GSM Association comments on the Draft BEREC Report on Oligopoly Analysis and Regulation (BoR (15) 74) 1 August 2015

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "GSM Association comments on the Draft BEREC Report on Oligopoly Analysis and Regulation (BoR (15) 74) 1 August 2015"

Transcription

1 BEREC ref. No BoR PC03 (15) 14 GSM Association comments on the Draft BEREC Report on Oligopoly Analysis and Regulation (BoR (15) 74) 1 August 2015 About the GSMA The GSMA represents the interests of mobile operators worldwide, uniting nearly 800 operators with more than 250 companies in the broader mobile ecosystem, including handset and device makers, software companies, equipment providers and Internet companies, as well as organisations in adjacent industry sectors. The GSMA also produces industry-leading events such as Mobile World Congress, Mobile World Congress Shanghai and the Mobile 360 Series conferences. For more information, please visit the GSMA corporate website at Follow the GSMA on Policy Contacts: Emanuela Lecchi Head of Competition elecchi[at]gsma.com Laszlo Toth Head of Office, Europe ltoth[at]gsma.com 1

2 1. SUMMARY The GSMA welcomes the opportunity to comment on BEREC s Draft Report on Oligopoly Analysis and Regulation ( Draft Report ). As the GSMA represents specifically the mobile industry, the following comments focus on issues concerning mobile networks. BEREC accepts that oligopolies do not necessarily lead to poor outcomes for consumers, if long run and short run competitive effects are taken into account. It proposes to adapt the Significant Impediment of Effective Competition (SIEC) test from merger cases into an ex-ante regulatory test for dealing with what might be viewed as poorly functioning oligopolies. The GSMA believes that creating a novel oligopoly regime will lead to uncertainty for investors, national regulators and competition authorities for the following reasons: SMP regulation has clear boundaries, it is about what to do when a party with Significant Market Power has been identified; similarly Collective SMP requires the finding of joint SMP based on the so-called Airtours criteria, we note that BEREC sees this as a substantial burden of proof; yet The proposed oligopoly regulation appears to require a subjective determination of whether a market is functioning in the consumer interest; and oligopoly regulation would be applicable to the telecoms industry only, compounding the issue that already the telecoms industry is subject to regulation over and above other sectors of the economy. We believe that the creation of a subjective test, with no case law sat behind it, would make the oligopoly regulation unworkable in practice. The SIEC test used in merger provides no assistance to the measurement and assessment of the absolute quality of competition and as BEREC accepts, the new exante process would require the balancing of a wide range of static and dynamic competitive factors. If BEREC considers that a new regime of regulating oligopolies could be based on the SIEC test, further clarity is required as to how this would be applied. Alternatively, if BEREC is considering the type of approach that the Commission (and certain national authorities) employs in market investigations, then this also needs to be explained in more detail. Mobile markets have either not had operators with SMP, or seen the removal of SMP conditions very early on, to such an extent that the market for access and call origination was removed from the list of relevant markets. While national licensing regimes and high investment requirements preserve the characteristics of more concentrated markets for mobile network operators, competitive pressures from MVNOs and Internet-based content and application providers (CAPs) deliver competitive outcomes for consumers, in terms of prices, choice, quality, investment and innovation. It is the view of the GSMA that the forthcoming review of the electronic communications regulatory framework should focus on modernising and wherever possible reducing regulation in the mobile sector taking full account of new sources of disruptive competition that are emerging from non-traditional sources. A major concern of the GSMA is that BEREC seems to see the need for regulatory action on oligopolies as a consequence of consolidation, raising the spectrum of multiple reviews and disparate national outcomes following mergers already examined by a competition authority with a general remit over the economy as a whole. In this paper, the GSMA: Considers the theoretical pricing assumptions that underpin the Draft Report and warns that economic models should be treated with caution, as they do not capture some of the defining features of telecommunications markets including sunk cost, investment levels and quality 2

3 differentiation. The GSMA believes that consumer benefit should not be exclusively framed by a debate about lowest price. (section 2); Considers the factors singled out for a finding that a tight oligopoly exists and concludes that there is not sufficient clarity about what factors would lead to a positive determination (section 3); Believes that BEREC should better take into account in its Final Report the broader market trends that have a profound impact on the telecoms sector. (section 4); Specifically focuses on the two scenarios in which regulation of oligopolies could take place (greenfield regulation and lifting of existing regulation). The GSMA believes that if NRAs can move in to regulate at the national level newly merged parties (after a merger investigation), outside the boundaries of SMP regulation and competition law, there would be serious implications for the Digital Single Market (section 5); Singles out a lack of clarity on the burden of proof in the two above scenarios and raises concerns that regulation would happen on the basis of reliance on hypotheticals (Section 6); Expresses concerns that these proposals will lead to an extra layer of regulation imposed on the telecoms sector only. (Section 7); and Explains that merger control is not the appropriate benchmark to consider, nor a justification for extra regulation of tight oligopolies (Section 8). In this paper we also point to some of the inconsistencies in the Draft Report and we encourage BEREC to eliminate them when finalising the Report. The GSMA does not have much to add to the debate about the framework for regulating coordinated oligopolies. The framework for intervention both as a matter of competition law (in joint dominance cases) and indeed in the context of merger control (applying the Airtours criteria) is quite well established and we broadly agree with the framework set out in the Draft Report. We would like to note that existing precedent would not appear to support a finding of coordinated oligopoly in the mobile industry. As BEREC states in several paragraphs, one of the necessary conditions for coordination is transparency in the market, such that a focal point can be identified, and that it should be relatively simple to monitor adherence. Given that BEREC also notes that collusion is often price based, it is important to bear in mind that the mobile industry has a very large range of retail tariffs and menus of non-linear tariffs for both individual and business customers. Furthermore, many customers will often have tailored tariffs and/or special offers. This is consistent with NRA s findings, for example, in the UK Ofcom found in the 2015 Mobile Call Termination review, that there is a high degree of retail price discrimination in the mobile market. 1 It is therefore not clear that prices are sufficiently transparent for operators to use as a focal point for collusion. 2. PRICING IN TELECOMS There are two points on pricing in the telecoms sector that we believe warrant further consideration and discussion by BEREC. First, in Section the Draft Report discusses socially optimal prices in a perfectly competitive market and why prices are often above the competitive level in an oligopoly. In particular, BEREC states (page 12) that in oligopolistic markets as well as in a monopoly, prices are typically above marginal costs, foremost, because firms are able to exert a degree of market power. Such a characterisation, correct in 1 Ofcom, Mobile Call Termination Statement (2015), Paragraph /statement/MCT_final_statement.pdf 3

4 general economic theory, does not hold true in the telecommunications market. As BEREC notes in a number of places, the sector is characterised by significant sunk costs as well as fixed and common costs. The concept of marginal cost is therefore not useful because it is generally close to (or equal to) zero until a network reaches capacity, at which point the marginal cost of serving an additional customer (or of providing another minute of voice or another bit of data) is extremely high. For this reason, telecom regulators use the Long Run Incremental Cost (or LRIC) concept rather than marginal cost. Furthermore, due to the presence of fixed and common costs and in order to recover investments that are sunk, it is necessary for operators to charge prices above LRIC for a number of services. Therefore, in the telecommunications sector, prices for certain products have to be above LRIC in order for firms to recover their efficiently incurred costs, not because they are able to exert some market power. 2 This will be the case even if prices are at the competitive level. Of course, it is also necessary for regulators and competition authorities to take dynamic efficiency into account as well as static efficiency when considering telecoms markets. This is something that BEREC notes in the Draft Report (Sections and ) and we agree on this point. Secondly, we are concerned about the reference to prices being high in telecoms markets made throughout the Draft Report (see specifically the discussion of capacity constraints and the demand-side factors discussed below), despite the acknowledgement that the cost structure is determined by the presence of high investment costs which have to be covered on a long lasting basis (page 51). The European mobile industry has seen significant reductions in absolute and per unit pricing alongside improvements in coverage, reliability and capability. The revenue pool of the industry faces downward pressures from competition, while operators must undertake significant investments to meet increasing demand for broadband access and innovative services. A certain degree of consolidation is necessary in some markets to provide operators with the resources and incentives to invest in network upgrades and new services. Investment in new technology is the most important determinant of consumer outcomes in mobile markets. Frequent technology cycles significantly increase capacity, and reducing unit prices through higher volumes. We agree with BEREC that it is difficult to assess whether a specific price level reflects effective competition from a dynamic perspective, or whether it should be considered non-competitive from a short term perspective. (page 51). But the Draft Report then sets out different ways of assessing national price trends or making international comparisons, which may well be misleading as price levels across different country markets are influenced by many factors beyond competitive intensity 3. The GSMA is particularly concerned that BEREC intends to advocate for NRAs the right to assess whether a specific price level reflects effective competition from a dynamic perspective, or whether it should be considered noncompetitive from a short term perspective. It can easily be discerned how unsettling it would be for any firms contemplating a merger and for their investors, to face the prospect of a lengthy investigation by 2 Indeed, following the EC s 2009 Recommendation that NRAs should set mobile termination rates (MTRs) at LRIC, a number of regulators reduced MTRs on the basis that a portion of fixed and common costs could be recovered from retail markets. See for example Section 8 of Ofcom s 2011 Mobile Call Termination Statement. 3 Price levels across different country markets are influenced by many factors including differences in input costs for items such as labour, real estate costs and network/capacity leasing, differences in the upfront and ongoing costs of mobile spectrum, differences in taxation, GDP per capita, population density, the level of maturity of the market for mobile data. Unless these factors can be robustly controlled for, we believe that the most informative metric for regulators to consider are operators return on capital employed over the long-term (as there will inevitably be variation year-on-year). Such analysis should ideally reflect economic rates of return rather than accounting rates of return, as company accounts can often over- or understate economic costs. 4

5 the competition authorities under generally applicable merger control, possibly leading to commitments, and then face the NRAs investigations at the national level. Low incentives for investment in the telecoms industry will then not be indicators of non-effective competition. More likely, they will be indicators of non-effective regulation. 3. DEFINING TIGHT OLIGOPOLIES : THE SEVEN FACTORS The term tight oligopolist has not generally been used in competition and regulatory policy. The GSMA considers tight oligopoly and non-coordinated oligopoly to be equivalent terms. In the context of a regulatory discussion, we believe there would be merit in not multiplying the (already complex) concepts to be used. 4 BEREC lists seven main factors that could lead to ineffective oligopolistic competition in the absence of (tacit) collusion. The presence of one or more of these factors is said to possibly lead to unilateral behaviour which forms a self-sustaining reduction in competition and prevents the development of competitive outcomes (page 16). We consider that one or more factors does not provide enough clarity to either regulators or operators, particularly as BEREC later states (page 50) that the number of firms does not give a complete impression of the competition effects : therefore, market concentration on its own is not sufficient for a finding of a tight oligopoly (see also high market concentration, below). The Draft Report goes on to state that Instead, these effects must always be assessed in the light of additional factors ; however, these additional factors are not specified (page 50). That notwithstanding, elsewhere (page 16) BEREC seems to single out two factors: capacity constraints and high entry barriers, and quotes spectrum availability in mobile as an example for both. We do not agree with this example and we are concerned that BEREC may be basing its views on incorrect or outdated factual assumptions (see discussion below under Capacity Constraints ). High market concentration: The presence of a high market concentration is inherent in the definition of an oligopoly. Therefore, if high market concentration on its own were sufficient for a finding of a tight oligopoly and if it could be used to justify ex-ante regulation, then this would be tantamount to imposing regulation on all oligopolies. If BEREC agrees that high market concentration is not sufficient on its own to justify regulation, it would be helpful to amend the position in the Draft Report that states that ineffective competition may occur when one or more factors are present in a market (for example on page 16). BEREC refers to OPTA s Economic Policy Note entitled Is two enough? 5 to justify the inclusion of this factor. If by high market concentration BEREC has in mind a duopoly rather than an oligopoly, it should be noted that, in the mobile sector at a national level, a two-operator structure cannot be found in the 28 EU Member States. High entry barriers and no significant new entrants: Throughout the Draft Report, there is an assumption that telecoms markets are subject to high barriers to entry 6. The only remedy referred to specifically in 4 The term tight oligopoly refers to oligopolistic market structures that cause non-effective market outcomes, without explicit collaboration or tacit collusion. (page 48) 5 Footnote 66 6 Para : high entry barriers due to, for example, substantial economies of scale, high fixed or sunk costs, legal barriers, patents or exclusive resource ownership may result in a low number of firms on the market. 5

6 the Draft Report as appropriate for tight oligopolists is tackling entry barriers (by way of wholesale access obligations imposed to ensure access for new entrants).7 The GSMA agrees that if innovation was likely, new firms could enter the market more easily based on new technologies, circumventing existing entry barriers. 8 Taking the example of services based on mobile platforms, customers clearly see these as substitutable irrespective of technology, whether they are delivered over mobile networks or IP protocol. However, there appears to be an inconsistency in the Draft Report, as at , it states: Both [text messaging and instant messaging] services may serve a similar purpose, but given that instant messaging uses different technology, they may not belong to the same relevant market". It is not clear from BEREC s Draft Report how the use of different technology affects demand-side substitution (which is one of the key considerations in defining markets). More generally, entry barriers can stem from a variety of sources, including regulatory controls. In mobile markets, entry to wholesale markets is organised by physical (e.g. radio spectrum); economic (e.g. high sunk costs) and regulatory (e.g. spectrum auctions; licensing regimes) constraints. Even when spectrum is made available specifically to attract new entrants, as happened with the remedy imposed in the merger of Hutchison 3G and Orange in Austria, this is no guarantee of new market entry. Where physical, economic, or regulatory barriers are lowered, such as in wholesale mobile access markets, many geographic markets across the EU have seen rapid entry of MVNOs, 9 based on wholesale access granted by mobile operators on a commercial basis. High level product differentiation: BEREC states that, unlike in the case of co-ordinated effects, characterised by homogeneity in the products offered, non-coordinated oligopolies are more likely to occur where the level of product differentiation is higher. 10 BEREC characterises telecoms markets as fairly homogeneous compared to other retail goods, but there are some ways in which they may be differentiated, such as in the case of bundled offerings. We have the following comments on this point. First, it is important to distinguish between regulation of an existing market place and an analysis in merger control (see below, section 8). Secondly, in regulation market definition is the first step if substitutability exists, the market should be defined accordingly (often, more widely). For example taking CAPs into account in market assessments will show that there is a much greater level of competition in most markets than is currently recognised by regulatory authorities and, consequently, will justify a significant degree of deregulation. If substitutability does not occur, any one provider of a bundle may have a position of single SMP in the marketplace. Thirdly, high level of product differentiation is prized by consumers and is a consequence of innovation brought about by competition. Capacity constraints: as a matter of economic theory, capacity constraints may impede oligopolists from competing on price when they cannot adjust output in response to a competitor s price rises. This aspect is considered in general at page 16 of the BEREC Draft Report the example given for capacity constraints 7 Para 8. Page 59 8 Footnote 12 9 GSMA Intelligence, The Global MVNO Footprint: A Changing Environment, February See also: Analysys Mason, MVNO market analysis: status update, emerging opportunities and outlook for Europe, April 2014; 10 Para 7.1.1, page 51 6

7 is the fact that spectrum availability may be limited. 11 We believe this is an over-simplification. As markets move to 4G, there might be overcapacity. In the 2005 ARCEP case summarised in Annex A, the French competition authority pointed out that the third MNO at least experienced overcapacity in its network and therefore that the scenario in which the third MNO would grant wholesale access to an MVNO was at least as probable as the scenario presented by ARCEP, weakening the case for ex-ante regulation. In BEREC s assessment of capacity constraints on page 37, it notes that in case ES/2005/0330 the NRA found that all of the providers were able to adjust their capacity easily. We also note that BEREC concludes that other factors than capacity constraints may be more relevant. Demand side restrictions: High switching costs, low growth of demand, low cross-price elasticity and no countervailing buyer power are all listed as factors which may enhance the market power exerted by the firms on the market (p 51). It appears from the examples that BEREC considers that these factors apply to the mobile sector. We would therefore make the following two points. First, consumers of mobile services value quality, in the form of network coverage, data speed, new and improved handsets. The ever-increasing demand for new content, higher bandwidth and new handsets is evidence that in mobile markets, demand continues to grow. Many consumers have more than one subscription, and there is growing interest in converged (CAP / mobile) services. As BEREC itself points out, 12 when growth is rapid, it would be easier for new firms to enter the market, because there are many potential new customers. Second, price elasticity is increasing in many mobile markets. Notably, in today s converging markets consumers are able to migrate to competing technologies if they perceive them to be better value than mobile. With the near-ubiquitous availability of Wi-Fi, switching between mobile and alternative networks has become very easy and commonplace. 4. THE DYNAMICS OF CHANGE IN THE MARKETPLACE AND ROLE OF CAPS ARE UNDERESTIMATED The GSMA is concerned about the assumption that these seven factors should apply to the mobile sector, making it a prime candidate for extra regulation of tight oligopolies, at a time when the mobile market is subject to fundamental changes and fierce competition. Before imposing any remedies in competition law or adopting any extra regulation, a market must be defined and then analysed. At page 59 of the Draft Report, 13 BEREC makes reference to the growing complexity of the link between retail and wholesale communications products, some of which fall outside the definition of electronic communications services in the current EU regulatory framework. This growing complexity is a crucial point and we believe BEREC should discuss this in more detail in its Final Report. For example, at page 8 of the Draft Report there seems to be some recognition of the changes in the industry, from which BEREC simply takes that consolidation in the industry may lead to oligopolies. 14 It appears that the Draft Report 11 See also page 37: In mobile telecommunications markets, capacity constraints may be more likely to be present, for example because it can be hard to obtain more spectrum or more sites. Capacity may be more constrained if the network is shared. But, so long as these constraints are similar it may be that collusion can be sustained. 12 Footnote And, very briefly, on page This evolution of the European telecommunications market is also conditioned by a trend towards consolidation of the industry via mergers and acquisitions. [ ] the increased occurrence of oligopolistic market structures, [ ] raises issues as to the level of competition in [the] markets as well as the question of the necessity and 7

8 is partly based upon those regulatory cases on access and call origination on public mobile telephone networks summarised in Annex A, All of these pre-date the launch of the iphone (2007) 15, which revolutionised the mobile market. We believe that if the indirect constraints that CAPs pose on telcos are properly considered in market definition and in market analysis, the market may not be an oligopoly at all. Even if an oligopoly exists, the pressure in many retail markets constrains wholesale pricing. With very few exceptions, even wholesale markets with fewer than four operators prove to be highly competitive. The move from four to three operators coexists with continuing and rapid price fall in the vast majority of downstream and retail markets. The mobile markets are very unlikely to lead to uncompetitive outcomes as they tend to be characterised by multiple infrastructure players with spare capacity and this provides incentives to offer wholesale access to third parties. Indeed, commercial MVNO agreements are the norm across Europe and that there is no evidence that this will change going forward. Europe is home to two thirds of MVNOs (585) in the world 16. In addition to that CAPs are another source of competition in wholesale markets, they are also exerting competitive pressure on operators through their buying power and their ability to enable users to choose between operators. The ability for access providers to attract exclusive content or certain flagship services and the ability for CAPS/hardware vendors to steer demand to ISPs can have significant impact on wholesale access conditions. The Draft Report recognises that at services level CAPs can exercise competitive pressure - it does not, however, consider that this impacts the wholesale access conditions. 5. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE DIGITAL SINGLE MARKET TWO SCENARIOS According to BEREC, the two situations in which NRAs potentially should have additional powers to intervene (para ) are: (i) (ii) in a market never previously regulated, NRAs wish to regulate operators without SMP, on the basis that these are tight oligopolists ; and in an already regulated market, due to a change in the market structure, the previously determined operator with single SMP (or, it seems the operators previously determined to have collective SMP) no longer have SMP. In the first scenario, no operator has even been subject to SMP regulation and each NRA will, under the proposal, decide whether to regulate, outside the current system of SMP regulation. In the second scenario, BEREC seems concerned at the prospect that existing regulation may be lifted. It therefore appears to be proposing an extra step: notwithstanding a finding of non-smp, regulation could remain in place, or different regulation could be imposed on the tight oligopolists. It seems that a major concern for BEREC is that, in the case of a merger between two smaller market players, the operator previously in a position of SMP finds itself less powerful (because it is subject to increased competition, which should presumably be welcomed). On this point, we note that any noncoordinated effects arising out of a merger would be properly analysed by the competition authority during the merger investigation, using a SIEC test when appropriate. effectiveness of ex-ante regulatory intervention in addressing any potential anticompetitive behaviour in such oligopolistic markets. 15 The Slovenian case was in 2008, but too early for the impact of smartphones to be properly assessed 16 GSMA Intelligence, The Global MVNO Footprint: A Changing Environment, February

9 One other instance when telecoms regulation is lifted occurs when the markets subject to regulation are no longer referred to in the EU Recommendation on Market, a fact recognised by BEREC on page 33 (and footnote 47): most of the regulatory cases considered in the Draft Report (Annex A) relate to markets no longer subject to SMP regulation. Therefore, the extra tool that NRAs wish to be granted could be used as a back-stop that could lead to continued regulation, along national lines, or could lead to new regulation in some countries but not others. There is a risk associated with such a proposal as it could side-step the system of SMP regulation which, to date, constitutes an important area of harmonisation across EU Member States. This would have important consequences for the very existence of a Digital Single Market. The EU encompasses a diverse range of economies and this is reflected in the competitive dynamics, price points, investment levels, penetration, coverage within national mobile markets. A decision by one NRA that its county s particular mix of parameters demonstrates a wellfunctioning oligopoly would imply that many other Member States have poorly functioning oligopolies, as their parameters would diverge from the optimal result posited by this NRA. Conversely, if an NRA found that its market was functioning sub-optimally, it would need to determine the optimal outcome in order to set remedies. In so doing, it would again be sending a signal to all other NRAs about the functioning (or otherwise) of their markets. In addition, would there be some proven competitive concerns in a given oligopolistic market, BEREC has not considered the possibility to use existing tools; when looking at the criteria listed by BEREC it indeed omits to take on board that the framework encompasses relevant provisions on issues such as switching, transparency (universal service directive), general access and interconnection obligations (access directive), symmetric access to given bottlenecks (framework directive). 6. THE TWO SCENARIOS - BURDEN OF PROOF BEREC seems to consider that there is a difference in approach between the two scenarios above, as regards the burden of proof. It is not entirely clear from the Draft Report what BEREC s key concern is as it considers both in the context of an assessment of collective SMP and of a tight oligopoly. Our understanding is that BEREC considers that the second scenario, cases where the NRA is reviewing a market previously subject to regulation, should lead to a different type of proof, but not a different standard of proof. BEREC equates this situation to one in which a competition authority carries out a merger investigation and it appears to conclude that in this second scenario, more reliance should be based on hypotheticals rather than facts. 17 The GSMA is unsure about what is proposed here, 18 but we have three concerns with the above conclusion (assuming our understanding of BEREC s proposals are correct). 17 See for example, at Page 47: Based on the above we conclude that the type of proof that NRAs can use in a regulated environment differs slightly from the evidence that Competition Authorities or NRAs in an unregulated environment can use. Hence, it seems likely that not so much the standard of proof that is being applied is or should be different but that the type of proof may be different. In a regulated environment NRAs will have to rely more on expectations and economic reasoning than on actual facts. (as in merger control). (emphasis added) 18 Page 48: Lastly, we considered what the appropriate standard of proof should be in terms of ex-ante intervention in a case of joint dominance. One could argue that the standard of proof for joint dominance in markets with existing (single SMP) regulation in place should be lower when compared to markets with no regulation in place. However, given the possible impact the imposition of regulation may have BEREC does not find 9

10 First, BEREC distinguishes the two scenarios on the basis that the second (lifting regulation) leads to an analysis to be done from a forward-looking perspective through evaluating the likely market developments, whereas the first (introducing new regulation) is done on the basis of a market assessment essentially made with regard to the current market structure and an observable market outcome (page 52). The GSMA considers that the introduction of regulation should always be forward-looking and always be based on an assessment of empirical evidence. Based on the current drafting, we are concerned that, in the context of markets which are no longer included in the Commission Recommendation on Relevant Markets, BEREC is advocating reliance on hypotheticals for continued regulation. Secondly, BEREC suggests that the findings of fact in scenario 2 are skewed by application of regulation in the previous period, leading to it being difficult, if not impossible, for regulators to depend on empirical evidence and factual data. 19 We disagree with this point and would argue that the facts that led to the adoption of regulation in the first place can be re-assessed in the context of a new market structure (and indeed that reassessment constitutes the basis for excluding markets from the Recommendation). Thirdly, we consider that regulation should not be based on a hypothetical scenario, which could be as possible as another hypothetical scenario. Much as the ARCEP case mentioned in Annex A proves, if a competitive outcome is hypothetically possible, the fact that another scenario (anti-competitive) is also possible, does not seem to be sound basis for regulation. 7. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE REGULATORY LEVEL PLAYING FIELD The GSMA is concerned that BEREC s proposal may lead to the adoption by NRAs of regulation of oligopolies in the telecom sector only, fragmented along national lines. We believe that any proposals to adopt extra controls of oligopolies should be considered across all sectors of the economy and that there should not be a presumption that oligopolistic market structures require ex-ante regulatory remedies. Ex-ante remedies should only be considered following careful analysis with clear evidence of durable market failure or abuse and, even then, when no other remedies exist. The GSMA contends that there is little or no evidence of mobile market failure and that the current framework provides all the tools necessary to address any concerns should they arise. Mobile markets have either not had operators with SMP, or seen the removal of SMP conditions very early on, to such an extent that the market for access and call origination was removed from the list of relevant markets. While national licensing regimes and high investment requirements preserve the characteristics of more concentrated markets for mobile network operators, competitive pressures from MVNOs and CAPs deliver competitive outcomes for consumers, in terms of prices, choice, quality, investment and innovation. The envisaged broadening of the ex-ante regulation in the telecoms sector raises concerns of successive layers of regulatory intervention. The sector has already subject to horizontal regulation (eg consumer it appropriate to do so. According to BEREC the standard of proof between regulated and unregulated markets is equal, i.e. in both cases SMP has to be proven. We also considered the types of evidence used for proving joint SMP. We argued that in markets with existing regulation in place it is hard, if not impossible, for NRAs to use empirical evidence. On the other hand, in markets where there currently is no regulation in place NRAs can rely more on factual evidence because the analysis is less hypothetical in nature. Yet, also for markets without existing regulation in place NRAs still have to cumulatively fulfil the Airtours criteria. 19 Para , page 46 10

11 protection, data protection), and obligations imposed as part of the spectrum licences or the remedies imposed on mergers. Moreover, the proposal would further aggravate the asymmetry of regulation between CAPs and network operators, because it singles out electronic communications providers as the only players to be subject to ex-ante regulation. It is just the opposite of what is needed today. It is the view of the GSMA, that the forthcoming review of the telecoms regulatory framework should focus on modernising and wherever possible reducing regulation in the sector taking full account of new sources of disruptive competition that are emerging from non-traditional sources. In the context of modernising the telecoms regulatory framework, the Digital Single Market Strategy 20 states that [t]here is a need for simpler and more proportionate regulation in those areas where infrastructure competition has emerged at regional or national scale. The deployment of very high capacity networks needs to be encouraged while maintaining effective competition and adequate returns relative to risks. The Strategy also anticipates that the review of the telecoms rules will focus on ensuring a level playing field for market players and consistent application of the rules. We are concerned that the BEREC proposal goes in the opposite direction. Further, it appears that the (alleged) adverse effects on competition of non-coordinated oligopolies could possibly be considered in the context of market investigations, a tool of some competition law systems, notably at the EU level 21 and in some countries, such as the UK 22. In those cases, market investigations can be carried out in any sector of the economy and are carried out by a competition authority, ensuring At the EU level, DG COMP can carry out Sector Inquiries, investigations into sectors of the economy and into types of agreements across various sectors, when it believes that a market is not working as well as it should (and also believes that breaches of the competition rules might be a contributory factor). 22 In the UK, the 2002 Enterprise Act introduced the tool of market investigations. The system involves: a first stage investigation by the competition authority and the sectoral regulators (including Ofcom) at the end of which a reference can be made for a second phase investigation by the general competition authority (used to be the Competition Commission and is now the Panel of the Competition and Markets Authority). Before deciding to make a reference for a second phase investigation, the first stage authority has to consider the following factors: Suitability of using the Competition Act (or sectoral powers) instead of these powers; Possibility of addressing the problem through commitments; The scale of the problem in terms of its adverse effect on competition; Feasibility that appropriate remedies will be available There is no statutory benchmark against which the Competition Authority measures adverse effects on competition. Therefore, the assessment is based on a balance of probabilities and assessed against a wellfunctioning market (i.e. not an idealised perfectly competitive market). Theories of harms drawing on sources such as unilateral market power, barriers to entry, coordinated conduct, vertical relationships and poor customer response to competitive offers - are set out to help with this assessment. Non-coordinated oligopolies refers to unilateral market power by a number of firms acting independently. 11

12 that no single sector is subject to enhanced scrutiny. 23 Granting NRAs specific tools for market investigations in the telecoms sector would mean extra scrutiny of the sector. 8. MERGER CONTROL IS NOT THE APPROPRIATE BENCHMARK BEREC relies on EU merger control, rather than market investigation references, to justify the concept of tight oligopolies as a reason to seek more regulatory tools for NRAs in the telecoms sector. 24 Specifically, the justification would be found in the change to the merger control test from a dominance test to a SIEC test. The GSMA does not agree that the change to the test in the EU Merger Regulation supports the stance taken by BEREC. A merger control investigation is by nature designed to deal with the effects of an anticipated increase in market concentration. This is a change in market structure which will happen as a result of the parties merging. Therefore a decision is made in relation to the appropriate counterfactual: what would happen if the merger did not go ahead. In practice, the existing situation, the status quo, is often the benchmark in merger control. The SIEC test is a comparative test and does not purport to measure the level of competition per se and determine whether it is good or bad. We also note that the move to a SIEC test in EU merger control did not lead to a change to the national systems of merger control in all the EU Member States. 25 It is a fundamentally different situation where a regulator considers a given marketplace to determine whether it requires regulation going forward because the market structure would have oligopolistic characteristics. The SMP regulation was anchored in Article 102 of the EU Treaty, but not the Merger Regulation, because it deals with a situation of significant market power defined in the same way as dominance (albeit that it is a different system, leading to ex ante regulation). We believe that the creation of a subjective test, with no case law sat behind it, would make the oligopoly regulation unworkable in practice. The creation of an ex-ante process for regulating markets without dominant firms would either mean: Double jeopardy for investors, who could see mergers cleared but then draconian ex-ante regulation imposed to address purported competition concerns that did not cause concerns in the merger process; or All mobile mergers being cleared without remedies, because merger authorities would have to take account of an ex-ante regime and its ability to remedy and competition issues that might arise. All of these issues suggest to GSMA that the justification, basis, application and consequences of BEREC s proposal do not justify the new concept of tight oligopoly regulation. 23 As an example, Ofcom in the UK has access to both the tools of SMP regulation and, as a concurrent regulator, the tools of competition law, including market investigation references (to the general competition authority, the CMA). 24 For example, at p 26 of the Draft Report, BEREC states that The introduction of the SIEC test in merger law was a consequence of identified gaps in dealing with merger cases in oligopolistic market structure, where the reliance on the concept of dominance did not seem to be sufficient to ensure effective competition. 25 Only 15 out of the 28 Member States have moved to a SIEC test nationally. 12

GSMA comments on the Draft BEREC Report on OTT services (BoR (15) 142)

GSMA comments on the Draft BEREC Report on OTT services (BoR (15) 142) BoR PC06 (15) 19 GSMA comments on the Draft BEREC Report on OTT services (BoR (15) 142) About the GSMA The GSMA represents the interests of mobile operators worldwide, uniting nearly 800 operators with

More information

Contribution of Orange to BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation

Contribution of Orange to BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation Contribution of Orange to BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation Document number: BoR (15) 74 July 2015 - Name of the organization responding to the questionnaire: Orange - Brief description

More information

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK 201[ ] ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS (GUIDELINES ON MARKET ANALYSIS AND THE ASSESSMENT OF SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER FOR NETWORKS AND SERVICES) (ARRANGEMENT OF GUIDELINES) Table of Contents 1. [Short Title]

More information

BoR (15) 195. BEREC Report on. Oligopoly analysis and regulation

BoR (15) 195. BEREC Report on. Oligopoly analysis and regulation BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation December 2015 Contents 1 Executive summary and main findings... 5 2 Contents of the report... 7 3 Context and objectives of the report... 8 4 Oligopoly

More information

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39 Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39 IRG PUBLIC CONSULTATION DOCUMENT Principles of Implementation and Best Practice

More information

BoR (15)74. BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation

BoR (15)74. BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation BoR (15)74 BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation June 2015 Contents 1 Executive summary and main findings... 5 2 Contents of the report... 7 3 Context and objectives of the report... 8 4 Oligopoly

More information

Position Paper. Cable Europe position paper on the Telecoms Review. Executive Summary. Policy objectives

Position Paper. Cable Europe position paper on the Telecoms Review. Executive Summary. Policy objectives 4 April 2016 Position Paper Cable Europe position paper on the Telecoms Review Executive Summary This Position Paper outlines Cable Europe s response to the Commission s consultation on the revision of

More information

Response to the consultation on the Draft review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies).

Response to the consultation on the Draft review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies). Response to the consultation on the Draft review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies). 7 February 2014 FTTH Council Europe ASBL Rue des Colonies

More information

BBC response to Ofcom s consultation: Broadcast Transmission Services: a review of the market

BBC response to Ofcom s consultation: Broadcast Transmission Services: a review of the market BBC response to Ofcom s consultation: Broadcast Transmission Services: a review of the market 9 June 2016 Overview 1. The BBC welcomes the opportunity to respond to Ofcom s consultation Broadcast Transmission

More information

REPUBLIC OF IRAQ COMMUNICATIONS AND MEDIA COMMISSION

REPUBLIC OF IRAQ COMMUNICATIONS AND MEDIA COMMISSION REPUBLIC OF IRAQ COMMUNICATIONS AND MEDIA COMMISSION CONSULTATION DOCUMENT MARKET REVIEWS JUNE 2016 INTRODUCTION The Communications and Media Commission should impose ex-ante regulation only on operators

More information

Market power and market definition in electronic communications

Market power and market definition in electronic communications Market power and market definition in electronic communications Alexandre de Streel University of Namur and CRIDS CERRE Expert Workshop 21 June 2011 1 Four steps to impose economic regulation in electronic

More information

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group The Directorate General of Competition is contemplating the introduction of Non Horizontal Merger (NHM) Guidelines.

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 18.9.2014 C(2014) 6809 final Autorité de Régulation des Communications électroniques et des Postes (ARCEP) 7, square Max Hymans F-75730 Paris-Cedex 15 France For the attention

More information

BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2017/1960

BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2017/1960 BoR (17) 53 BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2017/1960 Wholesale high-quality access provided at a fixed

More information

COOPVOCE Response to BoR (14) 172. Questions to stakeholders related to the. BEREC Report on Oligopoly - Analysis and Regulation

COOPVOCE Response to BoR (14) 172. Questions to stakeholders related to the. BEREC Report on Oligopoly - Analysis and Regulation BoR PC01 (15) 11 COOPVOCE Response to BoR (14) 172 Questions to stakeholders related to the BEREC Report on Oligopoly - Analysis and Regulation A. Introduction COOPVOCE, one of the leading MVNO operator

More information

Case SI/2009/0957: Wholesale (physical) network infrastructure access (including shared or fully unbundled access) at a fixed location

Case SI/2009/0957: Wholesale (physical) network infrastructure access (including shared or fully unbundled access) at a fixed location EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 11/09/2009 C(2009)7007 SG-Greffe (2009) D/5397 Agencija za pošto in elektronske komunikacije Republike Slovenije (APEK) Stegne 7, p.p. 418 1001 Ljubljana Slovenia For the

More information

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2015/1727

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2015/1727 BoR (15) 85 BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2015/1727 Wholesale local access provided at a fixed location

More information

BoR (14) 73. BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies)

BoR (14) 73. BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies) BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies) 5 June 2014 Contents Executive summary... 3 I. Introduction... 6 II. Basic principles... 7 III. Main cases since

More information

First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines

First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines GRC Conference, 29th September, Brussels First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines Damien Neven* Chief Competition Economist DG COMP, European Commission *The views expressed are my

More information

Response to the consultation on the BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation. FTTH Council Europe ASBL Rue des Colonies Brussels

Response to the consultation on the BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation. FTTH Council Europe ASBL Rue des Colonies Brussels Response to the consultation on the BEREC Report on Oligopoly analysis and regulation. FTTH Council Europe ASBL Rue des Colonies 11 1000 Brussels Belgium Transparency Register ID: 09838612482-61 31 July

More information

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. accompanying the COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. accompanying the COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION EN EN EN COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES Brussels, 7.5.2009 SEC(2009) 600 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT accompanying the COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION on the Regulatory Treatment of Fixed and Mobile

More information

Price regulation of unbundled broadband services

Price regulation of unbundled broadband services Price regulation of unbundled broadband services ARPCE, Brazzaville 19 February 2014 Pedro Seixas, expert ITU International Telecommunication Union Agenda Outline of regulatory issues Price regulation

More information

ReSPONSE by Deutsche Telekom. BEREC Public Consultation on the Draft Review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis

ReSPONSE by Deutsche Telekom. BEREC Public Consultation on the Draft Review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis ReSPONSE by Deutsche Telekom BEREC Public Consultation on the Draft Review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis February 2014 Executive Summary Deutsche Telekom welcomes

More information

Draft Call Termination Regulations Explanatory Note. 05 September 2014

Draft Call Termination Regulations Explanatory Note. 05 September 2014 Draft Call Termination Regulations 2014 Explanatory Note 05 September 2014 Page 1 of 27 Contents 1. Introduction... 4 2. An outline of the process followed... 5 Operator Access to the Top-Down and Bottom-Up

More information

AIIP comments on the

AIIP comments on the AIIP comments on the BEREC Common Position on best practice remedies on the market for wholesale broadband access (including bitstream access) imposed as a consequence of a position of significant market

More information

New powers for telecoms and media regulators? Part 1: the rise of oligopolists

New powers for telecoms and media regulators? Part 1: the rise of oligopolists Agenda Advancing economics in business New powers for telecoms and media regulators? Part 1: the rise of oligopolists Continued M&A activity in the fixed and mobile telecoms sector is creating more concentrated

More information

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry Mergers Types of Mergers Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry Vertical Merger this is a merger between two firms at different stages of the production

More information

Mobile call termination market review

Mobile call termination market review MA Mobile call termination market review 2018-21 Annexes 1-14 Consultation Publication date: 27 June 2017 Closing Date for Responses: 5 September 2017 Contents Annex Page 1 Responding to this consultation

More information

BoR (12) 40. BEREC Report of the Consultation on the draft BEREC report on Co-investment and SMP in NGA networks

BoR (12) 40. BEREC Report of the Consultation on the draft BEREC report on Co-investment and SMP in NGA networks BEREC Report of the Consultation on the draft BEREC report on Co-investment and SMP in NGA networks 24 May 2012 This document contains BEREC s report on the outcome of the public consultation on the Draft

More information

1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration

1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration 1. Market Definition, Measurement And Concentration 1.0 Overview A merger is unlikely to create or enhance market power or to facilitate its exercise unless it significantly increases concentration and

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Case AT/2014/1617: Voice call termination on individual mobile networks in Austria

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Case AT/2014/1617: Voice call termination on individual mobile networks in Austria EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 2.7.2014 C(2014) 4640 final Rundfunk und Telekom Regulierungs-GmbH (RTR) Mariahilferstraße 77-79 A-1060 Wien Austria For the attention of: Mr Johannes Gungl Fax: + 43 1 58

More information

CERRE CENTRE ON REGULATION IN EUROPE

CERRE CENTRE ON REGULATION IN EUROPE Market power and market definition in the network industries Summary of presentations and discussions, CERRE Regulation Forum 21 June 2011, Brussels Speakers: Prof. Pierre Larouche (CERRE & TILEC- Tilburg),

More information

7 Market power assessment

7 Market power assessment Section 7 7 Market power assessment Introduction 7.1 In the preceding sections we set out our proposed definitions of the relevant markets. In this section we present our Significant Market Power (SMP)

More information

Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC 1

Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC 1 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 26/03/2008 SG-Greffe (2008) D/201384 Rundfunk und Telekom Regulierungs- GmbH (RTR) Mariahilferstraße 77-79 A-1060 Wien Austria For the attention of: Mr. Georg Serentschy Mr.

More information

ERGEG Guidelines for Good Practice on Open Season Procedures (GGPOS) Ref: C06-GWG-29-05c 21 May 2007

ERGEG Guidelines for Good Practice on Open Season Procedures (GGPOS) Ref: C06-GWG-29-05c 21 May 2007 ERGEG Guidelines for Good Practice on Open Season Procedures (GGPOS) Ref: C06-GWG-29-05c 21 May 2007 European Regulators Group for Electricity and Gas Contact: Council of European Energy Regulators ASBL

More information

BT s response to Ofcom consultation document. Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts

BT s response to Ofcom consultation document. Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts BT s response to Ofcom consultation document Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts 14 March 2013 1 Executive Summary We welcome the opportunity to comment on this consultation on Price Rises in Fixed Term

More information

Wholesale voice call termination on individual mobile networks. Wholesale SMS termination on individual mobile networks

Wholesale voice call termination on individual mobile networks. Wholesale SMS termination on individual mobile networks Market Review Wholesale voice call termination on individual mobile networks Wholesale SMS termination on individual mobile networks Public Consultation 03/11 11th May 2011 Gibraltar Regulatory Authority

More information

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin Frontier Economics Bulletin Water Energy Retailing Transport Financial services Healthcare Telecoms Media Post Competition Policy Policy analysis and design Regulation Strategy Contract design and evaluation

More information

SUMMARY NOTIFICATION FORM: RETAIL INTERNET ACCESS MARKET AND RELEVANT

SUMMARY NOTIFICATION FORM: RETAIL INTERNET ACCESS MARKET AND RELEVANT SUMMARY NOTIFICATION FORM: RETAIL INTERNET ACCESS MARKET AND RELEVANT MARKETS 4 AND 5 1 MARKET DEFINITION 1.1 Affected relevant product/service markets 1 This draft decision, referred to hereafter as Decision

More information

Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General

Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General Speech given at the International Forum on EC Competition Law

More information

SESSION 4: STRATEGIC COSTING FOR BROADBAND SERVICES

SESSION 4: STRATEGIC COSTING FOR BROADBAND SERVICES SESSION 4: STRATEGIC COSTING FOR BROADBAND SERVICES ITU-D REGIONAL ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL FORUM OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS/ICTS FOR ASIA AND PACIFIC Yangon, The Republic of the Union of Myanmar, 1 September

More information

BoR (15) 143. BEREC Report Regulatory Accounting in Practice 2015

BoR (15) 143. BEREC Report Regulatory Accounting in Practice 2015 BoR () BEREC Report Regulatory Accounting in Practice October BoR () Contents. Executive summary.... Introduction.... Background.... Current report... 7. The data collection process... 7. Outline of the

More information

Review of fixed call origination and termination markets Call for inputs

Review of fixed call origination and termination markets Call for inputs Review of fixed call origination and termination markets 2016-19 Call for inputs Consultation Publication date: 2 April 2015 Closing Date for Responses: 14 May 2015 About this document Fixed call origination

More information

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2014/1642

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2014/1642 BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2014/1642 Call termination on individual public telephone networks provided

More information

BEREC Opinion. Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC:

BEREC Opinion. Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: BEREC Opinion Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case PL/2011/1260: Revision of dispute settlement decisions concerning voice call

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 14/12/2012 C(2012) 9778 Γραφείο Επιτρόπου Ρυθµίσεως Ηλεκτρονικών Επικοινωνιών Και Ταχυδροµείων (OCECPR) Helioupoleos 12 1101 Λευκωσία Cyprus For the attention of: Dr Polis

More information

Telecom Italia response to. BEREC Consultations. Roaming Regulation Choice of decoupling method

Telecom Italia response to. BEREC Consultations. Roaming Regulation Choice of decoupling method Telecom Italia response to BEREC Consultations on Roaming Regulation Choice of decoupling method 10 th August 2012 Page 1 (10) Executive Summary TI shares BEREC s view that it would be inappropriate to

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Dear Mr Michaelides,

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Dear Mr Michaelides, EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 16.12.2014 C(2014) 10121 final Γραφείο Επιτρόπου Ρυθμίσεως Ηλεκτρονικών Επικοινωνιών Και Ταχυδρομείων (OCECPR) Helioupoleos 12 1101 Λευκωσία Cyprus For the attention of: Mr.

More information

Contents. BoR (18) 34

Contents. BoR (18) 34 BEREC report on the outcome of the public consultation on the impact of premium content on ECS markets and the effect of devices on the open use of the Internet 8 March 2018 Contents 1. Introduction...

More information

Study prepared for Nkom. Principles for margin squeeze tests for fibre access in Market 4 and 5

Study prepared for Nkom. Principles for margin squeeze tests for fibre access in Market 4 and 5 Study prepared for Nkom Principles for margin squeeze tests for fibre access in Market 4 and 5 Bad Honnef, 9 February 2015 Principles for margin squeeze tests for fibre access in Market 4 and 5 I Contents

More information

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School Mergers in the energy sector IESE Business School Outline Trends. The quest for size Characteristics of electricity markets Horizontal merger analysis Vertical merger and foreclosure Remedies Market power

More information

Telecommunications Authority of Trinidad and Tobago

Telecommunications Authority of Trinidad and Tobago Telecommunications Authority of Trinidad and Tobago Determination of Market Definitions in the Retail Domestic Fixed Voice Sector of T&T April 14 th 2009 PREFACE This document is divided into five main

More information

Mark Naftel Norton Rose

Mark Naftel Norton Rose The International Telecommunication Union Regulatory Implications of Broadband Workshop Market Implications of Technologically Neutral Regulation Mark Naftel naftelm@nortonrose.com Dial up access Flat

More information

Trends in Telecommunications: Implications for Regulation

Trends in Telecommunications: Implications for Regulation Trends in Telecommunications: Implications for Regulation 20 September 2017 Mark DJ Williams, Managing Director, BRG mark.williams@thinkbrg.com +44 (0) 7825 862 132 Trends in Telecommunications Regulatory

More information

Next Generation Networks Consultation

Next Generation Networks Consultation 17 th August 2005 Next Generation Networks Consultation Summary ITSPA welcomes the opportunity to comment on Ofcom s further consultation on Next Generation Networks. Ofcom s approach to IP voice interconnect

More information

Public Consultation on the Review of the Significant Market Power (SMP) Guidelines

Public Consultation on the Review of the Significant Market Power (SMP) Guidelines Contribution ID: 48deea53-5371-4330-9994-3169fe71667b Date: 23/06/2017 17:57:54 Public Consultation on the Review of the Significant Market Power (SMP) Guidelines 1 Objective of the public consultation

More information

telecoms regulatory framework for

telecoms regulatory framework for Jornadas sobre a Regulação dos Mercados de Telecomunicações Towards a new telecoms regulatory framework for Europe Luis Enriquez Lisbon, November 5, 2002 McKinsey & Company, Inc KEY MESSAGES Liberalization

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Dear Mr Silicani, Commission decision concerning:

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Dear Mr Silicani, Commission decision concerning: EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 28.11.2014 C(2014) 9270 final Autorité de Régulation des Communications électroniques et des Postes (ARCEP) 7, square Max Hymans F-75730 Paris-Cedex 15 France For the attention

More information

experience Principal, International Ofcom April 2008

experience Principal, International Ofcom April 2008 Functional separation: the UK experience Tom Kiedrowski Tom Kiedrowski Principal, International Ofcom April 2008 Agenda Section 1 Background and context Section 2 Approach and rationale Section 3 Taking

More information

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER EN EN EN EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 22 January 2010 COMMISSION STAFF WORKING PAPER INTERPRETATIVE NOTE ON DIRECTIVE 2009/72/EC CONCERNING COMMON RULES FOR THE INTERNAL MARKET IN ELECTRICITY AND DIRECTIVE

More information

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002 Microeconomics Revision Essay (7) Perfect Competition and Monopoly (a) Explain why perfect competition might be expected to result in an allocation of resources which is both productively and allocatively

More information

ERG (09) 21. ERG Report on price consistency in upstream broadband markets

ERG (09) 21. ERG Report on price consistency in upstream broadband markets ERG Report on price consistency in upstream broadband markets June 2009 Contents Executive Summary... 2 1 Introduction... 4 2 Value chain in broadband services and corresponding price regulation across

More information

Case AT/2009/0970: Wholesale broadband access in Austria. Opening of Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7(4) of Directive 2002/21/EC 1

Case AT/2009/0970: Wholesale broadband access in Austria. Opening of Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7(4) of Directive 2002/21/EC 1 EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 5/10/2009 C(2009)7720 SG-Greffe (2009) D/6009 Rundfunk und Telekom Regulierungs-GmbH (RTR) Mariahilferstraße 77-79 A-1060 Wien Austria For the attention of: Mr Georg Serentschy

More information

Market studies. Guidance on the OFT approach

Market studies. Guidance on the OFT approach Market studies Guidance on the OFT approach Crown copyright 2010 This publication (excluding the OFT logo) may be reproduced free of charge in any format or medium provided that it is reproduced accurately

More information

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level Edexcel (B) Economics A-level Theme 4: Making Markets Work 4.1 Competition and Market Power 4.1.1 Spectrum of competition Notes Characteristics of monopoly, oligopoly, imperfect and perfect competition

More information

Executive Summary. Enhancing support to SMEs - Through better understanding of dual-use aspects of the EDTIB supply chain

Executive Summary. Enhancing support to SMEs - Through better understanding of dual-use aspects of the EDTIB supply chain Enhancing support to SMEs - Through better understanding of dual-use aspects of the EDTIB supply chain November 2014 Executive Summary It is well-recognised that small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs)

More information

Statement regarding a European single market for electronic communications

Statement regarding a European single market for electronic communications KKV1007, v1.3, 2012-09-10 STATEMENT 06/11/2013 593/2013 1 (7) The Ministry of Enterprise, Energy and Communications 103 33 Stockholm Statement regarding a European single market for electronic communications

More information

EU Telecoms Sector: Regulatory Developments, Threats and. Opportunities

EU Telecoms Sector: Regulatory Developments, Threats and. Opportunities EU Telecoms Sector: Regulatory Developments, Threats and Opportunities Institute of International and European Affairs Dublin, 11 November 2013 Intervention by Mr Luigi Gambardella Chairman of the Executive

More information

Keynote ECTA Conference

Keynote ECTA Conference Keynote ECTA Conference Brussels, November 28th, 2017 Good Afternoon ladies and gentlemen, Thank you very much for inviting me to this distinguished conference and for the opportunity to enter into a dialogue

More information

The BEREC Opinion on the draft. methodologies. Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Vice President BNetzA 8th EETT International Conference Athens, 16/17 May 2013

The BEREC Opinion on the draft. methodologies. Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Vice President BNetzA 8th EETT International Conference Athens, 16/17 May 2013 The BEREC Opinion on the draft Recommendation on consistent nondiscrimination obligations and costing methodologies Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Vice President BNetzA 8th EETT International Conference Athens,

More information

Definition - Markets and Dominance Control

Definition - Markets and Dominance Control 1 Definition - Markets and Dominance Control 2 Markets and dominance DEFINITION: MARKET: A medium that allows buyers and sellers of a specific good or service to interact in order to facilitate an exchange.

More information

Routing calls to ported telephone numbers Statement. ( Redacted for publication)

Routing calls to ported telephone numbers Statement. ( Redacted for publication) Routing calls to ported telephone numbers Statement ( Redacted for publication) Statement Publication date: 1 April 2010 Contents Section Annex Page 1 Summary 1 2 Introduction and background 4 3 Ofcom

More information

BEREC REPORT ON IMPACT OF FIXED-MOBILE SUBSTITUTION IN MARKET DEFINITION

BEREC REPORT ON IMPACT OF FIXED-MOBILE SUBSTITUTION IN MARKET DEFINITION Draft BEREC REPORT ON IMPACT OF FIXED-MOBILE SUBSTITUTION IN MARKET DEFINITION 8 December 2011 INDEX 1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 3 2. INTRODUCTION... 5 2.1. Structure of the report... 6 2.2. Scope of analysis...

More information

International Conference: Regulating the Electronic Communications Market, 26 September 27 September 2016, Budva, Montenegro

International Conference: Regulating the Electronic Communications Market, 26 September 27 September 2016, Budva, Montenegro International Conference: Regulating the Electronic Communications Market, 26 September 27 September 2016, Budva, Montenegro Communications Regulation Commission Redefined Recommendation 2014/710/EU Relevant

More information

Raising confidence in telephone numbers Including new UK-wide 03 numbers and a consultation to amend General Condition 17

Raising confidence in telephone numbers Including new UK-wide 03 numbers and a consultation to amend General Condition 17 Raising confidence in telephone numbers Including new UK-wide 03 numbers and a consultation to amend General Condition 17 Statement & consultation Publication date: 13 February 2007 Contents Section Annex

More information

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January 2011 Economics Assessment Unit A2 1 Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON MARK SCHEME 6364.01 General Marking Instructions This mark

More information

OPERATOR STRATEGIES FOR THE esim ERA: OPPORTUNITIES IN DEVICE BUNDLING, SALES CHANNELS AND WHOLESALE

OPERATOR STRATEGIES FOR THE esim ERA: OPPORTUNITIES IN DEVICE BUNDLING, SALES CHANNELS AND WHOLESALE RESEARCH STRATEGY REPORT OPERATOR STRATEGIES FOR THE esim ERA: OPPORTUNITIES IN DEVICE BUNDLING, SALES CHANNELS AND WHOLESALE KEREM ARSAL analysysmason.com About this report An esim is an embedded (although

More information

Memorandum of understanding between the Competition and Markets Authority and the Office of Communications concurrent competition powers

Memorandum of understanding between the Competition and Markets Authority and the Office of Communications concurrent competition powers 8 February 2016 Memorandum of understanding between the Competition and Markets Authority and the Office of Communications concurrent competition powers Contents Page Foreword... 2 Memorandum of Understanding

More information

Key principles of market regulation in telecommunications

Key principles of market regulation in telecommunications Key principles of market regulation in telecommunications Hans Bakker, director of Regulaid The Netherlands Why does the telecommunications market need special regulation? Electronic communications are

More information

Resetting competition policy frameworks for the digital ecosystem. Executive Summary October 2016

Resetting competition policy frameworks for the digital ecosystem. Executive Summary October 2016 Resetting competition policy frameworks for the digital ecosystem Executive Summary October 2016 The GSMA represents the interests of mobile operators worldwide, uniting nearly 800 operators with almost

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 26.11.2012 C(2012) 8828 Comisión del Mercado de las Telecomunicaciones (CMT) Carrer de la Marina 16-18 E-08005 Barcelona Spain For the attention of: Mr. Bernardo Lorenzo Presidente

More information

The Telco Organisational Structure beyond Tim Hills with Rupert Wood Edited by Catherine Viola

The Telco Organisational Structure beyond Tim Hills with Rupert Wood Edited by Catherine Viola The Telco Organisational Structure beyond 2010 Tim Hills with Rupert Wood Edited by Catherine Viola Analysys Research Fixed Networks and Services Analysys Research Fixed Networks and Services online market

More information

Mobile Call Termination Market Review Draft Statement

Mobile Call Termination Market Review Draft Statement Mobile Call Termination Market Review 2018-2021 Draft Statement Publication Date: 23 February 2018 About this document Mobile call termination is a wholesale service offered by a mobile provider to connect

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION CRITERIA FOR THE COMPATIBILITY ANALYSIS OF TRAINING STATE AID CASES SUBJECT TO INDIVIDUAL NOTIFICATION

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION CRITERIA FOR THE COMPATIBILITY ANALYSIS OF TRAINING STATE AID CASES SUBJECT TO INDIVIDUAL NOTIFICATION EN EN EN COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION CRITERIA FOR THE COMPATIBILITY ANALYSIS OF TRAINING STATE AID CASES SUBJECT TO INDIVIDUAL NOTIFICATION 1. INTRODUCTION 1. The Lisbon European Council in March

More information

COMISION DEL MERCADO DE LAS TELECOMUNICACIONES

COMISION DEL MERCADO DE LAS TELECOMUNICACIONES Notification of Draft Measures pursuant to 7(3) of the Directive 2002/21/EC for access and call origination on public mobile telephone networks. Under the obligation in article 16 of the Directive 2002/21/EC,

More information

Comments on ERG Bitstream Access Consultation document

Comments on ERG Bitstream Access Consultation document Comments on ERG Bitstream Access Consultation document This paper provides the European Competitive Telecommunications Association, ECTA, comment on the ERG consultation document. ECTA represents over

More information

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2013/1424

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2013/1424 BoR (13) 47 BEREC Opinion on Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2013/1424 Wholesale voice call termination on individual

More information

Mobile Call Termination Market Review Final Statement

Mobile Call Termination Market Review Final Statement Mobile Call Termination Market Review 2018-2021 Final Statement Publication Date: 28 March 2018 About this document Mobile call termination is a wholesale service offered by a mobile provider to connect

More information

Contents. Bitstream access: comments on the draft determination PUBLIC. Report for TelstraClear, 19 May Network Strategies Report Number 25013

Contents. Bitstream access: comments on the draft determination PUBLIC. Report for TelstraClear, 19 May Network Strategies Report Number 25013 Bitstream access: comments on the draft determination Report for TelstraClear, 19 May 2005 Network Strategies Report Number 25013 Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Differential business and residential pricing

More information

Commission questionnaire Open Internet and Net Neutrality UK Music observations

Commission questionnaire Open Internet and Net Neutrality UK Music observations Commission questionnaire Open Internet and Net Neutrality UK Music observations UK Music is the umbrella organisation which represents the collective interests of the UK s commercial music industry - from

More information

Non-horizontal mergers

Non-horizontal mergers Fordham Institute, New York July 9 13, 2007 Non-horizontal mergers Vincent Verouden European Commission, DG Competition, Chief Economist Team *The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily

More information

CEDA June The Changing Face of Australian Telecommunications and what that means for Australia.

CEDA June The Changing Face of Australian Telecommunications and what that means for Australia. CEDA June 9 2005 The Changing Face of Australian Telecommunications and what that means for Australia. Paul O Sullivan, Optus Chief Executive Introduction My first job at Optus, when I joined the company

More information

Australian Communications and Media Authority s Calling the Emergency Call Service Review of Arrangements Discussion Paper

Australian Communications and Media Authority s Calling the Emergency Call Service Review of Arrangements Discussion Paper Australian Communications and Media Authority s Calling the Emergency Call Service Review of Arrangements Discussion Paper Submission by Communications Alliance and the Australian Mobile Telecommunication

More information

If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an to

If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an  to 1/5 June 2016 Introduction The Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM) creates opportunities and options for businesses and consumers. By fighting against unfair competition and making it

More information

Market Power in Electricity Generation and Transmission

Market Power in Electricity Generation and Transmission Market Power in Electricity Generation and Transmission Prepared by Diana KORSAKAITE 2015 November 27, Budapest www. erranet.org Different market designs - examples Perfect competition Monopolistic competition

More information

Annex 1. Analysis of the markets for voice call termination on individual mobile communications networks

Annex 1. Analysis of the markets for voice call termination on individual mobile communications networks Annex 1 Analysis of the markets for voice call termination on individual mobile communications networks 4 April 2007 Contents Summary and conclusion... 3 1 Introduction and background... 6 1.1 Background...

More information

What makes unilateral conduct abusive? An economic perspective

What makes unilateral conduct abusive? An economic perspective What makes unilateral conduct abusive? An economic perspective 11 th Annual Conference of the GCLC, Brussels, 26 and 27 November 2015 Andrea Lofaro 23 November, 2015 Overview Effects based vs form based

More information

Client Briefing. A matter of definition

Client Briefing. A matter of definition Frontier Economics Client Briefing Water Energy Climate Change Transport Telecoms Media Competition policy Policy analysis and design Regulation Strategy Contract design and evaluation Dispute support

More information

Economic benefits from making the GHz band available for mobile broadband services in Pakistan. Report for the GSM Association

Economic benefits from making the GHz band available for mobile broadband services in Pakistan. Report for the GSM Association Economic benefits from making the 2.72.9GHz band available for mobile broadband services in Pakistan Report for the GSM Association Final report 29 July 2014 Benefits from making the 2.72.9GHz available

More information

4G radio spectrum auction: lessons learned

4G radio spectrum auction: lessons learned Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General Ofcom 4G radio spectrum auction: lessons learned HC 968 SESSION 2013-14 12 MARCH 2014 4 Key facts 4G radio spectrum auction: lessons learned Key facts 83m

More information