SUSTAINABLE URBAN TRANSPORTATION - SUTRA D08/B: ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT

Similar documents
Economic analysis of benefits and cost in different countries

Methodology Interdepartmental Group on Costs and Benefits, Air Quality Subject Group February 2011

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF OUTDOOR AIR POLLUTION

CLEAN AIR FOR EUROPE - THE BASELINE ASSESSMENT

ExternE : Methodology and Results

Questions and answers on the EU Clean Air Policy Package

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF OUTDOOR AIR POLLUTION

External and infrastructure costs of HGVs in the EU28 in Update of the total cost figures from Are trucks taking their toll?

Handbook Environmental Prices Executive Summary

THE JOINT ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF CLIMATE CHANGE AND AIR POLLUTION. Rob Dellink Environment Directorate, OECD

Transport Costs and Urban Form: Is There a Connection? H Lansdell, R McKellar

Exceedance of air quality standards

The European Environment Agency (EEA) is an independent EU agency.

Measuring Environmental Impacts - Air

Environmental Parameter Values [PV4]

CBA of policy scenarios for. Mike Holland, EMRC SEG5 meeting, Brussels, April 2013

Oregon. 800 NE Oregon St. #640 Portland, OR (971)

PROJECT AND THE ENVIRONMENT

Rainer Friedrich. 37th TFIAM meeting. University of Stuttgart

Use of the guidelines in protecting public health


Abbreviations and Terminology

Transport and the Environment

TASK FORCE ON INTEGRATED ASSESSMENT MODELLING (TFIAM) 42 nd session, April 2013 Copenhagen, Denmark. Draft Chairs report I.

When OECD Environment Ministers met in April 2004, they drew

The Greenhouse Gases Sub-Objective

Definitions & Concepts

Climate Change (CC) Impacts & Adaptation

SEEA Experimental Ecosystem Accounts Valuation

GAINS model Principle concepts and example applications for Europe and Asia

4 Air quality

The increased flow of knowledge, resources, goods and services among nations that has

AN EXAMINATION OF POTENTIALS IN APPLICATION OF SUSTAINABLE TRANSPORTATION PERFORMANCE INDICATORS (STPI) TO SRI LANKA

Metrics for Sustainable Development

5. Health risk assessment of transport-related air pollution

HAMILTON B LINE LRT EVALUATION OF PHASING SCENARIOS TECHNICAL REPORT

Summary of the DICE model

Action on Climate Change and Air Pollution

Denmark. Sources of information. The following communications have been made available for this study.

5 - CBA under the microscope

UK Road Pricing Feasibility Study: Modelling the Impacts Elizabeth Cox 1 UK

ENVIRONMENTAL-ECONOMIC ACCOUNTING 101

Components, sub-components and statistical topics of the FDES 2013

Environmental Economics Lecture on topics in valuation of environmental goods. Jon Strand February 15, 2017

Comparing the Benefits of Clean Car Regulations

General principles for assessment and quantification of the health impacts of air pollution

A Preliminary Assessment of the Economic Benefits of Project Aqua

CE 326 Principles of Environmental Engineering Prof. Tim Ellis

TRANSPHORM. Transport related Air Pollution and Health impacts. Integrated Methodologies for Assessing Particulate Matter

METHOD FACTSHEET Value transfer method

3 Air pollutant emissions

ECONOMY AND ENVIRONMENT, 2018 SUMMARY AND RECOMMANDATIONS

2.14 Environmental Profile of Spain 2012

Components, sub-components and statistical topics of the FDES 2013

01#*!2334! ISBN !

Methodologies for Environmental Valuation

Session SBI46 (2016)

The impact of future vehicles on pollutant emissions and air quality in Europe

The methods to estimate the monetary value of the environment

GE 2211 Environmental Science and Engineering Unit III Air Pollution. M. Subramanian

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change

PART IV Benefits for Cities in Climate Change Action

Multiple Account Evaluation for Alberta Transportation: A Decision Making Tool

CLIMATE CHANGE (EMISSIONS REDUCTION TARGETS) (SCOTLAND) BILL

Climate Change Adaptation and Disaster Risk Management in Nigeria for Sustainable Development

Indicators to Assess Sustainability of Transport Activities

Poland s Third National Communication under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, 2001

A- 1: Emissions of pollutants into the atmospheric air. 2) Relevance for environmental policy... 3

TOOL #62. THE USE OF ANALYTICAL MODELS AND METHODS

ExternE. Externalities of Energy. Methodology 2005 Update EUR 21951

Interconnections Between Air Pollution, Climate Change and Health: Promoting Sino U.S. Cooperation

CE 213A Introduction to Environmental Science

Towards the Use of Emission Taxes in Canada

European Perspectives

MARRAKECH 2016 COP22 CMP12 CMA1 U N C L I M A T E C H A N G E C O N F E R E N C E

The impacts of policies to meet the UK Climate Change Act target on air quality an explicit modelling study

Estimating the Benefits of EPA s Air Pollution Regulations

The role of externalities in the Cost Benefit Analysis of Rome Milan HS line

Environmental Externalities: Short history and basic concepts

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the documents


Report on Projections of GHG Emissions up to 2020

Drivers of transport demand trends

Overview of. Aviation Air Quality and Climate Impacts. Federal Aviation Administration

EUROPEAN COMMISSION Programme «LIFE+2007» Developing Local Plans for Climate Change Mitigation by 2020 (CLIM LOCAL2020) LIFE07 ENV/GR/000282

AIR POLLUTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

10.0 AIR QUALITY AND CLIMATIC FACTORS

Air Quality & Environment

Health effects of climate changes: need for mitigating and adaptive measures

Millennials Inheritance Revisited by Alberto Bientinesi, FAO Volunteer

Benefit cost Analysis: General Approaches Jeff Lazo Tuesday September 21, 2009

EU AMBIENT AIR QUALITY LEGISLATION PRESENT AND FUTURE. A. Kobe DG Environment, European Commission

Global work on climate change indicators

Measurement & Valuation Framework

The Economics of Climate Change C 175. Learning. Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 5 Risk and Uncertainty 39

The Economics of Climate Change Nicholas Stern

ECONOMIC QUESTIONS OF AIR ASSET VALUATION: A METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH

Introduction. 1 McKinstry/Bounajm. 1 In this paper, any reference to short lines also includes regional railways.

Final Revisions to the Primary National Ambient Air Quality Standard for Nitrogen Dioxide (NO 2 )

Concept of Sustainable Transport: Planning and Designing for Sustainable and Inclusive Transportation Systems UNESCAP Transport Division

Transcription:

SUSTAINABLE URBAN TRANSPORTATION - SUTRA D08/B: ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT First Interim Report January 2002 Gretel Gambarelli, Dino Pinelli Content of this first interim report This report D08/b- Economic assessment is part of the final deliverable of Workpackage 8 of SUTRA Sustainable Urban Transportation (EVK4-1999-00006P). The final version of the report will describe the methodology to be applied for the economic assessment of the scenarios of sustainable urban development. This first interim report outlines the structure of the final report. Each section starts with a description of its future content in the final report. It also provides an overview of the proposed methodology for the economic assessment of scenarios in SUTRA, including a first selection of the categories of costs that are likely to be included in the final economic assessment. The structure of the report is based on the assumption that this report needs only to describe the methodology. The description of the results of economic assessment will be in D.12 (Scenario analysis city and summary report) and D.13 (Scenario comparison and multi-criteria assessment).

TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION 2 ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT OF URBAN TRANSPORTATION SCENARIOS 3 EVALUATION OF THE TOTAL SOCIAL TRANSPORT COST 3.1 EXTERNAL COSTS 4 REFERENCES 2

1. Introduction This report is part of the project SUTRA Sustainable Urban Transportation (EVK4-1999-00006P). It describes the methodology to be applied for the economic assessment of the scenarios of sustainable urban development (Workpackage 8). The primary objective of SUTRA is to develop a consistent and comprehensive approach and planning methodology for the analysis of urban transportation problems, that helps to design strategies for sustainable cities. The project is based on the model-based elaboration of scenarios of urban development using transport, emission, air quality and energy system analysis models. Scenarios are defined for each of the cities participating in the project, considering the current base line, and a set of probable development strategies in terms of demographic, socio-economic, spatial, structural, and technological developments over the next decade and beyond (30 year horizon). A set of indicators compatible with the indicators for urban sustainability used in the Dobris Report, are used for a baseline analysis, ranking and benchmarking (within the participating cities and across all of Europe) that ultimately support a discrete multi-criteria selection mechanism to identify preferred strategies and policies. The economic assessment is part of the overall strategy of the project and intends to complement the multicriteria selection mechanisms with an overall assessment of costs associated with each scenario of urban sustainable development. This report describes the methodology to be applied for the economic assessment to be undertaken for each scenario. Results are reported and discussed in D.12 (Scenario analysis city and summary report) and D.13 (Scenario comparison and multi-criteria assessment). In particular, this report: discusses the main features of the evaluation of scenarios; identifies the categories of costs that need to be included in the economic assessment of SUTRA scenarios; introduces the approach undertaken in this study for each category of costs; reviews for each category the estimations available in the literature, summarising the findings in a way that will be applicable in the modelling exercises. 2. Economic assessment of urban transportation scenarios The economic assessment of a given urban development scenario aims at evaluating the main costs implied in a transition from the baseline to that scenario. The purpose of this evaluation is to complement the multicriteria selection mechanisms, providing policy makers with a main information, which cannot be set aside in public decision making. In SUTRA, each scenario can be interpreted as a programme of projects that include a variety of things, such as changes in the composition of the fleet, in land-use patterns or in mobility management devices and practices. Each of these programmes is likely to have important consequences for individuals and households, for businesses of all sizes, and for local, regional, and national governments and it is therefore likely to change the total social transport cost. Total social transport cost is the sum of private and external costs. Private costs are costs supported by the same individuals who benefit from transportation. Therefore, in economic terms they are referred to as internal costs. They include individual s time, investment and operating costs (i.e., fuel etc). External costs, on the contrary, are costs derived from the behaviour of some individuals, but supported also by other people. They include congestion costs (the increase in time costs of other drivers), air pollution costs (i.e.: damages to building, human health), noise costs. The implementation of a set of measures in a scenario modifies the stream of private and external costs that define the total social transport cost. The economic assessment of a scenario implies the evaluation of the change in total social transport cost relatively to a do-nothing alternative. The change in total social transport 3

cost is not intended to represent a precise quantitative measure of the gains or the losses that can emerge when adopting a certain scenario: the uncertainties involved in the measurement of impacts and in the assignment of an economic value to these impacts prevent from relying on such an index. The purpose is just to provide policy makers with a rough information about whether and to what extent a program is likely to reduce or increase total social costs of transportation with respect to the baseline scenarios. 3. Evaluation of the total social transport cost As stated above, total social transport cost can be viewed as the sum of private and external costs. In a socialeconomic perspective, costs can be seen as burdens which affect individuals welfare. It is very easy to understand how private costs influence the welfare of people, through modifying their wealth. Hence, the economic valuation of this category of costs is an unavoidable task. Since in an urban development scenario private costs concern market goods, such as durable goods (e.g. cars), non-durable goods (e.g. fuel), services (e.g. periodic car maintenance) and time (which has an economic value in the labour market), the economic assessment concerning these cost is straightforward. Besides private costs, however, even external costs concur to influence quality of life at a very high degree. Some examples are the effects on health of air pollution and accidents, the time lost due to congestion, the implications of high levels of noise in urban areas. Because of the main impact of these costs on individuals welfare, they cannot be ignored in a comprehensive cost assessment of urban development scenarios, whose objective is to provide policy makers with a global view of the cost implications of each considered alternative. In order to achieve this ambitious goal, there is a need to evaluate external costs. Contrary to the case of private costs, at this point a major problem arises, because goods which external costs refer to are generally non-market goods. Clean air, health, free time are not traded in markets, so that market dynamics cannot give us a price, which is normally used as a starting point to derive the real value of the considered good. Nevertheless, the recent environmental-economic literature has developed powerful tools to give an economic value to some goods, which cannot be estimated through market considerations. Applying these methodologies, it is possible to evaluate the most important external costs, which are likely to be generated by the implementation of a considered program. A comprehensive assessment would include all the primary and secondary effects that complex social and natural systems would involve. An economic assessment cannot consider every single category of costs which is generated in each step. Even if it could, the outcome of the analysis would not be reliable, since the estimates provided by existing economic tools are subject to a very high level of uncertainty. Particularly as regards external costs, the economic theory is very recent and still incomplete: many proposed evaluation methods have not been sufficiently tested and for what concerns some impacts, no acceptable evaluation methods have been found yet. Because of these reasons, a limited set of private and external costs will be considered in this analysis. The criteria used to choose which costs to include are the following: the relative burden of a category of costs compared to the others: according to the existing literature, we will not consider costs which are likely to be of minor importance; the reliability of the assessment of particular impacts: if the estimation of a certain impact is source of major discussion between experts, the corresponding category of costs will not be taken into consideration; the existence in the literature of reliable estimates of the considered costs: if there is a lack of information, the interested class of costs will not be assessed. In the following subsections, literature on the evaluation of the main private and external costs will be reviewed and the methodologies which are likely to be applied in each case will be briefly mentioned. The exclusion of a category of costs will be justified on the basis of the criteria mentioned above. 4

3.1 External costs SUTRA WP 8/b Economic assessment In an urban transportation scenario, an external cost arises when a direct effect of the transportation system is the source of an indirect effect, or impact, on either humans, materials or natural systems When this impact is strong enough to cause a change in individuals welfare and the responsibles of this impact (i.e. the users of transportation) don t cover the full cost of the social utility loss, then an external cost is born. Main direct effects of transportation capable to produce external costs are: air pollution; accidents; noise; congestion; GHGs emissions. In what follows, each of these phenomena is investigated with respect to the main external costs it is likely to generate. Air pollution Transportation is a main source of emissions in the atmosphere. In particular, pollutants which cause major negative impacts are: NO X, VOCS, CO and PM 10. NO X is a responsible of acid rain that, as it is known, have adverse effects on vegetation. Some have observed that exposure to NO X can cause an aggravation of asthmatics crisis in susceptible subjects. Some of the VOCs have carcinogenic effects on human and animals, while others are precursor of molecules (oxygenated molecules) that is known can damage vegetations and materials. CO is responsible of damage on people health and life quality as it has a very strong affinity for emoglobin and, therefore, it binds itself to this molecule, causing a less oxygen distribution to tissues. PM 10 is a pollutant very important in damaging health as, for its very small dimension, it could be inhaled and thus enter in respiratory organs; the danger lies in the fact that often it contain other dangerous substances, as carcinogenic Pb and Cr. These pollutants are implicated in the following impacts: NO X VOCs CO PM 10 HEALTH (mortality and X X X X morbidity) BUILDINGS MATERIALS AND CROPS X X FORESTS X X X According to the existing literature, effects on health, crops and materials have the highest relative importance, while impacts on ecosystems, forests and visibility are suggested to a very high level of uncertainty. [See, for example, the Economic Assessment of PEEP, in which an exhaustive review of the literature up to 1998 can be found]. As regards impacts on crops, an important specification has to be made: NO 2 and SO 2 are responsible of fertilisation effects, i.e. the impact of these pollutants on agricultural production is positive. On the contrary, O 3 has a negative effect on crops. Different evaluation studies have tried to assess the overall effect of NO 2, SO 2 and O 3 on crops. The net impact results to be in some cases positive, in other negative [see Holland et al., 1999]. Hence, in this study we assume that fertilisation effects offsets crop yield damages due to O 3. For what concerns buildings and materials, all the considered pollutants have a noxious impact on them. Nevertheless, the damage results to be of minor importance if compared to the effects on health. Hence, the analysis will focus exclusively on health effects, with regard to both mortality and morbidity. X 5

The methodology used to compute external costs related to health impacts is, nowadays, rather accepted in the health-economic literature. It is based on the concept of willingness to pay (WTP) for reducing the risk of dying or of contracting a specified illness. WTP is estimated through individual surveys, where the questionnaires are constructed following different criteria, depending on the chosen method (contingent valuation, stated preferences etc.). Once WTP has been estimated, it is possible to derive the so called value of a statistical life (VOSL). This estimate can be applied in the evaluation of air pollution related mortality. Alternatively, an approach that takes into account the length of life lost through premature mortality can be used, where the value of a life year (VOLY) is computable on the basis of estimates of the VOSL. As regards VOLY, different values exist, depending on whether we consider chronic or acute effects and on what type of chronic illnesses. For what concerns morbidity, the WTP for an illness is composed of the following parts: the value of the time lost because of the illness, the value of the lost utility because of the pain and suffering, and the costs of any expenditures on averting and/or mitigating the effects of the illness. In the European Project ExternE, the reference value for a VOSL equal to MECU 3.1 (1995), corresponding to an average VOLY between 84,000 ECU (0% discount rate and age 35) and 322,392 ECU (10% discount rate and age of 45). Besides, WTP for many air pollution related diseases is provided. Because these estimates have been chosen after a serious review of the literature and hence are commonly used as a benchmark in other studies, we will rely on them, once adjusted for the average GDP real growth rate. Accidents Strictly speaking, accident costs are just partially external costs: the users of transportation, who are responsible of accidents, do generally pay a big share of the cost of unsafety, in terms of deaths, injuries and other losses. Hence, these costs should probably be better considered as private costs. Methods used for evaluating the cost of accidents generally involve multiplying the numbers of dead and injured people and other damages by the per unit cost of these deaths, injuries and losses. As stated above, cost estimates are increasingly based upon individuals willingness to pay. Hence, this methodology will be adopted. Noise Noise impacts are very difficult to evaluate, since they depend on a number of features, like the frequency and regularity of noise, the source of noise (e.g. railway noise and road noise producing the same nuisance differ of 5 dba) and individuals perception of noise. The most common methods of evaluation are: Assessing the effects on the market value of buildings, since a negative correlation exists between noise levels and the market value of dwellings. Evaluating the cost of actions, which would have to be taken to eliminate or attenuate noise. Evaluating the damage caused by noise and the cost of corrective action, where the damage is essentially related to health. All of these methods present major limits and a high level of uncertainty. This is the reason why there exists a wide dispersion within current evaluations. Greene et al. (1997) provide a set of evaluations in terms of ECU per 100 passenger-km, coming from several studies on different European countries. The range is between 0.03 and 1.00, with a mean value of 0.37. Avoiding extreme values, as well as evaluations referred to non-urban areas, a value of 0.4 ECU per 100 passenger-km, seems reasonable and will be used in the assessment. Congestion The green paper of the European Union refers to congestion costs as the difference between real transport times and transport times, which would be possible without any congestion, at a very low traffic. The main difficulty involved in the valuation of these costs is that there exists a large spectrum of values of time, according to the personal characteristic of the user and the purpose of the travel. 6

VISUM model will be used to assess the time lost due to congestion per passenger-km. In order to give a value to this time, the average wage rate will be used. GHGs emissions The increase in concentrations of CO 2 and other gases (mainly CH 4 and N 2 O) in the atmosphere causes the so called greenhouse effect, i.e. an increase in the global temperature. Likely consequences of this warming include such things as biodiversity losses, effects on agriculture, a rise in sea level, etc. The exact extent of temperature increase due to urban emissions of such gases and its impact on regional and local meteorological conditions, as well as the resulting economic and social impacts are uncertain. Studies of the monetised value of damage done from global warming are now quite extensive. Two forms of estimate have been produced in the literature: estimates of actual damage arising at the point in time when 2xCO2 occurs (i.e. a doubling of pre industrial atmospheric concentrations of CO2) and arising from a small increase in emissions now; a shadow price defined as the level of tax required to keep emissions on an optimal trajectory as estimated by the modeller. Because the estimates relate to damage or benefit at the time when 2xCO2 occurs, they are then discounted back to the present so that the choice of discount rate matters. Frankauser (1995) provides estimates of marginal damage values for the main greenhouse gases, using the discount rate as a random variable (p=0%, 0.5%, 3%), with a best guess value of 0.5% for p. The resulting estimates for the 3 considered gases are expressed in terms of 1997$/tonne. Alternatively, Greene et al. provide, as for noise, a set of estimates from different studies, expressed in terms of ECU per 100 passenger-km. Both of these bunches of values are worthwhile for SUTRA, since VISUM model is going to provide both estimates of n. passenger-km and of tons CO2 emitted for each scenario (consumed fuel times CO2 coefficient). Hence, either Frankauser s or Greene s values will be used. 7

4. References SUTRA WP 8/b Economic assessment Economic Assessment of Priorities for a European Environmental Policy Plan (PEEP), Background Document (1998) Frankhauser, S. (1995) Valuing Climate Change: the Economics of the Greenhouse, Earthscan, London. Greene, D. L., Jones, D. W., Delucchi, M. A. (1997) The Full Costs and Benefits of Transportation, Springer Holland, M. R., Forster, D. King, K. (1999) Cost-Benefit Analysis for the Protocol to Abate Acidification, Eutrophication and Ground Level Ozone in Europe Markandya, A. (1997) Monetary Valuation Issues in Extended ExternE, for EC DGXII (JOULE Programme), European Commission, 1999. NERA (1997) Valuation of Deaths from Air Pollution. National Economic Research Associates. Report for the Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions, 123 Victoria Street, London. 8