative sales share, but the collaboration product share has no effect. The coefficient for CONTR&D is only statistically significant (p<.1) in the second model. Results by country One concern is that there could be unexplained differences by country in what constitutes an innovation, which could influence the estimated innovation sales share. Consistent national differences will partly be accounted for by the inclusion of country dummies in the main regressions presented in Table 6. Nevertheless, both models were also run separately for each country, since different national systems of innovation could cause different patterns in the C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 13

14 influence of several factors on the innovative sales share. The country results, however, need to be interpreted cautiously, since they are based on a small number of firms. These regressions for each country are weighted to represent the national distribution of innovative firms by size and sector 8. Table 7 provides the results for model 1 (contribution of in-house development of innovations) while Table 8 provides results for model 2 (collaborative development). No results are given for the UK, due to a small number of cases, while neither model fits the data for France or Italy. The in-house product share is only significant for Holland in model 1, while COLLPROD is significant and positive in three of the four countries. This suggests that Germany, Denmark and Greece do not contribute very much to the significant coefficient for in-house product share in Table 6. Conversely, the model 2 results shown in Table 8 show that the collaboration product share is significant and positive in Germany but significant and negative in Greece. INHOUSE (some innovations developed in-house) is positive and significant for Holland and Germany, but significant and negative for Greece. Table 7. Non-linear logistic model results for innovative sales share Model 1. In-house product share Holland Germany Denmark Greece Constant *** ** In-house product share *** COLLPROD ** *** ** R&D employee share Log employees * * ** Dummy variables for sector Chemicals ** Telecom equipment *** ** ** Computer services *** *** EXTR&D * PRIPROJ * INDEPENDENT ** *** ** CONTR&D ** COMPETS * ** SUBSIDY ** ** SECRECY * N Model F R Notes: Weighted results. *** p <.01, ** p <.05, * p < The weighted results are rescaled to equal the actual sample size while maintaining the weighted distribution. C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 14

15 These and other results from the country models suggest that collaboration in Germany makes a positive contribution to the innovation sales share, but has no effect or a negative effect (Greece) in the other three countries. The positive effect of collaboration in Germany could be due to links with other divisions within the same firm, since coefficient for INDEPENDENT is negative and highly significant in both models. This shows that the innovative sales share for German firms is higher for firms that are part of a group. Another interesting result in the case of Germany is that the variable SUBSIDY has a significant and positive effect on the innovative sales share in both models. Moreover, this is the only result that still holds in an unweighted regression for Germany, other than sector effects. Table 8. Non-linear logistic model results for innovative sales share Model 2: Collaboration product share Holland Germany Denmark Greece b B B B Constant *** Collaboration product share *** *** IN-HOUSE * ** ** R&D employee share Log employees * Dummy variables for sector Chemicals * Telecom equipment *** * ** Computer services *** *** * EXTR&D PRIPROJ * INDEPENDENT ** *** ** CONTR&D ** COMPETS * ** *** SUBSIDY * ** SECRECY N Model F R Notes: Weighted results. *** p <.01, ** p <.05, * p <.10. For Denmark, neither the in-house product share (Table 7) nor the collaboration product share (Table 8) increases the innovation sales share. The most interesting result is that in both models independent firms have a higher innovative sales share, while participation in research projects with PRIs (PRIPROJ) and subsidies (SUBSIDY) reduces the innovative sales share. The latter result could be due to the survey capturing small high technology start-ups which have yet to introduce products onto the market 9. An alternative explanation is due to the small 9 Question to KNOW Danish partners: Is this plausible? C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 15

16 number of firms for Denmark and the lack of significance for the sector variables, which in contrast are highly significant for both the Netherlands and Germany. For Denmark, the specific variables for firm characteristics could be explaining the dependent variable, while for the Netherlands and Germany the larger sample size means that differences in firm characteristics are captured by sector variables. The unweighted regressions for Denmark provide similar results, except that the coefficients for INDEPENDENT and SUBSIDY are no longer significant. The results for Greece show no effect for in-house product share, although some collaboration (COLLPROD) increases the innovation sales share in model 1. In model 2, the coefficients for collaboration product share and IN-HOUSE are both significant and negative. The unweighted results are similar, except for the coefficients for COLLPROD and INDEPENDENT in model 1 and INHOUSE in model 2, which are no longer significant. Since both the collaboration product share (model 2) and the in-house product share (model 1) are negative for Greece, the share of innovations out of total sales in Greece is probably more dependent on buying-in innovations than in other countries. While the average percentage of product innovations developed via buying in is 12.5% across all countries, Germany and Greece buy in 17.3% and 21.14% of all their product innovations, respectively. Conclusions Based on the regression results for the full data set, in-house capabilities, as shown by the percentage of product innovations developed in-house, increase the innovative sales share, although some collaboration is also beneficial. In contrast, other measures of collaboration, such as the percentage of products developed via collaboration, participation in research projects with PRIs, and external R&D spending, have little or no effect. The results for specific countries show that differences in national systems of innovation could influence the role of collaboration. The collaborative product share increases the innovative sales share in Germany, although this result could be due to collaboration with other divisions within the same firm, rather than collaboration with external partners. In both Germany and the Netherlands, independent firms have lower innovative sales shares, as expected, but in Denmark independent firms have a higher innovative sales share. However, there is little evidence from Denmark that either collaborative activities or in-house activities influence the innovative sales share, with the exception of a decline in the innovative sales share for firms that collaborate with PRIs. These results provide little empirical support for the very positive view of collaboration in recent innovation theory. These results are of interest to European innovation policies to encourage collaboration. The results clearly question the advantages of too much collaboration, although some collaboration is beneficial. There are several limitations to the results: they are limited to seven countries, four sectors, and small and medium-sized firms with less than 1,250 employees. Collaboration could be far more effective and productive in other countries or C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 16

17 among larger firms, or what is more likely, in specific sectors such as biotechnology where there is intense collaboration between PRIs, dedicated biotechnology firms, and large pharmaceutical and seed firms. If true, this means that policies to encourage collaboration need to carefully consider how collaboration is mediated by the development stage of the technology. References Albach et al. Innovation in the European Chemical Industry. EIMS Project Report, Luxembourg, May, Antonelli C. Industrial organisation and the production of knowledge. Cambridge Journal of Economics 23: , Arundel A, Soete L, van der Paal G. Innovation Strategies of Europe s Largest Industrial Firms, European Commission, Arundel, A, Steinmueller E, Hawkins R. Strategies for the Future: Innovation in the European Telecom Equipment Industry. MERIT, July Asheim, B. and Smith, K. Regional Innovation Systems, Regional Networks and Regional Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Autio E, Dietrichs E, Fηhrer K, Smith K. Innovation Activities in Pulp, Paper and Paper Products in Europe. STEP Report 4/97, STEP, Oslo, Beise M, Stahl H. Public research and industrial innovations in Germany. Research Policy 28: , Cohen W, Levinthal D. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35:128-52, Cowan R, Foray D. The economics of codification and the diffusion of knowledge. MERIT research memorandum 2/97-005, MERIT, Maastricht, Bosworth D, Stoneman P. Information and technology transfer in Europe. In Arundel A, Garrelfs R (Eds) Innovation Measurement and Policies, pp , European Commission, Luxembourg, EUR EN, Edquist, C. (ed.) Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organisations. London: Pinter, Freeman, C. Technology Policy and Economic Performance: Lessons from Japan. London: Pinter, Georghiou L. Science, technology and innovation policy for the 21st century. Science and Public Policy 25: , Geroski P. Markets for technology: Knowledge, innovaiton and appropriability. In Stoneman P. Handbook of the economics of Innovation and Technological Change. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp , Hagedoorn, J. and Schakenraad, J. Leading companies and networks of strategic alliances in information technologies. Research Policy, vol 21, Hagedoorn, J, Link AN, Vonortas, N. Research partnerships. Research Policy 29: , Howells J. Research and technology outsourcing. Technology Analysis and Strategic Management 11:17-29, Kleinknecht A, Reijnen J. Why do firms cooperate on R&D? Research Policy 21: , C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 17

18 Kline, S. and Rosenberg, N. An Overview of Innovation. In Landau, R., (Eds.), The Positive Sum Strategy. National Academic Press, Washington, DC. (1986. Levin RC et al, Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Acitivity 3: , Lundvall, B. Innovation, the organised market and the productivity slowdown, in OECD Technology and Productivity: The Challenges for Economic Policy, Paris, Lundvall, B. (ed.) National Systems of Innovation. London: Pinter, Mansfield E. Academic Research and Industrial Innovation Research Policy, 20: Mansfield, E. and Lee, J-Y. The Modern University: Contributor to Industrial Innovation and Recipient of Industrial R&D support, Research Policy, 25: Malerba F. et al. The Office and Computer Equipment Industry, EIMS Poject Report, Luxembourg, Minne B. Expenditures in relation to the knowledge-based economy in 10 OECD countries. OECD Conference on new S&T indicators for the knowledge-based economy, Paris, June Mowery D. The practice of technology policy. In Stoneman P. Handbook of the economics of Innovation and Technological Change. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp , Nas SO, Sandven T, Smith K. Inovasjon og teknologi I norsk industri: En oversikt (Innovation and New Technology in Norwegian Industry: An Overview). STEP Report 4/94, STEP, Oslo, Nelson, R. (ed.) National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Study. New York: Oxford University Press, Pavitt, K. What Makes Basic Research Economically Useful? Research Policy, 20: Rothwell Successful Industrial Innovation: Critical Factors of the 1990s, R&D Management, Vol 22, no.3, Saviotti P.P. On the dynamics of appropriability, of tacit and of codified knowledge. Research Policy 26: , Senker, J. Tacit Knowledge and Models of Innovation in Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol.4, no.2, Veuglers R, Cassiman B. Make and buy in innovation strategies: evidence from Belgian manufacturing firms. Research Policy 28:63-80, Vonortas, N. Cooperation in research and development. Kluwer Academic, Boston, Von Hippel, E. The Sources of Innovation. Oxford University Press: Oxford, C:\WINDOWS\Επιφάνεια εργασίας\rename-ioanna\in-housemerit_final.doc 18

How firms innovate: R&D, non-r&d, and technology adoption. Can Huang, Anthony Arundel and Hugo Hollanders

How firms innovate: R&D, non-r&d, and technology adoption. Can Huang, Anthony Arundel and Hugo Hollanders Working Paper Series #2010-027 How firms innovate: R&D, non-r&d, and technology adoption Can Huang, Anthony Arundel and Hugo Hollanders United Nations University - Maastricht Economic and social Research

More information

The Fourth Community Innovation Survey (CIS IV)

The Fourth Community Innovation Survey (CIS IV) The Fourth Community Innovation Survey (CIS IV) THE HARMONISED SURVEY QUESTIONNAIRE The Fourth Community Innovation Survey (Final Version: October 20 2004) This survey collects information about product

More information

The Innovation Union Scoreboard: Monitoring the innovation performance of the 27 EU Member States

The Innovation Union Scoreboard: Monitoring the innovation performance of the 27 EU Member States MEMO/12/74 Brussels, 7 February 2012 The Innovation Union Scoreboard: Monitoring the innovation performance of the 27 EU Member States This MEMO provides an overview of the research and innovation performance

More information

Design, Implementation & Analysis of Innovation Surveys

Design, Implementation & Analysis of Innovation Surveys Design, Implementation & Analysis of Innovation Surveys With a note on presenting results Anthony Arundel UNU-MERIT, The Netherlands Survey design and implementation 1 Tampere 200 Outline Part 1 How to

More information

The determinants and effects of technological and nontechnological innovations Evidence from the German CIS IV

The determinants and effects of technological and nontechnological innovations Evidence from the German CIS IV The determinants and effects of technological and nontechnological innovations Evidence from the German CIS IV Tobias Schmidt 1 Christian Rammer 2 This (shortened) version: 06 September 2006 Abstract In

More information

A taxonomy of innovation: How do public sector agencies innovate? Results of the 2010 European Innobarometer survey of public agencies

A taxonomy of innovation: How do public sector agencies innovate? Results of the 2010 European Innobarometer survey of public agencies A taxonomy of innovation: How do public sector agencies innovate? Results of the 2010 European Innobarometer survey of public agencies This report was prepared by Anthony Arundel 1 & Hugo Hollanders 2

More information

User innovators and their influence on innovation activities of firms in Finland Jari Kuusisto, Mervi Niemi and Fred Gault

User innovators and their influence on innovation activities of firms in Finland Jari Kuusisto, Mervi Niemi and Fred Gault Working Paper Series #2014-003 User innovators and their influence on innovation activities of firms in Finland Jari Kuusisto, Mervi Niemi and Fred Gault Maastricht Economic and social Research institute

More information

The Community Innovation Survey 2010

The Community Innovation Survey 2010 The Community Innovation Survey 2010 (CIS 2010) THE HARMONISED SURVEY QUESTIONNAIRE The Community Innovation Survey 2010 FINAL VERSION July 9, 2010 This survey collects information on your enterprise s

More information

The micro-evidence of innovation: data and research applications. Micheline Goedhuys. UNU-MERIT, Maastricht, Netherlands

The micro-evidence of innovation: data and research applications. Micheline Goedhuys. UNU-MERIT, Maastricht, Netherlands The micro-evidence of innovation: data and research applications Micheline Goedhuys UNU-MERIT, Maastricht, Netherlands Overview of lecture 1. The rise of survey methods 2. OECD Oslo manual and innovation

More information

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Preliminary version Abstract This paper

More information

KNOWLEDGE-INTENSIVE BUSINESS SERVICES AS IMPORTANT SERVICES FOR INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SLOVAKIA Tatiana Čorejová 1, Mario Al Kassiri 2

KNOWLEDGE-INTENSIVE BUSINESS SERVICES AS IMPORTANT SERVICES FOR INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SLOVAKIA Tatiana Čorejová 1, Mario Al Kassiri 2 KNOWLEDGE-INTENSIVE BUSINESS SERVICES AS IMPORTANT SERVICES FOR INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SLOVAKIA Tatiana Čorejová 1, Mario Al Kassiri 2 Abstract: This paper illustrates the importance of Knowledge-intensive

More information

MODELLING INNOVATIVE ACTIVITY IN THE NEW ZEALAND BIOTECHNOLOGY SECTOR

MODELLING INNOVATIVE ACTIVITY IN THE NEW ZEALAND BIOTECHNOLOGY SECTOR MODELLING INNOVATIVE ACTIVITY IN THE NEW ZEALAND BIOTECHNOLOGY SECTOR Dan Marsh (1) and Les Oxley (2) (1) Department of Economics, University of Waikato (2) Department of Economics, University of Canterbury

More information

Assessing recent developments in innovation measurement: the third edition of the Oslo Manual

Assessing recent developments in innovation measurement: the third edition of the Oslo Manual Science and Public Policy, 34(1), February 2007, pages 23 34 DOI: 10.3152/030234207X190487; http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/beech/spp Assessing recent developments in innovation measurement: the

More information

Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries

Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries Quantifying differences between broadband penetration rates for Australia and other countries July 2003 TP TP OECD, The issue of broadband internet access is an important one for public policy makers in

More information

Measuring Services Innovation: Service Sector Innovation Index

Measuring Services Innovation: Service Sector Innovation Index Measuring Services Innovation: Service Sector Innovation Index Hugo Hollanders UNU-MERIT (Maastricht University) Six Countries Programme (6CP) Workshop Non-technical Innovations Definition, Measurement

More information

4 Strategic Directions for Czech Economic Policy

4 Strategic Directions for Czech Economic Policy 4 Strategic Directions for Czech Economic Policy Executive Summary The objective of this document is to start a discussion of how the Czech Republic can set a strategy (allocate its current economic and

More information

The Impact of Firm s R&D Strategy on Profit and Productivity

The Impact of Firm s R&D Strategy on Profit and Productivity CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 156 The Impact of Firm s R&D Strategy on Profit and Productivity Börje Johansson* and Hans Lööf** (*CESIS and JIBS, **CESIS and Division of Economics, KTH)

More information

Epidemic, rank, stock and order effects in renewable energy diffusion: a model and empirical evidence from China s wind power sector

Epidemic, rank, stock and order effects in renewable energy diffusion: a model and empirical evidence from China s wind power sector Epidemic, rank, stock and order effects in renewable energy diffusion: a model and empirical evidence from China s wind power sector Yang Liu Department of Economics, Ecole Polytechnique, France Taoyuan

More information

INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD 2011

INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD 2011 INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD 2011 The Innovation Union's performance scoreboard for Research and Innovation 7 February 2012 The IUS report, its annexes and the indicators database are available at http://www.proinno-europe.eu/metrics

More information

QUESTIONNAIRE FOR FIRMS. INNOVATION-BASED STRATEGIES FOR GLOBALIZATION Questionnaire for SECTOR NAME (COUNTRY NAME)

QUESTIONNAIRE FOR FIRMS. INNOVATION-BASED STRATEGIES FOR GLOBALIZATION Questionnaire for SECTOR NAME (COUNTRY NAME) VR Questionnaire Insert logo of partner institution here QUESTIONNAIRE FOR FIRMS INNOVATION-BASED STRATEGIES FOR GLOBALIZATION Questionnaire for SECTOR NAME (COUNTRY NAME) Person that makes the interview

More information

TIK WORKING PAPERS. on Innovation Studies No U N I V E R S I T Y O F O S L O.

TIK WORKING PAPERS. on Innovation Studies No U N I V E R S I T Y O F O S L O. U N I V E R S I T Y O F O S L O TIK Centre for technology, innovation and culture P.O. BOX 1108 Blindern N-0317 OSLO Norway Eilert Sundts House, 7 th floor Moltke Moesvei 31 Phone: +47 22 84 16 00 Fax:

More information

25 % 20 % 15 % 10 % 5 % Share rail, inland waterways and oil pipelines 0 %

25 % 20 % 15 % 10 % 5 % Share rail, inland waterways and oil pipelines 0 % Indicator fact sheet TERM 2003 13b EEA 17 Modal split in freight transport The share of road freight transport increased during the 1991 2000 period, whereas the modal share of short-sea shipping remained

More information

UTILITIES: HOW THE EU DIRECTIVE IS IMPLEMENTED AND HOW IT WORKS IN EU MEMBER STATES

UTILITIES: HOW THE EU DIRECTIVE IS IMPLEMENTED AND HOW IT WORKS IN EU MEMBER STATES A joint initiative of the OECD and the European Union, principally financed by the EU VIth IPA REGIONAL PUBLIC PROCUREMENT CONFERENCE UTILITIES: HOW THE EU DIRECTIVE IS IMPLEMENTED AND HOW IT WORKS IN

More information

WIND POWER TARGETS FOR EUROPE: 75,000 MW by 2010

WIND POWER TARGETS FOR EUROPE: 75,000 MW by 2010 About EWEA EWEA is the voice of the wind industry actively promoting the utilisation of wind power in Europe and worldwide. EWEA members from over 4 countries include 2 companies, organisations, and research

More information

Analysis of Ireland s Innovation Performance

Analysis of Ireland s Innovation Performance Analysis of Ireland s Innovation Performance March 2011 FORFÁS ANALYSIS OF IRELAND S INNOVATION PERFORMANCE Executive Summary 2 1. Background to Community Innovation Survey 2006-2008 Analysis 7 2. International

More information

Work-based learning : a frame of reference for policy making

Work-based learning : a frame of reference for policy making Work-based learning : a frame of reference for policy making Paolo FEDERIGHI, University of Florence, Italy Cedefop, 21 October 2014 Contents Preliminary Comments 1. WBL: policy challanges Distribution

More information

FIRM INNOVATION AND DEVELOPMENT

FIRM INNOVATION AND DEVELOPMENT PIEB ISSN 1804-0527 Perspectives of Innovations, Economics and Business Perspectives of Innovations, Economics & Business, Volume 14, Issue 1, 2014 ISSN 1804-0527 / Online version is a primary open-access

More information

Measuring e-government

Measuring e-government Chapter 6 Measuring e-government 6.1 Towards consensus on indicators 94 6.2 Assessing online services and e-participation 95 6.3 Accounting for capacity constraints 96 6.4 Conclusions 97 Reliable and relevant

More information

15189/04 DGE/coc 1 DG C II

15189/04 DGE/coc 1 DG C II COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 24 November 2004 15189/04 COVER NOTE from: COMPET 197 IND 155 RECH 243 ECOFIN 400 ECO 188 Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Ms Patricia BUGNOT,

More information

ESTIMATING TOURISTS' ECONOMIC VALUES OF PUBLIC BEACH ACCESS POINTS

ESTIMATING TOURISTS' ECONOMIC VALUES OF PUBLIC BEACH ACCESS POINTS University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Tourism Travel and Research Association: Advancing Tourism Research Globally 2007 ttra International Conference ESTIMATING TOURISTS' ECONOMIC

More information

COMMUNITY INNOVATION SURVEY (CIS)

COMMUNITY INNOVATION SURVEY (CIS) Standard Report on Methods and Quality for COMMUNITY INNOVATION SURVEY (CIS) Published as: Innovation in Irish Enterprises This documentation applies to the reporting period: 2012 2014 inclusive Last edited:

More information

Survey of Licensing Activities in Selected Fields of Environmentally Sound Technologies (ESTs) FINAL REPORT-DRAFT. Submitted by Dr. Meir Perez Pugatch

Survey of Licensing Activities in Selected Fields of Environmentally Sound Technologies (ESTs) FINAL REPORT-DRAFT. Submitted by Dr. Meir Perez Pugatch Survey of Licensing Activities in Selected Fields of Environmentally Sound Technologies (ESTs) A Joint Project by the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), the European Patent Office (EPO), and

More information

IRISH LABOUR COSTS IN EUROPEAN COMPARISON

IRISH LABOUR COSTS IN EUROPEAN COMPARISON IRISH LABOUR COSTS IN EUROPEAN COMPARISON MICHAEL TAFT RESEARCH OFFICER, UNITE THE UNION EUROPEAN LABOUR FORCE SURVEY Labour Costs in Market (Business) Economy: 2011 ( ) Denmark Sweden Belgium 39.61 39.28

More information

Policy Note August 2015

Policy Note August 2015 Unit Labour Costs, Wages and Productivity in Malta: A Sectoral and Cross-Country Analysis Brian Micallef 1 Policy Note August 2015 1 The author is a Senior Research Economist in the Bank s Modelling and

More information

Accounting for Innovation and Measuring Innovativeness: An Illustrative Framework and an Application

Accounting for Innovation and Measuring Innovativeness: An Illustrative Framework and an Application Accounting for Innovation and Measuring Innovativeness: An Illustrative Framework and an Application By JACQUES MAIRESSE AND PIERRE MOHNEN* The purpose of this paper is to propose and illustrate an accounting

More information

Sectoral Profile - Industry

Sectoral Profile - Industry Sectoral Profile - Industry Energy consumption Energy consumption trends in EU There is a regular decrease in energy consumption since 2003, although there was growth in industrial activity from 2003 to

More information

COOPERATION INNOVATION ACTIVITIES: THE IMPORTANCE OF PARTNERS

COOPERATION INNOVATION ACTIVITIES: THE IMPORTANCE OF PARTNERS COOPERATION INNOVATION ACTIVITIES: THE IMPORTANCE OF PARTNERS Pedro Faria Instituto Superior Técnico and IN+, Technical University of Lisbon Av. Rovisco Pais, 1049-001 Lisboa, Portugal (T) +351.218.417.893;

More information

Regional Innovation Reviews Competitive Regional Clusters: National Policy Approaches

Regional Innovation Reviews Competitive Regional Clusters: National Policy Approaches Regional Innovation Reviews Competitive Regional Clusters: National Policy Approaches Summary in English Why are cluster policies still popular? While the cluster concept is not new and remains subject

More information

Innovation, IP choice, and productivity: Evidence from UK firms

Innovation, IP choice, and productivity: Evidence from UK firms Innovation, IP choice, and productivity: Evidence from UK firms Bronwyn H. Hall 1 Vania Sena 2 December 2011 This report is module 3b for the project The choice between formal and informal intellectual

More information

Indicators for benchmarking biotechnology innovation policies

Indicators for benchmarking biotechnology innovation policies Indicators for benchmarking biotechnology innovation policies Thomas Reiss and Iciar Dominguez-Lacasa Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research (Fraunhofer ISI) Department Emerging Technologies

More information

ARE ROBOTS STEALING OUR JOBS?

ARE ROBOTS STEALING OUR JOBS? ARE ROBOTS STEALING OUR JOBS? Marco Vivarelli (Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milano; IZA, Bonn; MERIT, Maastricht) Social Situation Monitor - Research Seminar Brussels, 10 November 2017 Today alarm

More information

Working together to meet global energy challenges

Working together to meet global energy challenges Working together to meet global energy challenges Staff on loan From around the world From IEA and OECD member countries: Australia Austria Belgium Canada Chile Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France

More information

Estimating Demand Elasticities of Meat Demand in Slovakia

Estimating Demand Elasticities of Meat Demand in Slovakia Estimating Demand Elasticities of Meat Demand in Slovakia Daniela Hupkova (1) - Peter Bielik (2) (1) (2) Slovak University of Agriculture in Nitra, Faculty of Economics and Management, Department of Economics,

More information

Foreign-owned Plants and Job Security

Foreign-owned Plants and Job Security Foreign-owned Plants and Job Security Martyn Andrews University of Manchester, UK Lutz Bellmann Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung, Nürnberg, Germany Thorsten Schank Universität Erlangen Nürnberg,

More information

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay I. Theoretical Model In this paper, I define skill-biased technological change as the technological shock that began in the 1970s with

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 27.07.2007 SEC(2007) 1059 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Towards a European strategy in support of innovation in services: Challenges and key issues

More information

Working Party No. 1 on Macroeconomic and Structural Policy Analysis

Working Party No. 1 on Macroeconomic and Structural Policy Analysis For Official Use ECO/CPE/WP1(2005)2 ECO/CPE/WP1(2005)2 For Official Use Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 24-Feb-2005 English

More information

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data Andreas Mueller 1 Stockholm University First Draft: May 15, 2009 This Draft: August 11, 2010 Abstract This paper provides new evidence

More information

Higher Education and Economic Development in the Balkan Countries: A Panel Data Analysis

Higher Education and Economic Development in the Balkan Countries: A Panel Data Analysis 1 Further Education in the Balkan Countries Aristotle University of Thessaloniki Faculty of Philosophy and Education Department of Education 23-25 October 2008, Konya Turkey Higher Education and Economic

More information

TELECOMS WATCHDOGS LACK POWERS TO FIGHT MONOPOLIES, STUDY FINDS

TELECOMS WATCHDOGS LACK POWERS TO FIGHT MONOPOLIES, STUDY FINDS TELECOMS WATCHDOGS LACK POWERS TO FIGHT MONOPOLIES, STUDY FINDS Benchmark of 19 European countries shows lowest prices, highest investment where regulators have strong tools to enforce EU pro-competition

More information

Bargaining in technology markets: An empirical study of biotechnology alliances

Bargaining in technology markets: An empirical study of biotechnology alliances Bargaining in technology markets: An empirical study of biotechnology alliances Shinya Kinukawa Komazawa University Kazuyuki Motohashi University of Tokyo September 7, 2009 Abstract The division of innovative

More information

Determinants of innovation diffusion in the EU: A microeconometric analysis of firms innovation adoption choices 1

Determinants of innovation diffusion in the EU: A microeconometric analysis of firms innovation adoption choices 1 WP4/09 SEARCH WORKING PAPER Determinants of innovation diffusion in the EU: A microeconometric analysis of firms innovation adoption choices Corinne Autant-Bernard, Jean-Pascal Guironnet, Nadine Massard

More information

The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies

The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies Mladen Vuckovic The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies 130 - Organizational Response To Globally Driven Institutional Changes Abstract This paper will investigate

More information

Multinational Companies and the Diffusion of Employment Practices from Outside the Country of Origin: Explaining Variation across Firms

Multinational Companies and the Diffusion of Employment Practices from Outside the Country of Origin: Explaining Variation across Firms Multinational Companies and the Diffusion of Employment Practices from Outside the Country of Origin: Explaining Variation across Firms Tony Edwards 1, Paul Edwards 2, Anthony Ferner 3, Paul Marginson

More information

TOPIC 1B: DETERMINANTS AND THEORIES OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT (FDI)

TOPIC 1B: DETERMINANTS AND THEORIES OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT (FDI) TOPIC 1B: DETERMINANTS AND THEORIES OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT (FDI) 1. FDI is a feature of a broader economic phenomenon referred to as internationalization. 2. Internationalization relates to the organization

More information

Activity 3.6b Decision making in the Economy: Small Scale and Family owned

Activity 3.6b Decision making in the Economy: Small Scale and Family owned FACILITATION GUIDELINES: DEVELOPING GENDER STATISTICS Activity 3.6b Decision making in the Economy: Small Scale and Family owned OBJECTIVE PARTICIPANTS TIME ROOM SET-UP SUPPLIES This activity will allow

More information

Exporting services and exporting goods What are the effects on aggregate productivity growth?

Exporting services and exporting goods What are the effects on aggregate productivity growth? Exporting services and exporting goods What are the effects on aggregate productivity growth? Nikolaj Malchow-Møller *, Jakob R. Munch *, Jan Rose Skaksen * * Centre for Economic and Business Research

More information

Industry-university S&T transfers: what can we learn from Belgian CIS-2 data?

Industry-university S&T transfers: what can we learn from Belgian CIS-2 data? Industry-university S&T transfers: what can we learn from Belgian CIS-2 data? Henri Capron and Michele Cincera (ULB-DULBEA) WORKSHOP ON THE PROCESS OF REFORM OF THE UNIVERSITY ACROSS EUROPE. SIENA, ITALY,

More information

OECD LEED TRENTO CENTRE FOR LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFORMATION BROCHURE

OECD LEED TRENTO CENTRE FOR LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFORMATION BROCHURE OECD LEED TRENTO CENTRE FOR LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFORMATION BROCHURE THE ORGANISATION The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is a unique forum where governments work together to

More information

SAMPLE. Bracco Imaging S.p.A.Market Share Analysis. Bracco Imaging S.p.A. Market Share Analysis GDME0639CDB / Published January 2013

SAMPLE. Bracco Imaging S.p.A.Market Share Analysis. Bracco Imaging S.p.A. Market Share Analysis GDME0639CDB / Published January 2013 Market Share Analysis Reference Code: GDME0639CDB Publication Date: January 2013 GlobalData. This report is a licensed product and is not to be copied, reproduced, shared or resold in any form Page 1 Table

More information

EU-US Productivity and R&D Investment Gap

EU-US Productivity and R&D Investment Gap EU-US Productivity and R&D Investment Gap (A firm-sector-level Analysis) Federico Biagi, Juraj Stancik and Anna Sabadash Institute for Prospective Technological Studies Joint Research Centre European Commission

More information

THE ROLE OF INTANGIBLE, KNOWLEDGE-BASED CAPITAL IN ECONOMIC GROWTH

THE ROLE OF INTANGIBLE, KNOWLEDGE-BASED CAPITAL IN ECONOMIC GROWTH THE ROLE OF INTANGIBLE, KNOWLEDGE-BASED CAPITAL IN ECONOMIC GROWTH Alistair Nolan OECD Directorate for Science, Technology and Industry Washington DC, January 2014 What is knowledge-based capital (KBC)?

More information

Sustainable Procurement Survey

Sustainable Procurement Survey Sustainable Procurement Survey New Zealand business decision makers views on the - Role of Government in sustainable development, - Government procurement policy, - Promotion of sustainable or eco-labels

More information

Cutting Red Tape The Member State point of view. Presentation by Hilde Van de Velde Bruges March 2010

Cutting Red Tape The Member State point of view. Presentation by Hilde Van de Velde Bruges March 2010 Cutting Red Tape The Member State point of view Presentation by Hilde Van de Velde Bruges March 2010 The Action Programme created a momentum for reducing administrative burdens and inspired MS to launch

More information

The EU ETS: Over-allocation or Abatement?

The EU ETS: Over-allocation or Abatement? The EU ETS: Over-allocation or Abatement? A. Denny Ellerman & Barbara Buchner MIT and IEA Workshop on the Evaluation of the EU ETS, 19-20 April 2007, Paris Caisse des Dépôts OECD/IEA 2007 Some background

More information

ASSESSING GOOD PRACTICES IN POLICIES AND MEASURES TO MITIGATE CLIMATE CHANGE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE. Elena Petkova

ASSESSING GOOD PRACTICES IN POLICIES AND MEASURES TO MITIGATE CLIMATE CHANGE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE. Elena Petkova Workshop on Best Practices in Policies and Measures, 8-10 October 2001, Copenhagen ASSESSING GOOD PRACTICES IN POLICIES AND MEASURES TO MITIGATE CLIMATE CHANGE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE Elena Petkova

More information

MEANS TO AN END: the OECD Approach for Effective Implementation of Public Procurement Systems Getting really strategic

MEANS TO AN END: the OECD Approach for Effective Implementation of Public Procurement Systems Getting really strategic MEANS TO AN END: the OECD Approach for Effective Implementation of Public Procurement Systems Getting really strategic Paulo Magina Head of the Public Procurement Unit, GOV, OECD 11TH PUBLIC PROCUREMENT

More information

COST EFFICIENCY OF WASTE MANAGEMENT IN DUTCH MUNICIPALITIES

COST EFFICIENCY OF WASTE MANAGEMENT IN DUTCH MUNICIPALITIES COST EFFICIENCY OF WASTE MANAGEMENT IN DUTCH MUNICIPALITIES Hans de Groot (Innovation and Governance Studies, University of Twente) Alex van Heezik (Innovation and Public Sector Efficiency Studies, Delft

More information

ESF Ex-Post evaluation

ESF Ex-Post evaluation ESF 2007-2013 Ex-Post evaluation Fields marked with * are mandatory. Open public consultation Questionnaire Please consult the background document as it provides useful information on the European Social

More information

Relationship between Transformational Leadership and Innovation

Relationship between Transformational Leadership and Innovation Relationship between Transformational Leadership and Innovation Mohammad Hasan akbari Master of Public Administration (Governmental Management) Farabi Campus, University of Tehran Birjand, Iran Gholamreza

More information

Expert meeting on Building an open and innovative government for better policies and service delivery. Paris, 8-9 June 2010

Expert meeting on Building an open and innovative government for better policies and service delivery. Paris, 8-9 June 2010 Expert meeting on Building an open and innovative government for better policies and service delivery Paris, 8-9 June 2010 Background document for session 1 (8 June, 16h 17h) OECD Guiding Principles for

More information

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Jan Van Hove, Sophie Soete and Zuzanna Studnicka University of Leuven Document Identifier D5.10 Case Study on Belgian business succession practices

More information

Technical efficiency gains in European service sectors: The role of information and communication technology. Abstract

Technical efficiency gains in European service sectors: The role of information and communication technology. Abstract Technical efficiency gains in European service sectors: The role of information and communication technology Sophia P. Dimelis a and Sotiris K. Papaioannou b Abstract In this paper, we explore the hypothesis

More information

From Tradition to Innovation. Skill Needs in the Agri-Food Sector Skillsnet conference February 21-22, 2008 Cedefop, Thessaloniki, Greece

From Tradition to Innovation. Skill Needs in the Agri-Food Sector Skillsnet conference February 21-22, 2008 Cedefop, Thessaloniki, Greece From Tradition to Innovation. Skill Needs in the Agri-Food Sector Skillsnet conference February 21-22, 2008 Cedefop, Thessaloniki, Greece Prof. dr. Martin Mulder Head chair group of Education and Competence

More information

1980s. 1970s. 1990s 15/09/2015. Global Marketing Management: Planning and Organization. Learning Objectives. Global Marketing Management.

1980s. 1970s. 1990s 15/09/2015. Global Marketing Management: Planning and Organization. Learning Objectives. Global Marketing Management. Global Marketing Management: Planning and Organization Chapter 12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Learning Objectives LO1 LO2 LO3 LO4 How global

More information

2 ENERGY TECHNOLOGY RD&D BUDGETS: OVERVIEW (2017 edition) Released in October 2017. The IEA energy RD&D data collection and the analysis presented in this paper were performed by Remi Gigoux under the

More information

Farm structures. This document does not necessarily represent the official views of the European Commission

Farm structures. This document does not necessarily represent the official views of the European Commission Farm structures Content 1. EU farms - characteristics and trends... 3 Physical farm size... 4 Economic farm size... 8 Declining farm numbers... 11 Organisational structure... 13 Land ownership... 14 Farm

More information

Topic 3. Entry Modes

Topic 3. Entry Modes Topic 3 Entry Modes Entering Foreign Markets Non Equity Modes Exporting Direct exporting Indirect exporting Subcontracting Licensing Franchising Contracts Management Contract Contract Manufacturing Non-Equity

More information

Small Firms, their Customers and the Value of Strategic Alliances and Networks to Innovation

Small Firms, their Customers and the Value of Strategic Alliances and Networks to Innovation Small Firms, their Customers and the Value of Strategic Alliances and Networks to Innovation Dr. Tim Mazzarol Centre for Entrepreneurial Management & Innovation, GSM University of Western Australia mazzarol@gsm.uwa.edu.au

More information

The relative influences of government funding and. international collaboration on citation impact

The relative influences of government funding and. international collaboration on citation impact The relative influences of government funding and international collaboration on citation impact Loet Leydesdorff,* 1 Lutz Bornmann, 2 and Caroline S. Wagner 3 Abstract In a recent publication in Nature,

More information

Employment, innovation, and productivity: evidence from Italian microdata

Employment, innovation, and productivity: evidence from Italian microdata Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 17, Number 4, pp. 813 839 doi:10.1093/icc/dtn022 Advance Access published July 10, 2008 Employment, innovation, and productivity: evidence from Italian microdata

More information

Managing in Emerging Networks: Case MSN. Senja Svahn Helsinki School of Economics

Managing in Emerging Networks: Case MSN. Senja Svahn Helsinki School of Economics Managing in Emerging Networks: Case MSN Senja Svahn Helsinki School of Economics Competitive paper submitted to the 20 th IMP Conference, 2-4 September 2004, Copenhagen, Denmark. Helsinki School of Economics,

More information

Assessing the Macroeconomic Effects of Competition Policy - the Impact on Economic Growth

Assessing the Macroeconomic Effects of Competition Policy - the Impact on Economic Growth Economic Insights Trends and Challenges Vol.IV(LXVII) No. 3/2015 81-88 Assessing the Macroeconomic Effects of Competition Policy - the Impact on Economic Growth Oana Romano The Bucharest University of

More information

INNOVATIVE ORGANIZATION, INNOVATION, AND INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD

INNOVATIVE ORGANIZATION, INNOVATION, AND INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD Pregledni naučni rad UDC 001.895:331.103 INNOVATIVE ORGANIZATION, INNOVATION, AND INNOVATION UNION SCOREBOARD Edita Kastratovic 1, Lidija Miletic 2, Milan Dragic 3 1 Faculty of Business Economy and Entrepreneurship,

More information

GROWTH PATTERNS IN R&D PARTNERSHIPS: AN EXPLORATORY STATISTICAL STUDY. John Hagedoorn. Hans van Kranenburg. October 7, 2002

GROWTH PATTERNS IN R&D PARTNERSHIPS: AN EXPLORATORY STATISTICAL STUDY. John Hagedoorn. Hans van Kranenburg. October 7, 2002 GROWTH PATTERNS IN R&D PARTNERSHIPS: AN EXPLORATORY STATISTICAL STUDY John Hagedoorn Hans van Kranenburg October 7, 2002 Final version of paper for IJIO, MS 1974. The authors would like to thank Alok Chakrabarti,

More information

Irina Levina. Decentralization of decision-making at the firm: comparative analysis of firms in 7 European countries and Russia.

Irina Levina. Decentralization of decision-making at the firm: comparative analysis of firms in 7 European countries and Russia. Irina Levina Institute for Industrial and Market Studies, National Research University Higher School of Economics Decentralization of decision-making at the firm: comparative analysis of firms in 7 European

More information

WHY DO THE PRIMARY ENERGY INTENSITIES OF THE EU14 DIFFER?

WHY DO THE PRIMARY ENERGY INTENSITIES OF THE EU14 DIFFER? WHY DO THE PRIMARY ENERGY INTENSITIES OF THE EU14 DIFFER? Zeus Guevara a, Sergio Muñoz a, Sofia Henriques b, Tania Sousa c a Institute of Economic Research, National Autonomous University of Mexico, Circuito

More information

Data for Development: DAC Member Priorities and Challenges

Data for Development: DAC Member Priorities and Challenges Data for Development: DAC Member Priorities and Challenges Valentina Sanna and Ida Mc Donnell OECD DEVELOPMENT CO-OPERATION WORKING PAPER 35 Authorised for publication by Brenda Killen, Deputy Director,

More information

Quantifying the opportunity European Market Sizing Study for ETSA (June 2014)

Quantifying the opportunity European Market Sizing Study for ETSA (June 2014) Quantifying the opportunity European Market Sizing Study for ETSA (June 2014) NB: Deloitte has not audited data transmitted by ETSA members, and cannot guarantee the accuracy of the data provided 1 1.

More information

Knowledge for Africa s Development: Innovation, Education, and Information and Communications Technologies Johannesburg, South Africa, May 8-10, 2006 DEVELOPING AND IMPLEMENTING KNOWLEDGE STRATEGIES EXPERIENCES

More information

HOW TO GET INFRASTRUCTURE GOVERNANCE RIGHT AND THE STATE OF PLAY IN OECD COUNTRIES

HOW TO GET INFRASTRUCTURE GOVERNANCE RIGHT AND THE STATE OF PLAY IN OECD COUNTRIES HOW TO GET INFRASTRUCTURE GOVERNANCE RIGHT AND THE STATE OF PLAY IN OECD COUNTRIES Ian Hawkesworth, Snr Public Sector Expert, World Bank Camila Vammale, Snr Policy Analyst, OECD Juliane Jansen, Policy

More information

OUTLINE FOR A CLIENT SURVEY STUDY

OUTLINE FOR A CLIENT SURVEY STUDY OUTLINE FOR A CLIENT SURVEY STUDY Submitted by the Secretariat This Room Document is to be discussed by the WP-EV Informal Subgroup on Peer Reviews on 13 November. A report on these discussions will be

More information

HUMAN CAPITAL AND INTERNATIONAL COMPETITIVENESS OF OECD COUNTRIES

HUMAN CAPITAL AND INTERNATIONAL COMPETITIVENESS OF OECD COUNTRIES Adam Giegiel Anna Wildowicz Political Economy Chair Economic Faculty Białystok University HUMAN CAPITAL AND INTERNATIONAL COMPETITIVENESS OF OECD COUNTRIES Abstract The main purpose of this article is

More information

LOW R&D EFFICIENCY IN LARGE PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES

LOW R&D EFFICIENCY IN LARGE PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES American Journal of Medical Research 3(2), 2016 pp. 141 151, ISSN 2334-4814, eissn 2376-4481 LOW R&D EFFICIENCY IN LARGE PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES ERIK STRØJER MADSEN Ema@econ.au.dk Department of Economics

More information

working papers series social sciences Firm collaboration and modes of innovation in Norway in Economics and Social Sciences 2011/12 institute

working papers series social sciences Firm collaboration and modes of innovation in Norway in Economics and Social Sciences 2011/12 institute institute social sciences in Economics and Social Sciences 2011/12 Firm collaboration and modes of innovation in Norway by Rune Dahl Fitjar and Andrés Rodríguez-Pose July 2011 Ctra. Colmenar Viejo km.

More information

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence

The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: Reconciling the Evidence ECB - BoC Workshop : Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment 15-16 June 2011 Christiane Baumeister Ehsan U. Choudhri Lawrence Schembri

More information

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy Chapter 8 Firms in the Global Economy Summary 1. Introduction International trade is an important economic activity 2. General equilibrium model There are welfare gains from trade whenever relative prices

More information

Belgium s position in world trade

Belgium s position in world trade Belgium s position in world trade Belgium s position in world trade V. Baugnet K. Burggraeve L. Dresse Ch. Piette B. Vuidar Introduction The central role played by international trade in goods and services

More information

Producer Preferences and Characteristics in Biomass Supply Chains. Ira J. Altman Southern Illinois University-Carbondale

Producer Preferences and Characteristics in Biomass Supply Chains. Ira J. Altman Southern Illinois University-Carbondale Producer Preferences and Characteristics in Biomass Supply Chains Ira J. Altman Southern Illinois University-Carbondale Tom G. Johnson University of Missouri-Columbia Wanki Moon Southern Illinois University-Carbondale

More information

OPEN FOR INNOVATION: THE ROLE OF OPENNESS IN EXPLAINING INNOVATION PERFORMANCE AMONG U.K. MANUFACTURING FIRMS

OPEN FOR INNOVATION: THE ROLE OF OPENNESS IN EXPLAINING INNOVATION PERFORMANCE AMONG U.K. MANUFACTURING FIRMS Strategic Management Journal Strat. Mgmt. J., 27: 131 150 (2006) Published online 21 November 2005 in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/smj.507 OPEN FOR INNOVATION: THE ROLE

More information