The Strategic Use of Consumer Search Cost *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Strategic Use of Consumer Search Cost *"

Transcription

1 The Strategic Use of Consumer Search Cost * Florian Zettelmeyer Haas School of Business University of California at Berkeley Berkeley, CA florian@haas.berkeley.edu ( ) (510) (Office) (510) (Fax) This version: October 1998 Keywords: Competitive Strategy, Search Costs, Internet Marketing, Game Theory. * This paper has benefited greatly from many discussions with Meghan Busse, Jeromin Zettelmeyer and especially Birger Wernerfelt. Very helpful suggestions from three anonymous reviewers, the area editor and the editor are gratefully acknowledged. I also thank Eric Anderson, John Hauser, Leslie Marx, and Nader Tavassoli for detailed comments. Further, I have benefited from comments and discussions by seminar participants at MIT, Columbia University, Carnegie-Mellon University, Harvard University, Washington University in St. Louis, University of Pennsylvania, Dartmouth College, UCLA, UC Berkeley, Stanford University, USC, New York University, and the University of Rochester.

2

3 The Strategic Use of Consumer Search Cost Abstract Through their communications mix, firms make decisions that have implications for the ease with which consumers can search for product information. A common intuition is that firms would like to make information easily available to consumers, but choose not to because facilitating consumer search is costly to them. The main result of this paper counters this intuition firms may not want to make consumer search easy, even if it is costless for them to do so. I identify two reasons why firms will choose to make search hard for consumers. First, firms can soften price competition by differentiating themselves on the basis of consumer search cost, even if consumers don t differ in their disutility of search. Second, firms have an incentive to take advantage of consumer optimism. It is shown that the reduced cost of providing information in new electronic channels such as the Internet does not necessarily imply that firms will aid consumers in their search for information. Some of the marketing implications of this result are: The Internet may not develop into a smorgasbord of vendor provided information; firms can use the existence of multiple channels to ease price competition; the fact that stores have low service might not be related only to cost pressure.

4

5 1 Introduction How a firm designs its communications mix will determine how easy or hard it is for consumers to search for product information. In a traditional retail environment, the ease with which consumers can acquire product information depends on the extent to which the product can be evaluated at a retailer (shrink-wrapped package vs. display model), or the amount of technical information provided on the shelf tag or packaging. In mail-order, the ease with which consumers can acquire product information may depend on the availability of an 800 number for product inquiry, the layout of the catalog, or the amount of information, including product comparisons, provided in the catalog. Over new electronic channels, firms can influence the ease of acquiring product information by the number of on-line services in which they offer information and the amount of information they allow consumers to retrieve while on-line (e.g. only technical data or also a picture). For the rest of this paper I use consumer search cost to mean the time and effort that consumers incur in acquiring product information that allows them to determine how much they like a product. It is a common intuition that firms want to make consumer search for their own product easy in order to provide value to the customer or to treat the customer as a partner. However, we frequently observe that firms don t make it as easy as possible for consumers to search. Many software companies, for example Microsoft, Acron, or Adobe, do not make demonstration versions of their software available for downloading from the Internet, thereby making it harder for consumers to evaluate how much they like the software before purchasing. Many drug companies, for example the manufacturers of Tylenol, make it very hard for consumers to determine their valuation for any particular drug. Consumers are offered multiple drugs with identical active ingredients with little or no information on the drug packages about the differences between them. A similar example, but of a retailer, is the OfficeMax catalog. A comparison of handheld tape recorders reveals that the three line descriptions provide very little quality information; different features are highlighted in each description and the reader is uncertain whether the absence of particular feature in a description implies that it is missing from the product. An obvious answer for why we observe that firms don t try to minimize consumer search cost is that it is costly for them to do so. This does not explain the above examples. Demo versions of software can be provided at a negligible marginal cost. A table listing features of handheld tape recorders by product does not take up more space in the catalogue than text descriptions and would be far more helpful for consumers

6 The main result of my paper is that the common intuition that firms want to make consumer search as easy as possible need not be true, even if firms costs of facilitating search are not a factor. I will show that there may be additional, strategic 1 incentives to keep consumer search costs high. These reasons are of particular interest in view of the emergence of electronic shopping. Electronic channels such as on-line services and especially the Internet make it very cheap for firms to allow interested consumers to find out more about their products. A typical quote from the business and trade press early in the development of electronic shopping stated: [On-line shopping] allows merchandisers to serve individual customers better by getting information on relevant products and services to them exactly when they need them. (American Demographics, September 1994) This paper sets out to answer two questions which are of both fundamental and applied interest. Even if it is costless for a firm to make consumer search cost very low, will it want to do so? How does competition affect a firm s decision to make search cheap for consumers? To this effect I model consumers that are considering the purchase of a product in a particular category. Consumers have already done some preliminary search or have been exposed to enough advertised information to know the product offerings, their associated prices, and some characteristics that are common to the offerings in the product category. From their basic knowledge of the product category they are aware of the distribution from which their valuations are drawn but do not have a precise idea of the benefits they might derive from each particular product. They can determine their valuation for a product by searching for information about this product and inspecting the product. For some products, increased knowledge about the product category generally increases consumers perceived differentiation between products. This is true of wines, for example. Where a wine novice might not know the difference between a $10 bottle of red wine with the Pinot Noir grape and the Cabernet Sauvignon grape, a wine expert, for any particular meal, will not consider them to be particularly good substitutes. For other products, increased knowledge about the product category generally 1 Strategic in the sense that a firm considers the reactions of other firms and of consumers when deciding what to do. As an example, consider a consumer that is interested in purchasing a personal computer and knows how much she values having a 00 Mhz Pentium. She is aware from magazine advertising that IBM and Compaq both sell personal computers. From the ads she has identified prices and basic features of 00 Mhz Pentiums, as well as where to look for more information. The features she could identify from the ads are very similar for both products, so the consumer can t establish which product she prefers. She knows that she can put some effort into finding out more about each computer by searching the manufacturer website for product information, or by visiting a store and inspecting the computer. - -

7 decreases consumers perceived differentiation between products. Pain killers fall in this category. A consumer that is not particularly well informed about the active ingredients in pain killers might not consider Advil and a generic brand of ibuprofen as particularly good substitutes. A knowledgeable consumer on the other hand, will consider the products perfect substitutes since both carry identical active ingredients. Personal computers also fall into this category of products. A consumer with limited product specific information will not consider an IBM PC to be of equal value to a Packard Bell, even if they have identical core specifications. A consumer that is very well informed will know that their differentiation is not based on objective product attributes and is hence more likely to consider them of equal value. The paper considers products that fall into this second category, i.e. products for which increased knowledge about the product category generally decreases consumers perceived differentiation between products. I model these product types by assuming that, while a percentage of fully informed consumers have a higher valuation for one or the other product in the category, a sufficiently large portion of fully informed consumers consider the goods of competing firms to be of equal value. In summary, I model products (a) for which consumers valuations are initially uncertain, (b) for which consumers can determine their valuations through (potentially costly) search, (c) for which consumers can determine prices more easily than their exact valuation for the product, and (d) that are close substitutes in so far as a portion of fully informed consumers considers the goods of competing firms to be of equal value. Among the category of goods that fit this description are many infrequently purchased search goods, search goods that undergo rapid technological change, or products that are characterized by generics. For such products I show that there are situations in which firms will not want to facilitate consumer search. I highlight two reasons for this: (1) firms can soften price competition by differentiating themselves on the basis of consumer search cost, and () firms can take advantage of consumer optimism. The first reason results from the analysis of a vertically integrated duopoly, in which I show that firms can avoid ruinous price competition by using search costs to differentiate themselves. 3 There exists an equilibrium in which one firm offers a high price but makes search easy while the other firm 3 Since the firms modeled in this paper are vertically integrated the results apply only to firms with direct distribution. To determine whether the results generalize to channels with intermediaries requires further research and will depend on the way in which intermediaries are added to the model

8 makes search costly to consumers but offers a lower price. If firms did not differentiate themselves in this way, for example, if neither made it easy for consumers to obtain information, consumers would have to choose which product to buy on the basis of price alone. Similarly, if both firms informed consumers, then the portion of the consumers who valued the products equally would also choose on the basis of price alone. By differentiating themselves, both firms can sustain higher profits by softening price competition. For example, if consumers are only informed by firm 1 but not by firm, then after evaluating firm1 s product, consumers will decide either to buy from firm 1 at a higher price but knowing what they will get or to buy from firm at a lower price but with only an estimate of the value of firm s product to them. If consumers differ in their realized valuation for firm 1 s product, then a change in prices by either firm 1 or firm will induce only a few consumers on the margin to switch from store one to the other. This insensitive reaction of consumers demand softens price competition because none of the stores can capture the whole market by slightly lowering prices. The second reason can be shown in the simple case of a monopoly (but also holds in a duopoly). I show that higher search costs can yield higher profits if consumers are sufficiently 4 confident that they will like a product, even before they have precise knowledge of the product s value to them. Cheap search would allow those consumers whose true valuation is slightly below their expected valuation to avoid buying a product that they would have bought, had they not searched, but nevertheless don t return because of the cost associated with returning the product. These two reasons suggest that the mere fact that electronic channels allow cheap communication with consumers does not imply that firms will use this ability to lower consumer search cost. The role of marketing communications includes both informing and persuading consumers. Much of a firm s communications mix is geared towards persuasion and a large stream of marketing research analyzes various aspects of persuasion. In this paper, however, I want to concentrate on the information aspect of the communications mix since it is of increased importance on new electronic communication channels such as the Internet. While some literature portrays consumers as passive recipients of communication, I will look at consumers as active searchers for information, although they incur costs in this process. Like Wernerfelt (1994a, 1996) I deal with efficiency in marketing communication but focus on identifying situations where firms strategically communicate inefficiently. 4 In relation to the firm s marginal cost of production. See section for an explanation

9 I add to the literature on search and search costs by considering firms strategic decisions about the level of search cost that consumers have to incur if they decide to search. Daughety and Reinganum (1991), and DeGraba (1995) also consider firm decisions that impact consumer search cost but focus on product availability. An alternative explanation that also leads to the result that firms purposefully limit the information they make available to consumers is the potential for information overload. Since information overload suggests that amount of information could increase or decrease consumer s ease of search I model firms as influencing consumers search cost directly. I begin with the simplest case (monopoly) in section, and then model a duopoly in section 3. While this progression aids logical explication, it means that the results will be derived in an order slightly different from the presentation above. Section 4 discusses the results and section 5 concludes the paper. Monopoly.1 Model Assume consumers are interested in purchasing one unit of a product in a particular product category. Consumers know the price p of the product offered by the monopolist. Consumers do not know ex ante the gross utility u they will derive from the product. 5 They are, however, aware of the distribution from which their reservation prices are drawn. Consumers willingness to pay is distributed uniformly between 0 and 1 ( u U[ 01, ] ). A consumer can find out her reservation price u by evaluating the firm s product. In doing so she incurs search cost s. Consumers facing a purchase decision can either buy, search or decide not to buy at all. If they have searched and learned their reservation prices they then have the option to buy or to pass, i.e. searching allows consumers to ensure that they purchase only when their willingness to pay exceeds price. After the purchase consumers can choose to return the product. In doing so they incur a return cost r that can consist of a restocking fee, the hassle associated with returns, or the shipping and handling fee as- 5 I will use reservation price or willingness to pay synonymously with u

10 sociated with many products that are ordered on the Internet or through mail order (Hess, Chu, Gerstner 1996). Figure 1: Consumer decisions Stage 1 Buy Search Pass Stage Buy Pass In stage consumers know their reservation prices and only purchases if the reservation price u exceeds the price p. Hence consumers never return a product after buying at stage, and their payoffs are: Table 1: Consumer utilities in stage Action buy pass Utility s + u p s Since reservation prices u are distributed uniformly between 0 and 1, the density function of u is f() u = 1. In stage 1, i.e. before search, the expected utility for each of a consumer s choices are: Table : Expected consumer utilities in stage 1 Action buy 1 ( p r) Expected utility ( p r) ( u p) du rdu for p > r udu p for p r search pass: 1 s + ( u p) du p 0 With these utilities I can describe consumers best response functions to any price - search cost pair ( ps, ). Notice that every consumer has the same expected utility. Hence, given ( ps, ), if any consumer prefers a given action, all consumers will prefer that action

11 The monopolist has two choice variables, price p problem is given by: and search cost s. The monopolist maximization max ps, ( p c)dp (, s) (1) where c is marginal cost and D( p, s) is the fraction of consumers who buy and do not return the product. Given consumer behavior, this fraction is as follows: Dp (, s) = 1 ( p r) if consumers buy 1 p if consumers search 0 if consumers pass (). Solution From table we can derive the conditions on p and s for which buy, search, or pass is consumers best response. Consumers search rather than pass iff s ( 1 p). Notice that consumers never return products for p r. For p > r consumers buy rather than search 6 iff s ( r ) ( p r), and buy rather than pass iff p 1 r + r. For p r consumers buy rather than search iff s p, and buy rather than pass iff p 1. By graphing these thresholds in the firm s strategy space ( ps, ) for high and for low return costs r we obtain the best response regions shown in figure : Figure : Firm strategy space and consumer best response High return costs ( r = 1 ) Low return costs ( r = 1 10) buy pass 0.15 buy pass search 0.05 search The regions of consumers best responses for ( ps, ) are separated by dashed lines. To illustrate figure, consider for example a price of 0. and search cost of All consumers will want to buy 6 Note that in stage 1 search as a consumer strategy means: search and buy if u p, otherwise pass. Likewise in stage 1 buy means, buy and return if u< p d

12 immediately without searching. Although the value of information that could be obtained by searching is lower than the search cost, the price is so low that consumers priors regarding their reservation prices significantly exceed the price the monopolist charges. Maintaining the same level of search cost but increasing price to 0.6 makes it worthwhile for consumers to search before buying since the probability that the willingness to pay is lower than the price has risen. A substantial increase in search cost from ( ps, ) = ( 0.6, 0.03) makes consumers drop out of the market entirely if return costs are very high since consumers expected reservation price of 1/ is lower than p. If return costs are low and search costs high, buying dominates searching because potentially incurring return costs is lower in expectation than incurring search costs for sure. If both, prices and search costs are very high, consumers drop out of the market altogether, unless return costs are negligible. I can now specify the equilibria of this game: Proposition 1: Let F be the cumulative distribution of consumers on [ 01, ]. Then the following characterizes the game s pure-strategy equilibria: Assume r < 1. Then for c < 1 r + r such that Fc () c () r, p * ( 1 + c+ r) = s, * ( 1 + c)r, and for c 1 r + r such that Fc () c () r, p * = 1 r + r s * r, 1 r + --, r all consumers buy in stage 1 and some consumers return the product. For c such that Fc () > c, p * ( 1 + c) = s, all consumers search in stage 1, * ( 1 c), where c () r = 1 ( r 14 / r 34 / ) Assume r 1. Then for c such that Fc () c ( 1 ) = 1, p * = 1, s * 1 8, all consumers buy in stage 1 and no consumers return the product. For c such that Fc () > c ( 1 ) = 1, p * ( 1 + c) = s, all consumers * ( 1 c), search in stage 1. Proof of proposition 1: see appendix Suppose the firm has low marginal cost c. Then there are many consumers whose reservation prices are larger than marginal cost, i.e. 1 F() c is large (or Fc () is small). This allows the firm to set price well - 8 -

13 above marginal cost and still price below consumers expected utility of purchasing and potentially having to return the product at a cost r. Setting high search costs to induce consumers to buy without searching results in purchases by some ( r ) consumers with reservation prices below p that do not return the product but would not have bought it they had known their reservation price before the purchase. With marginal cost below most consumers reservation prices, profits reaped from each customer can be large and it will not pay for the firm to charge a higher price but lose a portion r of demand by allowing consumers to search. The distinction of two cases for Fc () c reflects that for larger marginal costs c the firm cannot price at p * = ( 1 + c+ r) without exceeding consumers expected utility of purchasing and potentially having to return the product. That is why for marginal costs such that 1 r + r c c () r the firm prices at consumers expected utility of purchasing and potentially having to return the product. The higher the marginal costs c, the less profit that the firm can reap of each individual consumer. If fewer than Fc () = c consumers have reservation prices that are above marginal cost, the firm is better off selling to only those with reservation prices above the firm s price but at a higher price than previously possible. Hence the firm permits search. I can now state the main result of this section: Corollary 1: For any strictly positive return cost there exists a region of the parameter space for which a monopolist is strictly better off setting strictly positive search cost, even if the provision of information to consumers is costless to the monopolist. Corollary 1 makes use of the fact that in the profit function of the monopolist (equation 1) there are no costs associated with lowering consumer search cost s. 3 Competition 3.1 Model To illustrate the effects of competition I introduce a second firm. The two firms products are substitutes. There is one segment of consumers with reservation prices distributed uniformly between 0 and 1. Consumers willingness to pay for firm 1 s and firm s product are u 1 and u respectively. These are identically but not necessarily independently distributed. For simplicity I assume the following correlation structure between reservation prices u 1 and u : if a consumer searches at firm i and learns about her reservation price u i then with probability q her reservation price at firm j is identical to the res

14 ervation price she just learned, i.e. Pr( u j = u i ) = q. With probability 1 q the reservation price at firm j is different 7 in which case her best estimate about her reservation price at firm j is her prior. The consumers possible actions are illustrated in figure 3: Figure 3: Consumer decisions Stage 1 Stage Buy at 1 Search at 1 Pass Search at Buy at Stage 3 Buy at 1 Pass Search at Buy at Buy at 1 Search at 1 Pass Buy at Buy at 1 Pass Buy at Buy at 1 Pass Buy at A consumer has the option to buy from either firm without any search, to search either firm or to pass altogether. If she has decided to search at firm i she knows her reservation price at that firm as well as her reservation price u j at firm j with probability q. With this knowledge she can decide to buy at either firm, to pass or to search at firm j. If the consumer searches at firm j she has full information, i.e. she knows and and decides to buy from one of the firms or to pass. To simplify the u i u j analysis in the duopoly case I assume that consumers can t return products or that consumers return costs are sufficiently high to prevent returns. As we saw in the monopoly case, allowing for returns changes the degree to which firms need to facilitate search costs in order to induce consumers to search. The qualitative results, however, remain the same as long as return costs are strictly positive. u i 7 By continuity of the distribution of reservation prices different means the same as independent of the reservation price of firm i

15 To determine consumers optimal responses to both firms price - search cost offerings ( p 1, s 1 ) and ( p, s ) let us consider a consumer s expected utility at each stage. In stage 3 a consumer knows both reservation prices, hence her overall payoff for each action is given by: Table 3: Consumer utilities in stage 3 Action buy at firm 1: buy at firm : pass: Utility s 1 s + u 1 p 1 s 1 s + u p s 1 s In stage the consumer has only searched one firm, say firm 1. 8 Her expected utilities then are: Table 4: Expected consumer utilities in stage Action buy at firm 1: buy at firm : search at firm Expected utility s 1 + u 1 p 1 s 1 + qu 1 + ( 1 q) u du p s 1 s + q max{ 0, u 1 p 1, u 1 p } + ( 1 q) 1 0 ( u 1 p 1 + p ) 1 max { 0, u 1 p } du 1 + max{ 0, u p } du ( + ) 0 u 1 p 1 p pass: s 1 Since at stage the consumer has searched firm 1, she is certain about her payoff if she buys from firm 1. She also knows that Pr( u 1 = u ) = q and Pr( u 1 u ) = 1 q so that she forms her expected value from purchasing at firm as the weighted average from her known reservation price at firm 1 and her prior expected reservation price at firm. If the consumer decides to do a stage search for her reservation price at firm she has to pay s in addition to the search cost s 1 already incurred. 8 Throughout this paper and without loss of generality I will assume that if there is search at all, firm 1 will be the first firm to be searched

16 With probability q (when u 1 = u ) the benefit of her stage 3 decision is the maximum of passing, buying at firm 1, and buying at firm, where the payoffs of each decision are already known. With probability ( 1 q) (when u 1 u ) her expected utility is the expected value of each choice for those values of u for which the respective choice is optimal. In stage 1 the consumer only knows the distribution of her reservation prices but not their realizations. Her expected payoffs at this stage are: Table 5: Expected consumer utilities in stage 1 Action buy at firm i: search at firm i s i + E ui max 0 u i p i Expected utility 1 0 u i du i,, qu i + ( 1 q) u j du j p j, p i 1 0 s j + q max 0 u i p i ( ) u i p i + p j {,, u i p j } + ( 1 q) 1 max { 0, u i p } du i + max{ 0, u j j p j } du j 0 ( u i p i + p j ) pass: 0 If a consumer decides to buy without any search, her expected utility from the purchase is just her expected reservation price (i.e. utility will be 0. ) minus the purchase price. If she decides not to purchase at all her The interesting case occurs if the consumer decides to search at one of the firms. She then incurs search cost and gains the option in stage to choose between passing, buying at firm i under full knowledge of her reservation price, buying at firm j under partial knowledge of her reservation price u j s i 1, or continuing to search at firm j. The firms have two choice variables, price and search cost. I will look at two versions of the game. In one game I assume that firms set search cost and prices sequentially and know each other s search cost at the time they compete in prices. The game is called with commitment since I assume that in the (second step 9 ) price game firms remain committed to the level of search cost that they chose in the 9 In this paper stage refers to consumers decision tree and step to the overall game

17 first step. In the game without commitment I assume that firms set search cost and prices simultaneously (or if they set them sequentially are not able to commit to first step search cost). In the game with commitment, firms equilibrium choices must satisfy: nd step: p i = argmax( p i c)d i ( p i, s i, p j, s j ) i (3) p i 1st step: s i = argmax( p * i ( s i, s j ) c)d i ( p * i ( s i, s j ), p * j ( s i, s j ) ) i (4) s i In the game without commitment firms equilibrium choices must satisfy: p i = max( p i c)d i ( p i, s i, p j, s j ) p i s i = max( p i c)d i ( p i, s i, p j, s j ) s i i (5) As in the monopoly case c stands for marginal cost and D i ( ) is demand for firm i s product. For different prices and search costs there are many different forms that firms demands can take; I will therefore refrain from specifying fully contingent demands at this point but refer the reader to the appendix. 3. Solution In this section I first comment on a crucial aspect of consumer demand and then present the results of competition with and without commitment Characteristics of consumer demand From the expected utilities in table 3 on page 11 through table 5 on page 1 we can derive a best response of consumers at each stage of the game and hence derive consumer demand for each pair of price and search cost. A familiar result from the industrial organization literature is that if firms compete on the basis of price alone, demand will be discrete; i.e., all consumers will buy from the firm with the lowest price. This is undesirable for firms because it leads to a result of marginal cost pricing and zero profits (Bertrand equilibrium). In much of the literature, this result is avoided by distributing consumers along a Hotelling line and positioning firms away from each other geographically or in product space. This dif

18 ferentiation makes the goods no longer perfect substitutes if their locations are different, and demand becomes continuous in price. The model in this paper has a similar outcome, but it is a result of the information structure. If there were no search, demand would be discrete in the first stage of the game, in which consumers willingness to pay at both firms are unknown and the only information available is price. However, as consumers realize the outcomes of search, they formulate their utilities as conditional expected values which are continuous in price, which implies that demand is continuous in price. Suppose for a moment that consumers had to decide between purchasing at firms 1and in stage 1. Their expected utilities from purchases at firm 1 and firm are 1 p 1 and 1 p respectively. Irrespective of their true reservation price (because it is unknown to them at this stage) consumers will choose to purchase from the firm with the lower price, meaning that the firm with the lower price will get the entire demand. This is the classic Bertrand result. Now suppose that consumers have searched for firm 1 s product and are consequently at stage. Consumers now know their reservation price at firm 1 and know that their reservation price at firm corresponds to that at firm 1 with probability q. A consumer s utility from buying at firm 1 thus is u 1 p 1 and the expected utility from buying at firm is qu 1 + ( 1 q)1 p. This means that buying at firm 1 is preferred to buying at firm for u 1 p 1 > qu 1 + ( 1 q)1 p, or after solving for u 1, u 1 > 1 ( p 1 p ) ( 1 q). Since the proportion of realizations of u 1 that fall above 1 ( p 1 p ) ( 1 q) will change continuously with p 1 and p, demand is now a continuous function of prices. Suppose finally that consumers decide to continue searching. At stage 3 they know both reservation prices, u 1 and u. A portion q of consumers find that u 1 = u, the rest will find that u 1 u. Those consumers with identical reservation prices across firms will buy from the firm with the lower price. Consumers with different reservation prices will buy at firm 1 as long as u 1 p 1 u p u 1 u p + p 1. Overall, the firms demand will be continuous where p i > p j (because the demand for 1 q of the consumers is continuous in price), with a discrete jump at p 1 = p (because the q consumers with equal reservation prices switch firms at this price). 3.. Competition with commitment In the two-step game in which firms face the demands I sketched out above, firms first set search cost and then compete in prices. I solve for a subgame perfect equilibrium in the standard way: I first cal

19 culate the second step price equilibrium ( p * 1 ( s 1, s ), p * ( s 1, s )) calculate equilibrium search cost ( s * 1, s* ). Define the following prices: as a function of search cost and then p* 1 = ( 8+ 16c( 1 q) + q( 47 ( q)q 31) +[ 4+ 16c ( 1 q) 4 + 8c( 1 q) ( q( 11 + ( 5 + q)q) 1) + q( 8 + q( 5+ 4q( 4 + q( 5+ ( 4+ q)q) )))] 1 / ( 4( 1 q) ) p* = ( + 4c( 1 q) + q( 13 ( 5+ q)q) +[ 4+ 16c ( 1 q) 4 + 8c( 1 q) ( q( 11 + ( 5 + q)q) 1) + q( 8 + q( 5+ 4q( 4 + q( 5+ ( 4+ q)q) )))] 1 / ( 1( 1 q) ) (6) (7) I can now state the main result of this section: Proposition : There exist parameters perfect equilibrium. cq, for which the following characterize a subgame Firms: firm 1 charges a higher price than firm, p* 1 > p*, but sets lower search cost, s* ( 1 q) 1 = 0 < ( 1 p*. Both firms make positive profits. ) = s* Π 1, Π > 0 Consumers: Stage 1: all consumers search firm 1. 1 p* Stage : consumers with u 1 such that 1 u p* buy at firm 1, q 1 p* consumers with u 1 such that -- 1 p* 1 1 p* > u buy at firm, 1 q q 1 1 p* consumers with u 1 such that > u search at firm, q 1 0 no consumers pass. Hence there is positive demand for firm 1 and firm. No consumers pass at stage, but all who did not buy from firm 1 or firm continue searching at firm. Stage 3: consumers with u such that 1 u p* buy at firm, consumers with u such that p* > u 0 pass, no consumers buy at firm 1. Hence there is positive demand for firm and no demand for firm 1 at this stage. Proof of proposition : see appendix

20 The significance of this proposition is that firms can use search cost strategically in order to soften price competition; this result depends fundamentally on firms ability to commit to different levels of search cost before they compete in prices. In equilibrium one firm will make search easy but charge a higher price and the other firm will make search costly but offer a lower price. The intuition behind this proposition is as follows. In equilibrium, firm 1 makes search costless. As a consequence all consumers will choose to begin by searching firm Consumers with high will choose to buy at firm 1 and those with lower reservation prices will consider buying at firm. For consumers with the lowest reservation prices, it is better to pass altogether than to buy at either firm; however, the search cost that firm sets is chosen so that those consumers who prefer passing to buying at either firm are indifferent between passing and searching at firm. For these consumers the expected value of search is 0, and thus they are just willing to continue to search at firm instead of passing. This way all consumers who might have left the market in stage now search for their reservation prices at firm ; for some of them it will then be beneficial to purchase at firm. Since the expected value of searching at firm is weakly lower than that of buying at firm 1 for u 1 p 1, any consumer for whom u 1 p 1 will have purchased already at stage ; firm 1 sells to no additional consumers in stage 3. Why don t firms 1 and have an incentive to deviate? Fix firm 1 s search cost at s 1 = 0 and consider first firm. If firm sets higher search cost, those consumers that now buy from either firm at stage are unaffected. Only those consumers that so far continued searching (and of whom some then bought at firm ) will now cease searching and pass at stage. Clearly, firm cannot gain from such a deviation. Suppose now that firm lowers search cost. Initially consumers who bought in stage from firm 1 are unaffected (i.e. they prefer buying from firm 1 to searching at firm ). However, some of the consumers that so far bought at firm in stage are added to the searchers. Allowing these consumers to get informed about their reservation prices can only hurt firm because some will detect that they should not buy (although they would have bought if they had not been given the information). As firm lowers search cost further some consumers that so far bought at firm 1 will also begin to search. In stage 3 some of these consumers will buy from firm 1 but also some from firm. Although firm gets some consumers that had been buying at firm 1, this does not make up for the loss in demand from those consumers that formerly bought at firm and now search instead. u 1 10 Actually there is a whole interval of search cost s 1 that would sustain the equilibrium. I only require that s 1 is low enough that all consumers search firm 1 in stage

21 At very low search cost and under the assumption that firm charges the lower price, there is a large portion of consumers from both segments who have searched both firms and have found that they have the same reservation prices at both firms. These consumers will buy at whichever firm offers the lower price. This creates an incentive for firm 1 to undercut by ε and capture these consumers. no consumers will search and a change in s Analogous to the familiar result from the sales promotion literature, this case has no equilibrium in pure strategies (see for example Varian 1980 and Narasimhan 1988). It becomes clear from this discussion that the existence of a portion of fully informed consumers that considers the goods of competing firms to be of equal value is crucial to the results of this paper. 11 Now fix s = ( 1 q) ( 1 p ) and consider firm 1 s incentives to deviate. Demand is discrete in s 1 (in contrast to s ) since s 1 influences consumers first stage decision, which is a decision made before any individuals know their reservation prices. Thus in response to a given s1, either all or all consumers. Recall that in equilibrium all consumers search. If s 1 will either have no effect, or will change the behavior of is high enough to impede consumers search, but is still below firm s search cost, consumers don t know their reservation prices at either firm because firm s search cost also discourages first stage search. As discussed at the beginning of section 3..1 consumers will all choose to purchase from the firm with the lower price. This will result in Bertrand competition and zero profits. Firm 1 thus also has no incentive to deviate. If firm 1 impedes search, but consumers are willing to search at firm in stage 1, it is similar to firms 1 and swapping equilibrium roles. Since firm s profits in equilibrium are lower than firm 1 s profits, firm 1 has no incentive to reverse roles with firm. It is important to note that prices as well as search costs in this model do not convey any information about product quality. Consumers uncertainty about their willingness to pay for firms products comes from uncertainty about what product characteristics mean to them, not from uncertainty about the quality of the product. Since a consumer s willingness to pay in this model is uncorrelated with the willingness to pay of other consumers, a price or a level of search costs can t signal to a consumer whether she will have a high or low willingness to pay for a firm s product. p s1 11 If q = 0 the strategies proposed in proposition are not an equilibrium. Instead, both firms set very low search costs. This corresponds to modeling products for which more information does not decrease the perceived differentiation between products. As I mention in the introduction the results of this paper only apply to those product classes for which this assumption is satisfied

22 3..3 Competition without commitment In contrast to competition with commitment, now suppose firms simultaneously choose search cost and prices. This enhances firm j s ability to deviate from any price equilibrium derived under the assumption of a particular ( s i, s j ) : Proposition 3: The equilibrium proposed in proposition cannot be sustained if firms choose search cost and prices simultaneously or if they are not able to commit to first step search cost. Instead, for the parameters of proposition there will not exist an equilibrium in pure strategies. Proof of proposition 3: see appendix Recall that the price equilibrium in proposition with could be sustained because consumers partial information in stage led demand to be continuous in ( p 1, p ). Firm 1 was not interested in undercutting firm s price by ε because the potential gain in demand was minimal and firm s choice in price was optimal given that its search cost was. If however, firm were able to change the information structure of consumers and inform them of their reservation prices, there would suddenly be a large proportion of consumers that knew that their reservation prices at both firms were identical and who then would choose the firm with the lower price, namely firm. We would then be at a situation where s 1 = s = 0 p* 1 > p* s * and firms mix over prices. 4 Discussion I can summarize the main results of the paper as follows. First, firms in competition as long as they can commit to maintain search cost unchanged in response to a competitor s price can make use of search cost in order to differentiate themselves and thus ease price competition. This can lead to a situation where one firm offers a high price but makes search easy while the other firm prevents most consumers from searching but offers a lower price. Second, this result does not hold if firms cannot commit to maintain search costs constant while they compete in prices. In such a case, firms simply use consumer search cost as one more variable with which they can compete. Third, in certain situations a firm does not choose to facilitate consumer search, even if providing information to consumers is completely costless. The firm thereby induces consumers to buy based on expected value rather than to search

23 From these results it becomes clear that the principal use of consumer search cost as a strategic variable varies by market structure as summarized in table 6. Table 6: The role of search cost Market Structure Monopoly Competition with commitment Competition, without commitment Role of search cost Prevent low types from identifying themselves Ease price competition Compete on a second dimension In a monopoly consumer search cost enhances the monopoly power of the firm by fine tuning the information of each consumer segment. If consumer search costs are stickier than prices, i.e. if firms can change prices more frequently than they can change consumer search costs, they can make use of search costs to differentiate themselves so that price competition becomes less severe. If firms can change search costs as frequently as prices, we have simply introduced another variable with which they can compete in Bertrand competition. Note that we obtain positive profits in the equilibrium with commitment without resorting to a Hotelling-type structure to avoid Bertrand competition through product or geographic differentiation (see for example Hotelling 199, D Aspremont et al. 1979, Moorthy 1988). Other than the fact that for some consumers reservation prices are independently distributed, in my model both firms distinguish themselves only by their strategic variables. We can find a similar structure in Kreps and Scheinkman (1983), which shows that a Cournot outcome results from price competition if firms have quantity constraints. In their model, firms commit to a maximum level of production quantity and thereby prevent one firm from serving the entire market. This leads to prices above marginal cost and positive profits. The search model in this paper differs from traditional search models in which consumers search for price (see for example Diamond 1971 and Rothschild 1974) by more than the strategic nature of firms decisions on search cost. In most traditional search models consumers basic problem consists of trading off the search cost associated with visiting an additional firm against a potentially better price they might find at that firm. The models assume that consumers have no uncertainty about their valuation for products but face price uncertainty. My model, in contrast, assumes that consumers have knowledge about prices but are uncertain about their valuations for products. While these might seem dual problems at first sight, there is a fundamental difference. I assume that consumers have the option

24 of purchasing a product for which they have uncertain valuation. In traditional search models consumers cannot purchase a product whose price they don t know. This distinction reflects that consumers frequently make purchase decisions with product uncertainty, but almost never without price information at the time of a purchase transaction. Since most of my results rely on consumers trade-off between purchasing a product with uncertain value versus searching, my formulation of consumer uncertainty as uncertainty of valuation for a product and not the product s price is crucial. The results of this paper bear resemblance to those from models of vertical differentiation. In these models firms mitigate price competition by differentiating on a product or service dimension along which consumers willingness to pay differs. For example, in traditional models of dual distribution, firms differentiate by creating high and low service stores. Since consumers with a higher willingness to pay typically have a higher valuation for service they self-select into stores with high service and higher prices. Consumers with low willingness to pay choose stores with low service and lower prices. Based on an analogous argument, Gerstner, Hess, and Chu (1993) present a result that shows that sellers may profit from differentiation by introducing product features that are meaningless and even detrimental to consumer welfare, and Chu, Gerstner, and Hess (1995) demonstrate that firms can soften price competition by differentiating selling styles. In all of these models the existing heterogeneity of consumers is exploited to soften price competition. This paper, in contrast, shows how firms can use search costs to manipulate consumers valuations in order to create consumer heterogeneity from consumers with ex-ante homogeneous valuations. Different search costs do not segment consumers because their disutility of search differs, but because asymmetric information regarding their valuation for the products of competing firms leads to maximally heterogeneous consumer valuations and hence to less price competition between firms. A model of vertical differentiation along search costs predicts that consumers that search at low search cost firms have a disutility of search that is systematically higher than consumers that search at high search cost firms. My model predicts that firms have an incentive to differentiate, even if consumers disutility of search does not vary across consumers that search at one or the other firm. Limitations A number of assumptions in this paper clearly ignore factors that can affect a firm s decision to provide information in the real world. First, firms are commonly differentiated along some dimension such as product quality, service, or location, second, consumers often have the wrong expectations about the - 0 -

25 utility they will derive from a firm s product, and third, it can be very costly for firms to make it easy for consumers to determine their reservation prices. If firms are differentiated along product quality, service, or location, there are cases in which firms no longer have an incentive to differentiate themselves through search costs. However, the results of this paper will continue to hold as long as, at some particular set of prices, a discrete portion of consumers that have either no or full information are indifferent between competing firms products and those prices are near the firms equilibrium prices. If consumers have the wrong expectations regarding their reservation prices, firms have incentives to withhold or reveal information. A firm for whom consumers have average posteriors that surpass their priors will have an incentive to facilitate consumer search, a firm with lower average posterior reservation prices than priors will have an incentive to withhold information from consumers. Firms ultimate choice depends on the relative magnitude of incentives stemming from incorrect priors and the competitive effect that comes from having informed or uninformed consumers. By assuming that priors are consistent with posteriors this paper has shown that firms might have incentives to withhold information from consumers, even if they have nothing to hide. Finally, if reducing search cost is costly to a firm, this will reduce its incentives to facilitate consumer search. The model in this paper assumes that the reduction of consumer search cost is costless to the firm. The purpose of this assumption is to isolate reasons other than costs for why firms might not want to facilitate consumer search. The assumption is biased against my results, i.e. if my results hold under the assumption of no cost to the firm, they will also hold if it is costly for firms to lower consumer search cost. This paper show that there exist regions of the parameter space for which firms have incentives to withhold information. The results do not, however, indicate how relevant these regions are in practice. The importance of these regions are an empirical question. It is a standard argument that a firm s ability to capitalize on selling to consumers that don t find it worthwhile to return products (as happens to some consumers in my models) is limited by repeat purchasing or competitive pressure (see Wernerfelt, 1994b). However, there are circumstances under which firms can sustain strategies in which they sell to consumers that would not have bought if they had searched. For example, turnover of consumers in the market will lead to some consumers that are uninformed. Long purchase intervals and consequently forgetful consumers might also lead to uninformed consumers. Consumers might have gone through changes in taste or new models of a product - 1 -

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Competitor Based Price Clauses Competitor Based Price Clauses: any price guarantee

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Problem 1. Shorter problems. (35 points) Solve the following shorter problems. 1. Consider the following (simultaneous) game of chicken. This is a game in

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information

EconS Bertrand Competition

EconS Bertrand Competition EconS 425 - Bertrand Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction Today, we

More information

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review 14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14 Lecture 2 - Review Prof. Sara Ellison MIT OpenCourseWare 4 basic things I want to get across in this review: Monopoly pricing function of demand, elasticity, & marginal

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

Economics of Information and Communication Technology

Economics of Information and Communication Technology Economics of Information and Communication Technology Alessio Moro, University of Cagliari October 5, 2017 What are digital markets? ICT technologies allow firms to sell their products online. The internet

More information

Sponsored Search Markets

Sponsored Search Markets COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Sponsored Search Markets Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Sponsored Search Markets

More information

Second-Degree Price Discrimination for Information Goods Under Nonlinear Utility Functions

Second-Degree Price Discrimination for Information Goods Under Nonlinear Utility Functions Second-Degree Price Discrimination for Information Goods Under Nonlinear Utility Functions Hemant K. Bhargava The Smeal College of Business Pennsylvania State University 342 Beam Building University Park,

More information

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

9 The optimum of Oligopoly Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, December 1, 2008 9 The optimum of Oligopoly During previous lectures we have investigated two important forms of market structure: pure competition, where there are typically

More information

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement Hideo Konishi Michael T. Sandfort June 21, 2001 Abstract Retail stores frequently advertise prices. When consumer search is costly, advertising low prices expands

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power May 19, 2012 Eric B. Rasmusen Dan R. and Catherine M. Dalton Professor, Department of Business Economics and Public Policy, Kelley

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Hitotsubashi University August 2009 Abstract We capture the differences between patent and copyright by considering the optimal

More information

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets S O L U T I O N S 26 Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets Solutions for Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach with Calculus (International Ed.) Apart from end-of-chapter exercises provided

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* Abstract Many software and video game firms offer a free demo with limited content to help buyers better assess the likely value

More information

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory Econ 500 - Microeconomic Analysis and Policy Monopoly Monopoly A monopoly is a single firm that serves an entire market and faces the market demand curve for its output. Unlike

More information

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge

More information

Competitive Franchising

Competitive Franchising Brett Graham and Dan Bernhardt University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign 2008 North American Summer Meeting of the Econometric Society Motivation What happens when firms compete using both prices and franchise

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* University of Florida Department of Economics, P.O.Box 117140 Gainesville, FL 32611-7140 Email: lifan51@ufl.edu Tel:1-352-846-5475

More information

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming

Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Market mechanisms and stochastic programming Kjetil K. Haugen and Stein W. Wallace Molde University College, Servicebox 8, N-6405 Molde, Norway E-mail: Kjetil.Haugen/Stein.W.Wallace@himolde.no 18.12.01

More information

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016 Game Theory & Firms Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016 What is Game Theory? Game Theory Intuitive Definition: Theory of strategic interaction Technical Definition: Account

More information

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition Competitors and Competition This chapter focuses on how market structure affects competition. It begins with a discussion of how to identify competitors, define markets, and describe the market structure.

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly and oligopoly (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Advanced pricing with market power and equilibrium oligopolistic

More information

Price ceilings and quality competition. Abstract

Price ceilings and quality competition. Abstract Price ceilings and quality competition Alexander Kemnitz University of Mannheim Cyrus Hemmasi University of Mannheim Abstract This paper investigates the quality implications of an upper limit on product

More information

The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with. Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1

The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with. Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1 The Retail Space-Exchange Problem with Pricing and Space Allocation Decisions 1 Mingming Leng, 3, Mahmut Parlar 4, Dengfeng Zhang 5 A 010 Revised A and N 011 Accepted N 011 To appear in Production and

More information

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of 137 Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of BMW 1,3,5,7. Hyperlink Harald Schmidt Show: rtsp://streamer2.streaming.szm.de/sat1/schmidt/media//03/03/20/procter_56.rm

More information

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden http://io.tholden.org/ Game theory refresher 2 Sequential games Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibria More static oligopoly: Entry Welfare Cournot versus Bertrand

More information

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs

Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Controlling Information to Influence Consumer Beliefs Quyen Nguyen University of Arizona November 14, 2015 Abstract Access to product information changes a consumer s initial belief about the product s

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 Pricing with market power and oligopolistic markets (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Module 4 Sep. 28, 2013

More information

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty

Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Dynamic Pricing in Experience Good Markets with Demand Uncertainty Yu-Hung Chen and Baojun Jiang January 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model to examine how a firm with a new, non-durable

More information

Newspapers. Joel Sobel. Mullainathan- Shleifer. Newspapers. Gentzkow- Shapiro. Ellman and Germano. Posner. Joel Sobel. UCSD and UAB.

Newspapers. Joel Sobel. Mullainathan- Shleifer. Newspapers. Gentzkow- Shapiro. Ellman and Germano. Posner. Joel Sobel. UCSD and UAB. UCSD and UAB 15 February 2007 ISSUES What do papers sell? Origin and Persistence of Bias? Does Competition Improve Outcomes? Relevance: Production and Consumption of Information in Group Environments.

More information

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Pricing Under Homogeneous Oligopoly We will assume that the

More information

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition Course Evaluations on Thursday: Be sure to bring laptop, smartphone, or tablet with browser, so that you can complete your evaluation in class. Oligopoly

More information

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Department of Applied Economics Faculty of Economics University of

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia March 30, 2014 Abstract We analyze how the market power of firms in consumer search markets depends on how consumers form beliefs

More information

1 Double Marginalization & Two Part Tariff

1 Double Marginalization & Two Part Tariff ECON 312: Vertical Relations 1 Industrial Organization Vertical Relations Vertical Relations refers to the relationship between two firms in the sequence along the value chain, where there is an upstream

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 19, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 31 November 19, 2015 1 / 32 Introduction We are now

More information

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects Peter M. Kort, Pauli Murto, and Grzegorz Pawlina April 25, 2005 Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not quote. Abstract This paper is about

More information

Solutions to Final Exam

Solutions to Final Exam Solutions to Final Exam AEC 504 - Summer 2007 Fundamentals of Economics c 2007 Alexander Barinov 1 Veni, vidi, vici (30 points) Two firms with constant marginal costs serve two markets for two different

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct. UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures 13-14 Oct. 1, 2011 Pricing While there is some involved analysis required,

More information

Pricing with Market Power

Pricing with Market Power Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power 7.1 Motives and objectives Broadly The model of perfect competition is extreme (and hence wonderfully powerful and simple) because of its assumption that each firm believes

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition

Volume 29, Issue 4. Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Volume 29, Issue 4 Customization: Ideal Varieties, Product Uniqueness and Price Competition Oksana Loginova University of Missouri-Columbia X. Henry Wang University of Missouri-Columbia Abstract We study

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Final Exam Solutions

Final Exam Solutions 14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14 Final Exam Solutions Prof. Sara Ellison MIT OpenCourseWare 1. a) Some examples include making prices hard to find, offering several versions of a product differentiated

More information

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research Alex John London Carnegie Mellon University Kevin J.S. Zollman Carnegie Mellon

More information

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Julian Wright Abstract In a recent paper, Chiara Fumagalli and Massimo Motta (2006) challenge the idea that an incumbent can foreclose efficient

More information

Part III. Sources of market power. Chapter 6. Advertising and related marketing strategies

Part III. Sources of market power. Chapter 6. Advertising and related marketing strategies Part III. Sources of market power Chapter 6. Advertising and related marketing strategies Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz, 2d Edition Cambridge

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET Chapter 6 We recall that perfect competition was theorised as a market structure where both consumers and firms were price takers. The behaviour of the firm in such circumstances was described in the Chapter

More information

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers Economics of Industrial Organization Lecture 12: Mergers Mergers Thus far we have talked about industry dynamics in terms of firms entering and exiting the industry, and have assumed that all these firms

More information

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach Economics II - October 7, 009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach GAME THEORY Economic agents can interact strategically in a variety of ways, and many of these have been

More information

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion Notes and Comments on Search Costs and Equilibrium Price Dispersion Moshe Barach Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion By Michael R. Baye, John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten Various models of

More information

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling.

Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Competition, Disclosure and Signaling. Maarten C.W. Janssen University of Vienna, Austria. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. December 6, 2012 Abstract Competition creates strategic

More information

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Economics Working Paper Series 2016/012 Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Kwok Tong Soo The Department of Economics Lancaster University Management School Lancaster LA1 4YX UK Authors All

More information

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2 EconS 425 - Vertical Pricing Restraints 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

EconS Vertical Di erentiation

EconS Vertical Di erentiation EconS 425 - Vertical Di erentiation Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41 Introduction For our

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information

Industrial Organization. Networks

Industrial Organization. Networks In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Industrial Organization 44772 (1392-93 1 st term) Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Networks Network externalities What

More information

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

ECON 115. Industrial Organization ECON 115 Industrial Organization 1. Review of the First Midterm 2. Review of Price Discrimination, Product Differentiation & Bundling 3. Introduction to Oligopolies 4. Introduction to Game Theory and Cournot

More information

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Econ 11b: Intermediate Microeconomics Dirk Bergemann, Spring 01 Week of 3/6-4/3 1 Lecture 16: Imperfectly Competitive Market 1.1 Price Discrimination In the previous section we saw that the monopolist

More information

An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1

An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1 An economic analysis of internet privacy regulation 1 Abraham L. Wickelgren University of Texas at Austin August 2015 1 I thank the George Mason Law and Economics Center for financial support and helpful

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market Manas Paul Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research Gen. Vaidya Marg Goregaon (East) Bombay 400 065. Sougata Poddar Department of Economics

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman Working Paper 11407 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11407 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia February 15, 2014 Abstract We analyze two unexplored aspects of the Wolinsky model (Wolinsky (1986)

More information

Search markets: Introduction

Search markets: Introduction Search markets: Introduction Caltech Ec106 (Caltech) Search Feb 2010 1 / 16 Why are prices for the same item so different across stores? (see evidence) A puzzle considering basic economic theory: review

More information

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY No, not the BCS Oligopoly: A market with few firms but more than one. Duopoly: A market with two firms. Cartel: Several

More information

DAILY DEAL WEBSITES IN MARKETS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION

DAILY DEAL WEBSITES IN MARKETS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION DAILY DEAL WEBSITES IN MARKETS WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Mark Bender Esther Gal Or Tansev Geylani mtb34@pitt.edu esther@katz.pitt.edu tgeylani@katz.pitt.edu University of Pittsburgh University of Pittsburgh

More information

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics Real-World Markets Readings for this lecture Required reading this time: Real-World

More information

Industrial Organization- micro : Price discrimination in oligopoly

Industrial Organization- micro : Price discrimination in oligopoly Industrial Organization- micro 3 2018: Price discrimination in oligopoly Price discrimination is a mechanism whereby a monopolist can effectively shift surplus from the consumer sector. With perfect price

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas. October 13, 2011 Abstract In a durable good market where sellers have private

More information

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22 Monopoly. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen November, Lecture Monopoly Outline. Chap : Monopoly. Chap : Shift in Demand and Effect of Tax Monopoly The monopolist is the single supply-side

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Abstract

Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Abstract Is a Minimum Quality Standard Socially Optimal? Stephan Marette UMR Economie Publique INRA Abstract This paper explores the role of a minimum quality standard when the quality choice is discrete. A minimum

More information

Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing

Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing Mark Armstrong and Julian Wright July, 004 Abstract We analyze some models of price competition in two-sided markets, allowing for the possibility

More information

Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building. Behavior. Somdutta Basu. October Abstract

Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building. Behavior. Somdutta Basu. October Abstract Competition: Boon or Bane for Reputation Building Behavior Somdutta Basu October 2014 Abstract This paper investigates whether competition aids or hinders reputation building behavior in experience goods

More information

Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure

Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 1 Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure It used to be thought that markets for information

More information

This paper investigates the pricing and restocking fee decisions of two competing firms selling horizontally

This paper investigates the pricing and restocking fee decisions of two competing firms selling horizontally MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 57, No. 2, February 2011, pp. 347 362 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 11 5702 0347 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1100.1274 2011 INFORMS Managing Consumer Returns in a Competitive Environment

More information

Strategic segmentation: when two monopolies are better than one

Strategic segmentation: when two monopolies are better than one Strategic segmentation: when two monopolies are better than one Barna Bakó András Kálecz-Simon July 28, 2014 Abstract In this article we show that the price and the profit of an incumbent firm may increase

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Market Structure ECON6021 Oligopoly Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Oligopoly a few major players The top 4 cereal manufacturers sell 90% of all

More information

Competing Payment Schemes

Competing Payment Schemes Competing Payment Schemes Graeme Guthrie and Julian Wright Victoria University of Wellington and National University of Singapore September 9, 2003 Abstract This paper presents a model of competing payment

More information

Credence goods. Even when the success of the service is observable to the consumer ex post, consumers typically

Credence goods. Even when the success of the service is observable to the consumer ex post, consumers typically Credence goods Credence goods: products and services purchased from informed experts such as auto mechanics, home improvement contractors, appliance service-persons, physicians, lawyers... The provider

More information

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009

Outline. Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization. Assumptions of Model. Example. Coase model of a durable monopoly good 10/16/2009 Outline Alternative Pricing Schemes Industrial Organization Session 2 K. Graddy The Coase Conjecture and Price Skimming Sales Non linear pricing Two part tariffs and the Disneyland monopolist Geographical

More information

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 30, 2005 Answer four of the six

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO 20015 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II Candidates should attempt TWO questions. marks. Each question carries equal When presenting numerical results, please give a complete

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO.

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. 2008-14 ASYMMETRIC MARKET SHARES, ADVERTISING, AND PRICING: EQUILIBRIUM

More information

Is Advance Selling Desirable with Competition?

Is Advance Selling Desirable with Competition? Is Advance Selling Desirable with Competition? Gérard P. Cachon and Pnina Feldman Abstract It has been shown that a monopolist can use advance selling to increase profits. This paper documents that this

More information

Product Fit Uncertainty and Information Provision in a Distribution Channel

Product Fit Uncertainty and Information Provision in a Distribution Channel Product Fit Uncertainty and Information Provision in a Distribution Channel Monic Sun Boston University Rajeev Tyagi University of California, Irvine April 5, 017 Abstract Most consumers considering buying

More information

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Eco 300 Intermediate Micro Instructor: Amalia Jerison Office Hours: T 12:00-1:00, Th 12:00-1:00, and by appointment BA 127A, aj4575@albany.edu A. Jerison (BA 127A) Eco 300 Spring 2010 1 / 61 Monopoly Market

More information