Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change"

Transcription

1 Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) locate/ econbase Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change William A. Pizer* Resources for the Future, 1616 P Street NW, Washington, DC 20036, USA Received 14 July 1999; received in revised form 18 December 2000; accepted 21 March 2001 Abstract Uncertainty about compliance costs causes otherwise equivalent price and quantity controls to behave differently and leads to divergent welfare consequences. Although most of the debate on global climate change policy has focused on quantity controls due to their political appeal, this paper argues that price controls are more efficient. Simulations based on a stochastic computable general equilibrium model indicate that the expected welfare gain from the optimal price policy is five times higher than the expected gain from the optimal quantity policy. An alternative hybrid policy combines both the political appeal of quantity controls with the efficiency of prices, using an initial distribution of tradeable permits to set a quantitative target, but allowing additional permits to be purchased at a fixed trigger price. Even sub-optimal hybrid policies offer dramatic efficiency improvements over otherwise standard quantity controls. For example, a $50 trigger price per ton of carbon converts the $3 trillion expected loss associated with a simple 1990 emission target to a $150 billion gain. These results suggest that a hybrid policy is an attractive alternative to either a pure price or quantity system Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Climate change; Decision-making under uncertainty; Price and quantity controls; General equilibrium modeling JEL classification: Q28; D81; C68 *Tel.: ; fax: address: pizer@rff.org (W.A. Pizer) / 02/ $ see front matter 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S (01)

2 410 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Introduction Seminal work by Weitzman (1974) drew attention to the fact that, in regulated markets, uncertainty about costs leads to a potentially important efficiency distinction between otherwise equivalent price and quantity controls. Despite this well-known observation and its relevance for climate change policy, most of the debate concerning the use of taxes and emission permits to control greenhouse 1 gases (GHGs) has centered on political, legal and revenue concerns. This paper responds to this important omission by examining the efficiency properties of 2 permit and tax policies to mitigate global climate change. The basic distinction among policy instruments arises because taxes fix the marginal cost of abatement at a specified tax level (assuming optimal firm behavior). With uncertainty about costs, this generates a range of possible abatement levels and emission outcomes. In contrast, a permit system precisely limits emissions but leads to a range of potential cost outcomes. When coupled with a model of the benefits associated with emission reduction, this divergence in emission and cost outcomes creates a distinction in the expected welfare associated with each policy. In the case of climate change, part of the cost uncertainty arises due to uncertainty about the level of future baseline emissions. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (1992; hereafter IPCC) gives a range of CO2 emission 3 levels in 2010 of between 9.2 and 13.1 gigatons carbon (GtC). This requires a uniform 1 15% adjustment to IPCC forecasts of carbon emissions. See p. 71 in Nordhaus (1994b). The cost of attaining a particular target, say the 1990 emission level of 8.5 GtC, will obviously fluctuate depending on the level of future uncontrolled emissions. In addition to the baseline, however, there is considerable uncertainty about the cost of reducing emissions below the baseline. A study by Nordhaus (1993) reports that a $30/ton carbon (tc) tax might reduce emissions anywhere from 10 to 40%. While some models predict that a $300/ tc would virtually eliminate 4 emissions, other models require a tax in excess of $400/tC. This wide range of 1 See Wiener (1998), McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1997) and Goulder et al. (1997). 2 Earlier work by the author (Pizer, 1999) focused on the effect of uncertainty on the level of control, measured by a control rate or emission tax. That paper compared price and control rate policies, but did not consider fixed emission limits. Recent work by Newell and Pizer (1998) and Hoel and Karp (1998) considers the theory of price and quantity regulation applied to pollution such as greenhouse gas emissions that accumulate in the environment. 3 The actual range is GtC. However, we include the carbon equivalent of CFC emissions in our discussions of controllable greenhouse gas/ carbon emissions in order to parallel the treatment in Nordhaus (1994b) and Pizer (1999). 4 A recent report by the Energy Information Administration (1998) indicates similar marginal costs ranging from $50 to $400/ tc to achieve comparable reductions in emissions based on different models. Weyand and Hill (1999) suggest even higher costs.

3 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) reduction estimates only compounds the uncertainty about baselines to generate extreme uncertainty about the cost of a particular emission target years in the future. Motivated by the policy implications of these large uncertainties, this paper uses a modified version of the Nordhaus (1994b) DICE model in order to analyze alternative policies under uncertainty. In particular, the model incorporates uncertainty about a wide range of model parameters developed in both Nordhaus (1994b) and Pizer (1996). The simulations are then sped up using a technique presented in Pizer (1999) that greatly facilitates computation. Details concerning costs and benefits are discussed in the next section while additional detail can be found in Pizer (1999) and Nordhaus (1994b). Two sets of simulations are emphasized. The first set focuses on the choice of policy in the year 2010 only. By examining estimated marginal cost and benefit schedules in this single period, we can directly apply Weitzman s original intuition. Such an analysis reveals the consequences of very short-term policy decisions, showing that the optimal price policy (a tax of $7.50/ tc) yields expected social benefits of $2.5 billion in net present value versus the optimal quantity policy (a 13 GtC permit scheme) yielding only $0.3 billion. The single-period experiments are followed by simulations of the optimal price and quantity policies over a 100-year horizon. These longer-term policy simulations indicate that an optimal permit path would similarly begin with a 13 GtC target in 2010, but rise gradually over time to about 45 GtC by 2100 in order to accomodate economic growth. This policy generates $69 billion in expected net benefits versus a no policy, business-as-usual alternative. Meanwhile, the optimal tax policy starts at $7/tC in 2010 and rises to about $55/tC by In contrast, this policy generates $337 billion in expected net benefits five times the gain of the optimal permit policy. Since these results are driven by untestable assumptions about the consequences of climate change, an obvious question is whether they are sensitive to increasingly non-linear climate effects. Indeed, the presence of a significant threshold can reverse the preference for taxes. Specifically, when damages rise from 1% to 9% as the mean global temperature rises from 3 to 4 degrees above historic levels, this is sufficient to encourage the use of quantity-based regulations over a 50-year policy horizon. Finally, a combined hybrid policy is proposed as an alternative to both the pure tax and permit approaches Roberts and Spence (1976); Weitzman (1978); and McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1997). Such a mechanism would involve an initial distribution of tradeable permits, with additional permits available from the government at a specified trigger price. This system turns out to be only slightly more efficient than a pure tax system. However, it achieves this efficiency while preserving the political appeal of permits: the ability to flexibly distribute the rents associated with emission rights. More importantly for current policy discussions, sub-optimal hybrid policies based on an aggressive target and high trigger price

4 412 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) lead to better welfare outcomes than a pure quantity-based policy with the same target. Both the improved flexibility and better welfare outcomes make the hybrid policy an attractive alternative to either permits or taxes alone. 2. Background 2.1. Weitzman Roberts Spence The analysis presented in Weitzman (1974) concerns the choice of a policy instrument to regulate a market where either political considerations or market failure require government intervention. A price (tax) or quantity (permit) instrument is at the government s disposal and the question posed by Weitzman is which of the two leads to the best welfare outcome, measured as net social 5 surplus. Importantly, the policy must be fixed before any uncertainty is resolved 6 and cannot be revised. Weitzman s basic result was that price instruments would be favored when the marginal benefit schedule was relatively flat and quantity instruments would be favored when the marginal cost schedule was relatively flat. In particular, he derived an expression for the relative welfare advantage of prices over quantities: 2 s D 5 ] 2(c 22 b 2) (1) 2c 2 2 where s is the variance of the shocks to the marginal cost schedule, c2 is the slope of the marginal cost schedule and b2 is the slope of the marginal benefit 7 schedule. Based on this expression, the price instrument is preferred when benefits are relatively flat (D. 0 when b 2, c 2) and the quantity instrument is preferred when benefits are relatively steep (D, 0 when b 2. c 2). More recently, Hoel and Karp (1998) and Newell and Pizer (1998) have demonstrated that Eqs. (1) continues to hold when benefits are related to the stock of accumulated output, rather than the annual flow, after adjusting b2 to account for discounting, decay, growth, and the potential correlation of cost shocks over time. Not long after Weitzman s original article, several authors proposed a hybrid policy in place of pure price or quantity controls (Weitzman, 1978; Roberts and 5 Here and throughout it is assumed that the quantity instrument is an efficient quantity instrument; e.g. a tradeable permit system with negligible transaction costs. 6 Laffont (1977) provides a careful description of the information structure assumed in policy choice problems formulated in the Weitzman tradition. 7 The parameter b2 is actually minus the slope since the schedule of total benefits is usually concave. This result is derived for the case of linear marginal costs and benefits, where uncertainty enters as small shifts to each curve (therefore the slopes b2 and c2 are known with certainty). The uncertainty about costs is assumed to be independent of any uncertainty about benefits. See Stavins (1996).

5 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Spence, 1976). A hybrid policy gives producers the choice of either obtaining a permit in the marketplace or purchasing a permit from the government at a 8 specified trigger price. Such a policy operates like a permit scheme with uncertain costs and fixed emissions as long as the marginal cost, reflected by the permit price, remains below the trigger. When the trigger price is reached, however, control costs are capped and emissions become uncertain, as in a tax scheme. By setting the trigger price high enough or the number of permits low enough, the hybrid policy can mimic either a pure quantity or pure price mechanism, respectively. Since it encompasses both tax and permit mechanisms as special 9 cases, the hybrid policy will always perform at least as well as either pure policy. Policymakers and economists often focus on many considerations other than the partial equilibrium welfare concerns highlighted by the Weitzman Roberts Spence analysis (Stavins, 1989; Goulder et al., 1997; and Parry and Williams, 1999). In the United States, experience with quantity-based permit systems for both national SOx and regional NOx pollution control has created political support for market-based quantity controls especially when valuable permits are provided gratis to those bearing the most concentrated cost burden. At the same time, popular opposition to taxes of any kind makes the prospect for pure 10 price-based regulations rather grim. Yet, a hybrid system with welfare properties nearly identical to (or better than) a pure price-based mechanism retains virtually 11 all the politically desirable characteristics of a permit system. Since this paper indicates that price-based or hybrid mechanisms produce five-times the welfare gain associated with quantity controls, it suggests an opportunity for significant and feasible policy improvement Costs of climate change mitigation In order to compare price- and quantity-based policies to mitigate climate change, we need a dynamic model of mitigation costs, benefits, and uncertainty. To this end, we make use of the model developed in Pizer (1999), which involves a stochastic extension to the deterministic climate economy model presented in Nordhaus (1994b). Based on the previous discussion of Weitzman Roberts Spence, we focus our attention on the model s characterization of costs, benefits and uncertainty, leaving the more interested reader to consult earlier work. The global cost of climate change mitigation is typically measured as the 8 A hybrid policy may also involve a price floor at which the government offers to buy back permits. However, this type of subsidy program creates dynamic inefficiencies. See Chapter 14 of Baumol and Oates (1988). 9 Such policies have been proposed in the climate change arena by McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1997), McKibbin (2000) and Kopp et al. (2000). 10 See Pearce (1991) for a discussion of the pros and cons of carbon taxes. 11 The one feature it does not share is an absolute cap on emissions. This is, however, somewhat illusory since even an absolute cap can be relaxed in the face of future political pressure.

6 414 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) reduction in consumable output associated with a particular emission level of greenhouse gases. This cost calculation is conveniently viewed in two steps: (1) calculation of the required emission reduction, expressed as a fraction of gross emissions; and (2) calculation of the fractional reduction in global output required 12 to achieve that fractional emission reduction. The first part of the calculation is determined by growth forecasts of population, productivity, and the carbon intensity of production (because carbon dioxide is the primary anthropogenic greenhouse gas). None of these trends are known with certainty and are therefore assigned probability distributions based on Nordhaus (1994b), Nordhaus and Popp (1997), and Pizer (1996). Fig. 1 shows the resulting distribution of CO2 emission forecasts used in this paper, along with the 1992 IPCC future emission scenarios for comparison. The Fig. 1. Simulated CO2 emission distribution vs. IPCC scenarios. Lines indicate the distribution of CO2 emission paths generated by the model. Circles (s) indicate 1992 IPCC CO2 emission scenarios (p. 12 IPCC 1992; pp , Pepper et al., 1992) adjusted to include controllable CFC s (see p. 71 Nordhaus (1994b)): letters in right margin refer to individual IPCC scenarios. 12 There is a third step converting the fractional loss of global output into an actual dollar loss. However, we really care about utility, not the level of output or consumption. Assuming roughly logarithmic utility (so du 5 (1/c)dc), fractional losses are a reasonable focal point since changes in utility are more closely related to fractional (versus level) changes in consumption.

7 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) IPCC forecasts tend to fall between the 5th and 75th quantiles of our simulations. This is consistent with more recent analysis suggesting a wider range of 13 possibilities than those contained in the 1992 scenarios (IPCC, 2000). The second part of the cost calculation relating fractional reductions in greenhouse gases to fractional reductions in world output is based on a survey of studies first summarized in Nordhaus (1993). These studies compute costs by various means, including engineering assessments, econometric estimation, and mathematical programming. The relationship and range of estimates are approximated in Nordhaus (1994b) by a power rule, fractional reduction in global output b 1(fractional reduction in GHG emissions) (2) Nordhaus (1994b) considers a range of values for b 1: 0.027, 0.034, 0.069, and 0.133, with the best guess being These values imply that a 20% reduction global emissions would require 0.026%, 0.033%, 0.066%, 0.077% and 0.128% reductions in global output, respectively. Here and in Pizer (1999), these values are assumed to occur with equal probability, independent of other uncertainty in the model (including the emission levels shown in Fig. 1). There are two subtle assumptions embedded in Eqs. (2) that bear mentioning. First, the relation assumes that marginal costs are increasingly steep as additional reductions are undertaken, and second, the choice of emission level is an annual decision involving an annual cost function. Both of these points are important in this analysis because they affect the slope of marginal costs, in turn affecting the difference in expected welfare between taxes and permits. The assumption of increasing marginal costs would seem innocuous based on the fact that one input the uncontrolled emission level is fixed. However, it has been argued that once non-marginal changes in production technologies are considered, costs could fall (Lovins, 1996). This relates to the second point: Over time the stock of both human and physical capital could evolve in a less carbon intensive direction, making emission choice a multi-period rather than single- 14 period decision. Both effects suggest a preference for price controls when regulation is focused on the near term, possibly switching to a preference for quantity controls when regulation is flexibly applied over a long horizon (e.g., with 15 banking and borrowing). 13 The 1992 scenarios were specifically criticized for ignoring the possibility that developing country income converges to developed country income (per capita), which would lead to higher uncontrolled emission forecasts. 14 This touches on the issue of endogenous technological change; see Grubler and Messner (1998); and Goulder and Mathai (2000). 15 If emissions can eventually be reduced at substantially lower costs, it suggests that the long-run marginal cost curve is flatter than the short-run marginal cost curve, favoring quantity controls applied over a sufficiently long horizon; see Eqs. (1).

8 416 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Benefits of climate change mitigation In contrast to mitigation costs, which are rooted in the economically familiar areas of aggregate energy use and fuel substitution, mitigation benefits are determined by long-term climate changes and the economic impacts associated with those changes. With only limited historical experience concerning climatic changes and especially their economic consequences, this is understandably the 16 most subjective and uncertain area of climate economy modeling. Nordhaus (1994a) found that scientists opinions on the possible damages from climate change range from 0% up to a 50% loss of global output. A simple model of climate dynamics coupled with a damage function based on the square of the change in global mean temperature drives our mitigation benefits. Economic activity determines a baseline, uncontrolled emission level for carbon dioxide. Mitigation activities reduce current emissions below the baseline. Each ton of unmitigated carbon dioxide generates a rise in the global mean temperature that peaks about 40 years after it is emitted, then dissipates slowly with a half-life of about 60 years. The initial 40-year delay arises because the global mean temperature equilibrates gradually in response to higher levels of accumulated carbon dioxide as the earth s atmosphere traps more solar radiation. The subsequent decline follows the gradual decay of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases in the atmosphere. A one-time 100 million ton increase in emissions (roughly 1% of annual global emissions in 1990) generates a peak temperature rise of about 2/ 10,000 of one degree Celsius using best-guess parameter values. Uncertainty in the climate model could double or halve this 18 estimated temperature increase. The economic consequences of climate change depend on these increases in global mean temperature. Following Nordhaus (1994b) and Pizer (1999), we specify a quadratic damage function with 2 fractional reduction in output due to climate damages 5 D? (T/3) (3) 0 where T is the change in temperature relative to a pre-industrialization baseline Current atmospheric CO2 concentrations of 368 ppm are higher than in any period over the past 400,000 years, which ranged ppm (Petit et al., 1999). Some work has used cross-sectional variation in climate to estimate economic consequences of climate changes such as temperature and precipitation (Mendelsohn et al., 1994). While instructive, these analyses ignore the difference between regional and global climate changes analogous to the difference between partial and general equilibrium as well as changes in storm patterns and extreme weather behavior. 17 As temperatures rise the earth radiates more heat into space, counteracting the increased retention of solar radiation due to higher levels of greenhouse gases. Eventually the earth reaches a new greenhouse gas/ temperature equilibrium. 18 There is uncertainty about both the amount of emitted CO2 that is rapidly absorbed by oceans (atmospheric retention rate) as well as the temperature change resulting from changes in atmospheric CO (climate sensitivity). 2

9 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) (circa 1860) and D0 is a parameter describing the global output reduction associated with a 38 temperature increase. Nordhaus (1994b) focuses on a bestguess value of for D0 with a sensitivity analysis including values of zero, 0.004, 0.013, and Pizer (1999) assumes these five values occur with equal probability and independently of other uncertainty in the model. The main weakness of this model of mitigation benefits is its failure to capture possibly abrupt temperature changes and/ or economic consequences related to both the level and rate of change in greenhouse gas concentrations. The thermohaline circulation of the North Atlantic Ocean, for example, warms Northern Europe by as much as 10 degrees Celsius and could collapse as a result of increased greenhouse gas emissions (Broecker, 1997; Stocker and Andreas, 1997). Such a collapse would lead to more dramatic consequences than those predicted by this model. In Section 4 we consider relaxing the quadratic functional form in Eqs. (3) to address this possibility of more abrupt climate effects Economic behavior These models of costs and benefits are dynamically linked via a simple one-sector stochastic growth model (Pizer, 1999). A representative agent chooses between consumption and savings each period based on the expected return to capital, which itself depends on population, the capital stock, and productivity. Productivity includes the negative consequences of both mitigation costs and climate damages. In this way, current mitigation costs and climate damages influence both current and, through investment, future consumption and output. Of course, mitigation activities also reduce greenhouse gas emissions and future climate damages. We compute the optimal savings level each period based on a linearized steady-state decision rule (Campbell, 1994). This allows us to simulate the economic and climate outcomes quite rapidly for a single random draw of model parameters and stochastic shocks over a 250-year horizon. We then use eight thousand random draws to approximate the range of uncertain outcomes. Mitigation costs and controlled (actual) emissions are computed separately in each period and for each state of nature based on the specified carbon tax or permit policy. The uncontrolled emission level and global output gross of climate mitigation are both determined by state variables at the beginning of each period. Under a permit policy, Eqs. (2) can be used to directly compute mitigation costs, where fractional reductions equal one minus the ratio of permits to uncontrolled emissions. In the case of a tax policy, Eqs. (2) can be differentiated to yield a marginal cost expression that, when set equal to the tax rate, can be solved for the fractional emission reduction. This reduction can then be substituted into the original relation to yield mitigation costs. With separate calculations in each state of nature, this procedure highlights how tax policies fix marginal costs and lead to

10 418 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) uncertain emissions while permit policies fix emissions and lead to uncertain marginal costs. The welfare effects of a particular policy are computed in terms of discounted utility for each state of nature. Discounted utility is then valued in a particular base year using the marginal utility of consumption in that year. Dollars in the base year can be averaged across states of nature to yield expected welfare. Additional details concerning the model specification, simulation, and welfare calculations can be found in Pizer (1999). 3. Simulation results Given the long-term nature of climate change, a policy to reduce greenhouse gas emissions inevitably involves decisions spanning many decades. In the first part of this Section, however, we consider the expected welfare consequences of choosing price or quantity controls for GHG emissions in a single year, By focusing on a single year in the near future, we can address the difference between alternate price/ quantity controls now, without becoming mired in the question of longerterm policy. In addition, focusing on a single year allows us to easily visualize the policy in quantity/ price space. While the policy is implemented in a single period, the measurement of costs and benefits includes consequences over a 250-year horizon. The second part of this section considers price and quantity policies spanning many periods. The policies are open-loop: There are no revisions to future policies as we learn about uncertain outcomes. Although such feedback is both desirable and more realistic, it would require a simplification of either the model or the 19 specification of uncertainty. With our motivating interest in instrument choice under uncertainty and not learning this is an undesirable trade-off. Based on the idea that policies are often fixed for long periods of time, we use these open-loop policies to provide an alternate bound on the welfare difference associated with the choice between price and quantity controls. A policy optimization over many periods also allows us to see whether the choice of policy in the future influences the optimal near-term policy choice. The remainder of the paper then considers the sensitivity of these results to key damage damage assumptions as well as hybrid policies that combine price and quantity controls Marginal costs and benefits We begin by computing schedules of mitigation costs and benefits in The benefits schedule is computed using 100 distinct simulations that fix emissions at 19 See Kelly and Kolstad (1999) who consider closed-loop policies in a similar model focused on learning.

11 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) intervals of 0.1 GtC over the range 5 15 GtC in the year 2010, leaving emission levels in other periods unchanged. By turning off the mitigation costs associated with the fixed emission level and comparing welfare to the base case where 2010 emissions are left unchanged, we can compute the gross benefit of a particular emission level (e.g., gross of costs). The cost schedule is computed by repeating these simulations with mitigation costs turned on. This produces estimates of the net benefits. By subtracting these net benefits from the aforementioned gross benefits, we produce estimates of cost. Both schedules can be converted to marginal ($/tc) measures by dividing the change in benefits and costs associated with an incremental 0.1 GtC reduction, measured in $billions, by 0.1 GtC. These two calculations result in a distribution of marginal benefits and marginal costs at each simulated emission level. Fig. 2 summarizes these distributions by showing both the mean marginal cost and marginal benefit at each level of emissions along with the 5% and 95% quantiles based on 8,000 states of nature (note that the 5% marginal benefit quantile overlaps the x-axis). Keeping in mind that 1990 GHG emissions were around 8.5 GtC, this figure indicates that achieving 1990 emission levels in 2010 would involve a marginal cost of between zero and Fig. 2. Distribution of marginal costs and benefits in (The 5% quantile of marginal benefits overlaps the x-axis.).

12 420 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) in excess of $30/tC far more than even the 95% quantile of marginal benefits. This large variation occurs for two reasons: Marginal costs are assumed to rise steeply given the specified cost function in Eqs. (2), and baseline emissions in 2010 are not known with certainty as highlighted in Fig. 1. Realizations of marginal costs in this figure are essentially a collection of fairly steep curves whose horizontal intercept is unknown. This figure indicates that marginal benefits, in contrast, are relatively constant though unknown. Considering the description of climate damages in the previous section, this may not come as a surprise. First, climate damage is presumed to be a gradual phenomenon with little consequence for small temperature changes, reflected in the quadratic damage function given in Eqs. (3) coupled with small values of D. Second, damages depend on the accumulated stock of GHGs in the 0 21 atmosphere and not the annual flow. Emissions in any single year, such as the 8.5 GtC emitted in 1990, represent a small fraction of the extra 190 GtC accumulated since the beginning of industrialization. This damage relation contrasts with traditional pollutants, such as particulates, SO x, NO x, etc., whose damages depend on the annual emission level because they dissipate rapidly in the environment. The scale of Fig. 2 masks the fact that marginal mitigation benefits/emission damages actually fall from $7.45 to $7.37 as emissions rise from 5 to 15 GtC. This is surprising because we generally assume convex damages: As we pollute the environment, there ought to be increasingly dire consequences from each additional ton. In the case of climate change, however, a key physical relationship connects the logarithm of atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations to the 22 change in temperature. That is, there is some fixed (but unknown) temperature change associated with each doubling of the level of carbon dioxide and other GHGs in the atmosphere thus as we emit more, the marginal temperature change is actually less. This feature coupled with quadratic damages due to temperature change guarantees a very flat and slightly concave benefit/ damage relation. We revisit this assumption in Section Comparative advantage of prices over quantities Under the assumptions made by Weitzman, the optimal permit level is simply the emission level where expected marginal benefits equal expected marginal costs and the optimal tax level is similarly the expected marginal benefit at that intersection. Thus P* 5 $7.50 and Q* 5 12 GtC indicate the optimal tax and permit policies in 2010 for controlling GHG emissions based on a Weitzman analysis. Calculating the slopes at the intersection, B050 and C055.4 $/(tc? 20 The actual 95% marginal cost quantile at 8.5 GtC is $180/tC. 21 More specifically, temperature change depends on the GHG stock and damages depend on temperature change. 22 See Eq. (2.9) in Nordhaus (1994b).

13 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) GtC), and setting s equal to the variance of marginal costs at the optimum, ($/tc), allows a rough calculation of the welfare gain of taxes over permits using Eqs. (1): ($/tc) D 5 ]]]]]] 2( $/(tC? GtC)) $25billion. 2? (5.4 $/(tc? GtC)) Discounting this to 1995 (the base year of the model) with a 6% discount rate suggests a gain of $10 billion from using taxes instead of permits just in the year This analysis based on Fig. 2 provides important intuition and a rough approximation of the welfare consequences of taxes and permits. However, it ignores important failures of the Weitzman assumptions in the current exercise. 23 Costs are not quadratic and the quantity control is not binding in all cases. In order to overcome these limitations, we now turn to the direct evaluation of social welfare. Numerically maximizing expected welfare over the range of possible price and quantity controls in 2010, we find that the optimal price policy is a $7.50/tC tax, yielding a $2.5 billion gain, and the optimal quantity policy is a 13 GtC emission 24 limit, yielding a $0.3 billion gain. The positive gain associated with price controls is quite robust: Taxes of up to $20/tC (almost three times the optimal level) continue to generate positive expected benefits. In contrast, quantitative targets below 12 GtC have negative expected benefits. A policy set at 8.5 GtC the emission level in 1990 and 20% below the median emission estimate in 2010 yields a expected net loss of $10 billion. The difference between optimal policies based on these direct simulations, $2.2 billion, is considerably less than the estimated value based on Fig. 2, $10 billion. While the Weitzman approach provides good qualitative intuition about the relative advantage of price- and quantity-based policies, the violation of key assumptions 25 clearly limits its quantitative application in this setting Optimal policy paths Up to this point the analysis has focused on the costs and benefits of different policies in a single year. The problem of climate change, however, is spread out over decades if not centuries. Policies to combat climate change may remain in 23 Uncontrolled emissions in 2010 are less than Q* 5 12 GtC in many of the simulated outcomes; see Figs. 1 and When optimizing over quantity controls, we require that emissions be at or below the specified quantity target in all states of nature (emissions will fall below the quantity target if uncontrolled emissions are low). 25 See Yohe (1978) and Watson and Ridker (1984) for further discussion.

14 422 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) place for a long time. Further, it is not obvious whether the results comparing different instruments in a single year are appropriate for a multi-period analysis. In particular, policies in future periods may influence the choice of policy in We now consider optimal policy paths for both taxes and permits. To compute optimal policies, these paths are parameterized with six values describing the tax or permit level in 2010 (the first year of implementation), 2020, 2040, 2070, and Policies in intervening years are based on smooth interpolations, except the level in 2160 which is allowed to be discontinuous and is held fixed through the end of the simulation (2245). The length of the simulation as well as the spacing of the policy parameters were chosen to emphasize policy evaluation in the period and especially the early period. Fig. 3 shows the optimized permit and tax policies over In the top panel, we see the optimal quantity limit on global greenhouse gas emissions. Interestingly, the optimal permit level of 13 GtC in 2010 is roughly the same as the optimal permit level determined in the one-period analysis. There are two explanations. First, given the large initial stock of GHGs in 1995 (190 GtC above the pre-industrialization level), emission reductions do not substantially affect the GHG stock for many years. Second, as we noted in the previous section, the marginal benefits are flat over a wide range of stock levels. Thus, future policies are unlikely to affect the value of discounted marginal benefits today both because marginal benefits are flat and, even if they were not flat, significant changes in the stock level will not occur for many years, leading us to discount the value of those changes in present value terms. A second observation is that a proposal to reduce emissions to their 1990 levels (roughly 8.5 GtC) and to then maintain (or further reduce) that level in the future is far below the optimal permit level in these simulations, a point emphasized in Nordhaus original analysis. In particular, the optimal permit level rises in the future to accomodate growth in population and productivity. While it is more useful to focus on the near-term policy implications specifically the fact that they are essentially independent of future manipulations of the GHG stock this second point shows that our historical experience with growth and technology coupled with our current climate damage assumptions is inconsistent with stabilizing long-term GHG emissions. Finally, we note that when the optimal permit policy is implemented it improves welfare on average by $69 billion discounted to 1995 (total discounted benefits minus total discounted costs). This can be compared to annual global output in 1995 of $24 trillion. The bottom panel of Fig. 3 shows the path of carbon taxes that maximize expected welfare. The initial tax of $7.35 is close to, but slightly lower than, the tax computed in the one-period analysis. Unlike the optimal permit policy which 26 Policies are interpolated to 10-year intervals using a cubic spline; annual policies are linearly interpolated from the 10-year values.

15 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Fig. 3. Optimized permit and tax policies over time.

16 424 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) relaxes over time in order to accomodate growth, the optimal tax policy becomes more stringent in the future. This occurs because a given tax encourages proportional reductions if the economy doubles and the tax remains the same, emissions will double. Although some increase in emissions is desirable as the economy grows, a proportional increase is not. Therefore the optimal tax must increase in stringency at the same time an optimal permit system must be relaxed. When this optimal tax policy is imposed, it improves welfare on average by $338 billion. Compared to the $69 billion gain under the optimal permit instrument, this represents an expected improvement that is five times higher. 4. Catastrophic damages We have noted that the efficiency gains associated with price-based regulation follow largely from underlying assumptions about climate behavior and the likely economic consequences. Let us now consider how the results change if these assumptions are relaxed. There are at least two rationales for considering this possibility: The climate might behave in a more dramatic, non-linear way than specified by Schneider and Thompson (1981) and subsequently used by Nordhaus (1994b) and Pizer (1999). Alternately, the economic consequences of climate change with which we have little experience might be more convex than 27 suggested by a quadratic damage function. For transparency we focus on the latter possibility, that damages are increasingly convex, and consider the impact of changing the exponent in Eqs. (3). Specifically, we consider a modified damage function of the form fractional reduction in GDP due to damages 5 D 3 (T/3) 0 d 1 (3a) where d1 is allowed to take on values Note that by writing the damage function such that (T/3) is raised to the exponent d 1, the kink in the damage function is fixed at 3 degrees and D0 continues to reflect the damage associated 28 with this amount of warming. It turns out that one additional modification is necessary to conduct the sensitivity analysis. Earlier, it was noted that the choice of policy in 2010 was relatively insensitive to whether or not mitigation policies were implemented in future years. This allowed us to consider isolated price and quantity controls in 2010 without worrying about what occurred in the future. It also allowed us to consider policies over a 50- or 100-year horizon without worrying that the 250-year simulation horizon would be too short to produce sensible results. This 27 For a more general discussion of catastrophic damages, see Gjerde et al. (1999). 28 It is possible to treat the kink as unknown, but this only smooths out the non-linearity. Sensitivity analysis in this direction does not qualitatively alter the price/ quantity comparison.

17 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) ability to focus on near-term policies is lost when damages acquire catastrophic proportions. The choice of current policy depends on how well we avoid catastrophes in the future. In the absense of future controls, for example, it becomes desirable to increase emissions now in order to create short-term damages that reduce the capital stock and thereby reduce emissions in the future indirectly a rather perverse result. Even when future controls are included, welfare estimates become sensitive to the simulation horizon and to minute policy changes hundreds of years in the future, obscuring the effect of near-term policies. In order to continue our focus on the near-term distinction between price and quantity controls, we hold future policy constant in a sensible way across all of our policy simulations. Specifically, emissions after 2060 are costlessly reduced to 6 GtC, a level that avoids any catastrophes in the distant future if prudent policies 29 are pursued in the near term. The elimination of mitigation costs after 2060 leads us to a slightly different comparison of prices and quantities under the benchmark assumption of quadratic damages discussed previously: Prices generate a $138 billion expected gain while quantity controls generate only $20 billion. Compared to the analysis in Section 3.3 this raises the relative advantage (price gain 4 30 quantity gain) from a factor of five to a factor of seven. Fig. 4 shows how this difference between prices and quantities varies as the damages become increasingly non-linear (d. 2). In the top panel, indicating the 1 expected welfare difference between prices and quantities, D in Eqs. (1), we see that prices continue to be preferred until the non-linearity becomes quite large. This crossover occurs when d1 7. With this degree of non-linearity, best-guess damages rise from 1% of global output with 3 degrees of warming to 9% with 4 31 degrees of warming. A second observation in the left panel is that initially the comparative advantage of prices over quantities increases in absolute terms as marginal damages become steeper, apparently violating Weitzman s Eqs. (1). That is, as d1 in Eqs. (3a) rises from two to three, the marginal benefit slope b2 in Eqs. (1) presumably rises as well which should reduce D. Such a conclusion is 2 mistaken, however, as both s and c 2 (the variance of cost shocks and slope of marginal costs) in Eqs. (1) may be changing along with the marginal benefit slope as d rises Of course, one could argue that the most important effect of near-term policy should be its influence on future emissions and mitigation costs, not current emissions. However, such an effect is arguably more dependent on the aggressiveness of mitigation policy than the choice of policy instrument. Since this paper is tightly focused on the issue of instrument choice, and since such connections between current and future policy are probably more complex than the current model allows, our emphasis on near-term emission reductions and mitigation costs remains a sensible starting point. 30 This should not come as a surprise since we are now more focused on the near term and the ratio for a single year discussed in Section 3.1 is more than a factor eight ($2.5B 4 $0.3B). 31 d1 21 The actual damage function is 1 2 (1 1 D 0(T/ 3) ) ; see Nordhaus (1994b). The distinction between this expression and Eqs. (3a) is only important at high damage levels.

18 426 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Fig. 4. Effect of non-linear damages on the relative advantage of price mechanisms. In the bottom panel, another pattern arises. When we consider the ratio of welfare gains under prices and quantities, that is, expected welfare with optimal price controls 2 expected welfare without any mitigation ]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]] expected welfare with optimal quantity controls 2 expected welfare without any mitigation 32 that ratio may be much larger than one but never falls noticeably below one. 32 The smallest value of this ratio is about 0.95 when d In

19 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) other words, when d 5 12 the $600 billion dollar advantage associated with 1 quantity controls, shown in the left panel, pales in comparison to the roughly $34 trillion dollar expected welfare gain associated with either policy, generating a ratio near one in the bottom panel. However, when d 5 2 the $118 billion dollar 1 difference is quite large compared to the $20 billion dollar gain associated with the optimal quantity policy. Here, the ratio of the gains associated with a price price policy is almost a factor of seven times larger than the gains associated with a quantity policy. Why is the gain from an optimal quantity policy never more than a few percent higher than the gain from an optimal price policy? Quantity controls are only preferred when marginal damages are quite steep. In this case, the gains from any policy to drastically reduce emissions even an inefficient one will be large. Although price controls will necessarily over-control in some cases in order to guarantee adequate control in others, this inefficiency will be small relative to the gain from reduced damages. In the extreme, sufficiently high prices will induce % abatement and will be equivalent to a quantitative ban on emissions. When we look more closely at the simulations, we see that this is indeed the case. In the absence of any policy, the likelihood that temperatures rise by more than 4 degrees by 2100 exceeds 9%. In the presence of catastrophic damages (d 5 12) optimal price and quantity controls both reduce emissions in such a way 1 that the temperature increase never exceeds 4 degrees roughly the point where the catastrophic consequences begin. Fig. 5 shows the actual policy choices. In terms of quantity controls, the optimal policy involves an emission limit of 10 GtC from 2010 through In terms of price controls, it involves a tax that begins at about $15 per ton in 2010 and rises to more than $500 per ton by These are considerably more aggressive than the policies based on quadratic damages. 5. Hybrid policies As pointed out in Section 2.1, a hybrid permit policy where an initial quantity target is coupled with a trigger price at which additional, above-target, permits are sold will perform at least as well as either a pure tax or permit scheme (which are counted as special cases). We now explore the extent to which this is true for climate change mitigation policies and then consider the welfare consequences of certain suboptimal policies Optimal hybrid policies We return to the case of quadratic climate damages and begin with the choice of 33 An important distinction between the real world and the stylized world of Weitzman (1974) is that real cost shocks are not arbitrarily large; we can impose price policies that for all practical purposes guarantee a certain level of emissions.

20 428 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Fig. 5. Optimal policies with quadratic and catastrophic damages. policy in A hybrid policy in the year 2010 can be represented by an arbitrary point in a two-dimensional plane, where one dimension is the initial quantity target and the other dimension is the trigger price. Picking any point in that plane, we can use our climate economy model to compute the expected welfare gain of the policy represented by that point. Repeating the process over a grid of quantity target/ trigger price combinations, we can create a surface summarizing the welfare gains associated with those policies. Fig. 6 plots this surface for initial permit levels of between zero and 15 GtC and trigger prices of between zero and 25 $/tc. The proper way to read Fig. 6 is to note that for a grid of emission targets (0 15

21 W.A. Pizer / Journal of Public Economics 85 (2002) Fig. 6. Net expected policy benefits of alternative hybrid permit policies in GtC) and trigger prices (0 $25/ tc), the expected welfare gain relative to business as usual (no policy) is plotted on the z-axis in net present value terms. For low permit levels (, 5 GtC; back right edge of figure), the policy is essentially a tax and the surface traces out, from front to back, the welfare gain associated with a pure price policy. Similarly, for high trigger prices ($25/tC; front right edge of figure), the surface roughly traces, from left to right, the welfare gain associated with a pure quantity policy. The global optimum, a 5 GtC target and $7/tC trigger price, yields a welfare gain that is imperceptibly higher than the $2.5 billion gain achieved with a straight 34 tax of $7.50/ tc. More importantly, however, it performs considerably better than even the best pure permit policy. Relative to sub-optimal permit policies such as 34 Such a policy is remarkably close to the proposal suggested by McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1997). They advocated 1990 emission levels as the permit volume coupled with a $10/ton C trigger global controllable GHG emissions were 8.5 GtC.

Summary of the DICE model

Summary of the DICE model Summary of the DICE model Stephen C. Newbold U.S. EPA, National Center for Environmental Economics 1 This report gives a brief summary of the DICE (Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy) model, developed

More information

US climate change impacts from the PAGE2002 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report

US climate change impacts from the PAGE2002 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report Page 1 of 54 16 November 27 US climate change impacts from the PAGE22 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report Chris Hope & Stephan Alberth Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, UK

More information

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account Index: 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account... 8. Introduction... 8. The deterministic case...3 8.3 Optimal consumption under uncertainty...4

More information

Images.com/Corbis 30

Images.com/Corbis 30 30 Images.com/Corbis & How Should BENEFITS COSTS Be Discounted in an Intergenerational Context? Twelve prominent economists convened at RFF to advise the US government on the vital challenge of evaluating

More information

A few arguments in favor of a carbon tax and a new proposal for climate cooperation

A few arguments in favor of a carbon tax and a new proposal for climate cooperation A few arguments in favor of a carbon tax and a new proposal for climate cooperation Robert Schmidt Yale University May 27, 2015 Schmidt: Reasons for a carbon tax + new proposal 1 Part 1: Arguments in favor

More information

Maxwell Climate Change Workshop Background: The Nature of the Problem

Maxwell Climate Change Workshop Background: The Nature of the Problem Maxwell Climate Change Workshop Background: The Nature of the Problem Peter J Wilcoxen Departments of Economics and Public Administration The Maxwell School of Syracuse University September 21, 2010 1

More information

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change Some Simple Economics of Climate Change Kevin M. Murphy The University of Chicago September 7, 2008 Climate Change Climate change has emerged as a significant policy issue. In the U.S. both Presidential

More information

Introduction. Frequently Used Abbreviations and Acronyms

Introduction. Frequently Used Abbreviations and Acronyms This Appendix is based upon material provided by the University of Maryland Center for Environmental Science. Frequently Used Abbreviations and Acronyms CO 2 : Carbon Dioxide IPCC: Intergovernmental Panel

More information

Climate Policy. Michael Springborn. Department of Environmental Science & Policy. springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu.

Climate Policy. Michael Springborn. Department of Environmental Science & Policy. springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu. Climate Policy Michael Springborn Department of Environmental Science & Policy springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu mspringborn@ucdavis.edu [image: USGCRP, 2010] The intensity of CO2/GDP is falling but not fast

More information

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Warwick J. McKibbin and Peter J. Wilcoxen Australian National University Economics and Environment Network Working Paper EEN0306

More information

Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy

Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy Figure SI.1: Diagrammatic illustration of different long-term effects of a one-period temperature shock depending on whether climate

More information

Pathways to climate stabilisation

Pathways to climate stabilisation Pathways to climate stabilisation Bent Sørensen Energy, Environment and Climate Group, Department of Environmental, Social and Spatial Change, Roskilde University, 4000 Roskilde, Denmark. E-mail: boson@ruc.dk

More information

Dominion Virginia Power and Clean Power Plan Costs: A brief review of the Dominion s 2015 Integrated Resource Plan compliance cost estimates

Dominion Virginia Power and Clean Power Plan Costs: A brief review of the Dominion s 2015 Integrated Resource Plan compliance cost estimates Dominion Virginia Power and Clean Power Plan Costs: A brief review of the Dominion s 2015 Integrated Resource Plan compliance cost estimates by William Shobe Center for Economic and Policy Studies and

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice Paul A Johnson Economics 304 Advanced Topics in Macroeconomics Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice A: The Two-Period Model Consider an individual who faces the problem of allocating their available

More information

Uncertainty, Ethics, and the Economics of Climate Change

Uncertainty, Ethics, and the Economics of Climate Change Uncertainty, Ethics, and the Economics of Climate Change Richard B. Howarth Pat and John Rosenwald Professor Dartmouth College Presentation to the Environmental Economics Research Hub Australian National

More information

December Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries 287

December Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries 287 The hybrid permit cum price ceiling policy proposal: intuition from the prices versus quantities literature Gary W. Yohe Abstract The social value of choosing a marketable permit cum price ceiling mechanism

More information

Global Warming Projections Using the Community Climate System Model, CCSM3

Global Warming Projections Using the Community Climate System Model, CCSM3 Global Warming Projections Using the Community Climate System Model, CCSM3 YOSHIDA Yoshikatsu, MARUYAMA Koki, TAKAHARA Hiroshi Abstract This paper provides an outline of the global warming projections

More information

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy Policy Brief Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research U.S. Climate-Change Policy: The Bush Administration s Plan and Beyond Lawrence H. Goulder In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration

More information

Before the Office of Administrative Hearings 600 North Robert Street St. Paul, MN 55101

Before the Office of Administrative Hearings 600 North Robert Street St. Paul, MN 55101 Rebuttal Testimony Anne E. Smith, Ph.D. Before the Office of Administrative Hearings 00 North Robert Street St. Paul, MN 0 For the Minnesota Public Utilities Commission Seventh Place East, Suite 0 St.

More information

A Minimal Framework with Precautionary Mitigation

A Minimal Framework with Precautionary Mitigation A Minimal Framework with Precautionary Mitigation Thomas F. Rutherford University of Wisconsin, Madison (with Geoff Blanford, Rich Richels, Steve Rose and the MERGE team) EMF Workshop: Climate Change Impacts

More information

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION BRENT HUETH AND TIGRAN MELKONYAN Abstract. This papers analyzes efficient regulatory design of a polluting firm who has two kinds

More information

Chapter 10: Jeffrey Sachs, Columbia University

Chapter 10: Jeffrey Sachs, Columbia University Chapter 10: Jeffrey Sachs, Columbia University Clearly Nick s Review has been having a huge and valuable political effect. My main question is how much disagreement there really is in the rhetoric of the

More information

Why the ETS will not succeed

Why the ETS will not succeed Why the ETS will not succeed By Peter Lang 1 August 2013 Abstract Justification for Australia s carbon-pricing scheme assumes there will be a global carbon pricing system with our ETS a part of it. This

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 6: Policies for Dealing with Externalities Externalities and imperfect competition share the characteristic of diverting market outcomes from Pareto optimality. Though

More information

Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation

Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation OP 55 October 2003 Hillard G. Huntington and Stephen P.A. Brown Forthcoming in Hillard G. Huntington Energy Modeling Forum 448 Terman Center Stanford

More information

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) Public Economics by Luca Spataro Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) 1 Introduction Connection between agents outside the price system The level of externality

More information

The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions. Additional Material Available on Request

The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions. Additional Material Available on Request The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions Additional Material Available on Request Contents A Robustness Checks B Untransformed Climate Variables

More information

Climate Bathtub Sim Coach Notes and FAQs

Climate Bathtub Sim Coach Notes and FAQs Climate Bathtub Sim Coach Notes and FAQs Drew Jones Climate Interactive With overall team: Tom Fiddaman, Michael Tempel, Linda Booth Sweeney, Peter Senge, John Sterman, Juan F. Martin, Susan Sweitzer,

More information

The Marshall Institute has addressed several issues identified by the Review as pertinent to its analysis.

The Marshall Institute has addressed several issues identified by the Review as pertinent to its analysis. 8 December 2005 Sir Nicholas Stern Stern Review 2nd Floor, Room 35/36 HM Treasury 1 Horse Guards Road London SW1A 2HQ Dear Sir: The George C. Marshall Institute, a nonprofit research organization founded

More information

DIGITAL VISION/GETTY IMAGES. h ttp://ha nsen.swlea rning.com

DIGITAL VISION/GETTY IMAGES. h ttp://ha nsen.swlea rning.com DECISION MAKING P A R T4 DIGITAL VISION/GETTY IMAGES 734 h ttp://ha nsen.swlea rning.com C H A P T E R 17 Cost-Volume-Profit Analysis 18 Activity Resource Usage Model and Tactical Decision Making 19 Pricing

More information

The Challenge of Global Warming

The Challenge of Global Warming Perspective Paper The Challenge of Global Warming Robert Mendelsohn Economics, Yale University This paper was produced for the Copenhagen Consensus 2004 project. The final version of this paper can be

More information

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY 1993, Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 6(1), 161 64.

More information

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern:

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern: December 2016 Professors Joseph Stiglitz and Lord Nicholas Stern Co-Chairs of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition and World Bank Group Subject: Commission on

More information

Chapter 6. Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost

Chapter 6. Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost Chapter 6 Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost Chapter 6: Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and

More information

Carbon Cycle A CORE LEARNING GOALS ACTIVITY FOR SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS

Carbon Cycle A CORE LEARNING GOALS ACTIVITY FOR SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS CoreModels Carbon Cycle A CORE LEARNING GOALS ACTIVITY FOR SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS Summary Students construct a computer model of the global carbon cycle using STELLA software. They change the model to

More information

The Economics of Climate Change

The Economics of Climate Change The Economics of Climate Change William D. Nordhaus Yale University Growth and Development Commission Workshop on Global Trends and Challenges September 28-29, 2007 Note: slides are available. Background

More information

Agriculture and Climate Change Revisited

Agriculture and Climate Change Revisited Agriculture and Climate Change Revisited Anthony Fisher 1 Michael Hanemann 1 Michael Roberts 2 Wolfram Schlenker 3 1 University California at Berkeley 2 North Carolina State University 3 Columbia University

More information

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. Understanding UPP Roy J. Epstein and Daniel L. Rubinfeld Published Version, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Policies and Perspectives, Volume 10, Issue 1, 2010 Introduction The standard economic

More information

CLIMATE CHANGE, MITIGATION AND ADAPTATION WITH UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING

CLIMATE CHANGE, MITIGATION AND ADAPTATION WITH UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING CLIMATE CHANGE, MITIGATION AND ADAPTATION WITH UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING Alan Ingham 1 This paper is produced as part of a project on The Economic Analysis of Adaptation and Mitigation and is based on papers

More information

The Economics of the IPCC s Special Report on Limiting Temperatures to 1.5 C

The Economics of the IPCC s Special Report on Limiting Temperatures to 1.5 C The Economics of the IPCC s Special Report on Limiting Temperatures to 1.5 C Ken Gregory, P.Eng. October 29, 2018 The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) published a special report (hereafter

More information

CBO. Issues in Climate Change

CBO. Issues in Climate Change CBO Statement of Peter R. Orszag Director Issues in Climate Change Presentation for the CBO Director s Conference on Climate Change November 16, 2007 CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE SECOND AND D STREETS, S.W.

More information

Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS. Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh

Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS. Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh Background Seven Pilots Trading Systems National ETS in 2017 European Emission Trading System

More information

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model 30/10/2013 The Belgian TIMES model 1.1 General overview: history» INTERNATIONAL DIMENSION» Developed by ETSAP implementing agreement of IEA as successor of MARKAL» History of 30 years development» Software

More information

Subject: Comments on Virginia s proposal to join the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative. Dear Executive Director McKeon and Members of the RGGI Board,

Subject: Comments on Virginia s proposal to join the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative. Dear Executive Director McKeon and Members of the RGGI Board, February 9, 2018 Andrew McKeon, Executive Director RGGI, Inc. 90 Church Street, 4th Floor New York, NY 10007 Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative VIA ELECTRONIC SUBMISSION Subject: Comments on Virginia s

More information

Introduction to Artificial Intelligence. Prof. Inkyu Moon Dept. of Robotics Engineering, DGIST

Introduction to Artificial Intelligence. Prof. Inkyu Moon Dept. of Robotics Engineering, DGIST Introduction to Artificial Intelligence Prof. Inkyu Moon Dept. of Robotics Engineering, DGIST Chapter 9 Evolutionary Computation Introduction Intelligence can be defined as the capability of a system to

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET Chapter 6 We recall that perfect competition was theorised as a market structure where both consumers and firms were price takers. The behaviour of the firm in such circumstances was described in the Chapter

More information

Cap-and-Trade & Climate Policy

Cap-and-Trade & Climate Policy Cap-and-Trade & Climate Policy Using musical chairs to illustrate cap and trade Eli M. Levitt, WA Department of Ecology October 27, 2009 Adapted from Dr. H Hummel (2007) Climate Economics Today, consumers

More information

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari These notes cover the basics of the first part of our classical model discussion. Review them in detail prior to the second class

More information

Climate Policy: Costs and Design

Climate Policy: Costs and Design Climate Policy: Costs and Design A survey of some recent numerical studies Michael Hoel, Mads Greaker, Christian Grorud, Ingeborg Rasmussen TemaNord 2009:550 Climate Policy: Costs and Design A survey of

More information

Utilizing Optimization Techniques to Enhance Cost and Schedule Risk Analysis

Utilizing Optimization Techniques to Enhance Cost and Schedule Risk Analysis 1 Utilizing Optimization Techniques to Enhance Cost and Schedule Risk Analysis Colin Smith, Brandon Herzog SCEA 2012 2 Table of Contents Introduction to Optimization Optimization and Uncertainty Analysis

More information

A Solution in Search of a Problem: The Shergold Report on Emissions Trading

A Solution in Search of a Problem: The Shergold Report on Emissions Trading A Solution in Search of a Problem: The Shergold Report on Emissions Trading Alex Robson A presentation to The Lavoisier Group s 2007 Workshop Rehabilitating Carbon Dioxide held in Melbourne on 29-30 June

More information

MBF1413 Quantitative Methods

MBF1413 Quantitative Methods MBF1413 Quantitative Methods Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar 1: Introduction to Quantitative Methods www.notes638.wordpress.com Assessment Two assignments Assignment 1 -individual 30% Assignment 2 -individual

More information

Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market

Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market Ju Vinn Chai, Cen Chen, Fabienne Giauque & Wei Zhu Overview Non-renewable resources such as fossil fuels are used extensively in industrial activities and transportation.

More information

Meeting global temperature targets the role of bioenergy with carbon capture and storage

Meeting global temperature targets the role of bioenergy with carbon capture and storage Meeting global temperature targets the role of bioenergy with carbon capture and storage Christian Azar, Daniel J.A. Johansson and Niclas Mattsson Supplementary In this supplementary material, we first

More information

Statement of Stephen A. Smith, DVM Executive Director Southern Alliance for Clean Energy

Statement of Stephen A. Smith, DVM Executive Director Southern Alliance for Clean Energy Statement of Stephen A. Smith, DVM Executive Director Southern Alliance for Clean Energy Submitted to the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Ways and Means September 18, 2008 Mr. Chairman, Ranking

More information

Stop and Switch Suicidal Subsidies and The Climate Solution

Stop and Switch Suicidal Subsidies and The Climate Solution Stop and Switch Suicidal Subsidies and The Climate Solution Introduction: the big missing climate solution Today, we are fixed on a world energy economic scenario that will lead to a global temperature

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ENTICE: ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE IN THE DICE MODEL OF GLOBAL WARMING. David Popp

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ENTICE: ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE IN THE DICE MODEL OF GLOBAL WARMING. David Popp NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ENTICE: ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE IN THE DICE MODEL OF GLOBAL WARMING David Popp Working Paper 9762 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9762 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies 14.03 Spring 2003 1 Externalities: The Coase Theorem and Market Remedies 1.1 Introduction You have seen externalities in 14.01. An externality

More information

Climate Change Policy Based on Accurate Trend Forecasting. Greg Bothun and Jordan Chess, Dept. of Physics, University of Oregon

Climate Change Policy Based on Accurate Trend Forecasting. Greg Bothun and Jordan Chess, Dept. of Physics, University of Oregon Climate Change Policy Based on Accurate Trend Forecasting. Greg Bothun and Jordan Chess, Dept. of Physics, University of Oregon Despite any global policy efforts to curb CO 2 emissions, we are currently

More information

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as Economists typically assume that firms or a firm s owners try to maximize their profit. et R be revenues of the firm, and C be the cost of production, then a firm s profit can be represented as follows,

More information

EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 Executive Summary April 20, 2009

EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 Executive Summary April 20, 2009 Summary EPA Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft: The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 Executive Summary April 20, 2009 At the request of House Energy and Commerce Committee Chairman

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Overview of EPA Analysis of the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 H.R in the 111 th Congress

Overview of EPA Analysis of the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 H.R in the 111 th Congress U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Office of Atmospheric Programs Overview of EPA Analysis of the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 H.R. 2454 in the 111 th Congress September 11, 2009 Reid

More information

Figure 15 Periodic annual increment (PAI) and gross mean annual increment (MAI) in basal area per acre by treatments for (A) Skykomish treatments 1,

Figure 15 Periodic annual increment (PAI) and gross mean annual increment (MAI) in basal area per acre by treatments for (A) Skykomish treatments 1, Figure 15 Periodic annual increment () and gross mean annual increment () in basal area per acre by treatments for (A) Skykomish treatments 1, 2, 4, and 7; (B) Skykomish treatments 3, 5, 6, and 8. Each

More information

Comments on Human and Natural Forcings. Climate changes (1900 to 2000) due to human activity. Climate Variability and Climate Change

Comments on Human and Natural Forcings. Climate changes (1900 to 2000) due to human activity. Climate Variability and Climate Change Comments on Human and Natural Forcings Human input of GH gases (carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, ozone, CFCs ) has warmed the planet: net RF = +2.9 W/m 2 The largest single warming factor is increased

More information

Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience

Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience Setting Emissions Reduction Targets in a Long-term Strategy: The Chilean Experience Marcia Montedonico, Head of Socioenvironmental Development Area, Energy Center, University of Chile Rodrigo Palma-Behnke,

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Design and Implementation of U.S. Climate Policy Volume Author/Editor: Don Fullerton and

More information

Congress, Congressional Research Service, , R41836, The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Lessons Learned and Issues for Congress.

Congress, Congressional Research Service, , R41836, The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Lessons Learned and Issues for Congress. Historical Data Considerations of the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative and Implications for Going Forward Environmental Energy Alliance of New York June 1, 2016 The Environmental Energy Alliance of New

More information

Market-based Valuation of Coal Generation and Coal R&D in the U.S. Electric Sector

Market-based Valuation of Coal Generation and Coal R&D in the U.S. Electric Sector Market-based Valuation of Coal Generation and Coal R&D in the U.S. Electric Sector 1006954 Final Report, May 2002 EPRI Project Manager Jeremy Platt Tel: 650-855-2000 Cosponsor LCG Consulting 4062 El Camino

More information

Exploring Climate Models: C-Learn

Exploring Climate Models: C-Learn S YS T E M S E N R I C H M E N T E X E R C I S E Exploring Climate Models: C-Learn Students use an online climate model to explore ways to address global climate change. Objectives After completing this

More information

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Chapter 13 COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition Overview and Objectives This chapter provides a classification of different types of goods

More information

The Economics of Climate Change. Temperature anomaly

The Economics of Climate Change. Temperature anomaly The Economics of Climate Change Temperature anomaly If we continue Business as usual: Alternative theories Friis-Christensen and Lassen (Science, 1991) The mainstream assessment More recently, a study

More information

The Management of Marketing Profit: An Investment Perspective

The Management of Marketing Profit: An Investment Perspective The Management of Marketing Profit: An Investment Perspective Draft of Chapter 1: A Philosophy of Competition and An Investment in Customer Value Ted Mitchell, May 1 2015 Learning Objectives for Chapter

More information

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power Ross Baldick Copyright c 2009 Ross Baldick Title Page 1 of 54 Go Back Full Screen Close Quit 1 Background This review of background

More information

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK Chapter Six GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK This chapter attempts to derive rough estimates of the adverse effects on Chinese GDP growth attendant upon an energy price shock, defined as a substantial

More information

STATISTICAL TECHNIQUES. Data Analysis and Modelling

STATISTICAL TECHNIQUES. Data Analysis and Modelling STATISTICAL TECHNIQUES Data Analysis and Modelling DATA ANALYSIS & MODELLING Data collection and presentation Many of us probably some of the methods involved in collecting raw data. Once the data has

More information

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods Mark R. Jacobsen, 1,5 Christopher R. Knittel, 2,5 James M. Sallee, 3,5 Arthur A. van Benthem 4,5 December 8, 2014

More information

Technical Bulletin Comparison of Lossy versus Lossless Shift Factors in the ISO Market Optimizations

Technical Bulletin Comparison of Lossy versus Lossless Shift Factors in the ISO Market Optimizations Technical Bulletin 2009-06-03 Comparison of Lossy versus Lossless Shift Factors in the ISO Market Optimizations June 15, 2009 Comparison of Lossy versus Lossless Shift Factors in the ISO Market Optimizations

More information

Revision confidence limits for recent data on trend levels, trend growth rates and seasonally adjusted levels

Revision confidence limits for recent data on trend levels, trend growth rates and seasonally adjusted levels W O R K I N G P A P E R S A N D S T U D I E S ISSN 1725-4825 Revision confidence limits for recent data on trend levels, trend growth rates and seasonally adjusted levels Conference on seasonality, seasonal

More information

Climate Change Impacts in the Asia-Pacific Region - Outcomes from the AIM Model - 1. Introduction

Climate Change Impacts in the Asia-Pacific Region - Outcomes from the AIM Model - 1. Introduction The Twelfth Asia-Pacific Seminar on Climate Change 3 July - 2 August 22, Bangkok Climate Change Impacts in the Asia-Pacific Region - Outcomes from the AIM Model - Mikiko Kainuma*, Yuzuru Matsuoka** and

More information

The Economics of Climate Change C 175. Learning. Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 5 Risk and Uncertainty 39

The Economics of Climate Change C 175. Learning. Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 5 Risk and Uncertainty 39 The Economics of Climate Change C 75 Learning Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 5 Risk and Uncertainty 9 The Economics of Climate Change C 75 Learning In the following: We continue with risk We work with a

More information

Evaluation of Police Patrol Patterns

Evaluation of Police Patrol Patterns -1- Evaluation of Police Patrol Patterns Stephen R. Sacks University of Connecticut Introduction The Desktop Hypercube is an interactive tool designed to help planners improve police services without additional

More information

CLIMATE CHANGE, HUMAN SYSTEMS, AND POLICY Vol. III - Integrated Assessment of Policy Instruments to Combat Climate Change - Hans Asbjorn Aaheim

CLIMATE CHANGE, HUMAN SYSTEMS, AND POLICY Vol. III - Integrated Assessment of Policy Instruments to Combat Climate Change - Hans Asbjorn Aaheim INTEGRATED ASSESSMENT OF POLICY INSTRUMENTS TO COMBAT CLIMATE CHANGE Hans Asbjorn Aaheim Center for International Climate and Energy Research-Oslo, University of Oslo, Norway Keywords: Climate policy,

More information

SIEPR policy brief. What s the Climate Worth? By Marshall Burke. Stanford University November About The Author

SIEPR policy brief. What s the Climate Worth? By Marshall Burke. Stanford University November About The Author SIEPR policy brief Stanford University November 2015 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu What s the Climate Worth? By Marshall Burke Later this month,

More information

Executive Summary... 2

Executive Summary... 2 Executive Summary... 2 Main Report 1 Introduction... 6 2 Overview of Modelling... 7 2.1 Model Structure... 7 2.2 Key Inputs and Assumptions... 9 2.3 Methods of Assessment... 1 3 Results... 11 3.1 What

More information

Decoupling vs. Lost Revenues. Regulatory Considerations

Decoupling vs. Lost Revenues. Regulatory Considerations Decoupling vs. Lost Revenues Regulatory Considerations David Moskovitz Cheryl Harrington Tom Austin May 1992 Regulatory Assistance Project 177 Water Street Gardiner, Maine 04345 207-582-1135 DECOUPLING

More information

COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE

COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE ABSTRACT Robert M. Saltzman, San Francisco State University This article presents two methods for coordinating

More information

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at Resource Extraction, Uncertainty, and Learning Author(s): Michael Hoel Source: The Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 9, No. 2 (Autumn, 1978), pp. 642-645 Published by: RAND Corporation Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3003604

More information

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs. This year, if national product at factor cost is Rs. 500 billion, indirect taxes 150 billion and subsidies Rs. 50 billion, then national product at market prices will be: _ Rs. 700 billion. _ Rs. 650 billion.

More information

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 13, 2013 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ECON2220: Macro Theory November 13, 2013 1 / 36 Chapter Outline

More information

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Yulei Luo SEF of HKU March 31, 2015 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ECON2102CD/2220CD: Intermediate Macro March 31, 2015 1 / 36 Chapter

More information

Guided Study Program in System Dynamics System Dynamics in Education Project System Dynamics Group MIT Sloan School of Management 1

Guided Study Program in System Dynamics System Dynamics in Education Project System Dynamics Group MIT Sloan School of Management 1 Guided Study Program in System Dynamics System Dynamics in Education Project System Dynamics Group MIT Sloan School of Management 1 Solutions to Assignment #14 Tuesday, February 16, 1999 All of the explanations

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

Pricing with Market Power

Pricing with Market Power Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power 7.1 Motives and objectives Broadly The model of perfect competition is extreme (and hence wonderfully powerful and simple) because of its assumption that each firm believes

More information

POLICY BRIEF. The Lieberman-Warner America's Climate Security Act: A Preliminary Assessment of Potential Economic Impacts

POLICY BRIEF. The Lieberman-Warner America's Climate Security Act: A Preliminary Assessment of Potential Economic Impacts POLICY BRIEF The Lieberman-Warner America's Climate Security Act: A Preliminary Assessment of Potential Economic Impacts Brian C. Murray Martin T. Ross October 2007 www.nicholas.duke.edu/institute NI PB

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction and maximization Introduction Maximization. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6. General results on maximizing with two variables 3. Non-negativity constraints

More information

University of Groningen. Milieu en innovatie Krozer, Yoram

University of Groningen. Milieu en innovatie Krozer, Yoram University of Groningen Milieu en innovatie Krozer, Yoram IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please check the document version

More information

Economics 155/Earth Systems 112 Spring Final Exam

Economics 155/Earth Systems 112 Spring Final Exam Economics 55/Earth Systems Spring 006-07 Final Exam Instructions Do not open this exam before it is time to begin. If you are a graduating, write Grad on your first bluebook so we can get your grades submitted.

More information

Energy Efficiency and Changes in Energy Demand Behavior

Energy Efficiency and Changes in Energy Demand Behavior Energy Efficiency and Changes in Energy Demand Behavior Marvin J. Horowitz, Demand Research LLC ABSTRACT This paper describes the results of a study that analyzes energy demand behavior in the residential,

More information

Man s Use of Energy - Units

Man s Use of Energy - Units Man s Use of Energy - Units Energy figures are quoted in a wide range of units. During the following lectures we will mainly use Joules for smaller energy quantities, TWh for discussions about national

More information