Economics 230a, Fall 2017 Lecture Note 4: Excess Burden and Basic Optimal Taxation

Similar documents
Econ 101, section 3, F06 Schroeter Exam #2, Red. Choose the single best answer for each question.

UNIT 4 PRACTICE EXAM

2014 $1.75 $10.00 $ $1.50 $10.50 $ $1.65 $11.00 $ $2.00 $11.50 $150

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

Homework 4 Economics

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

Assignment 2: Supply and Demand

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE THE UNIVERSITY OF HONG KONG ECON6021 MICROECONOMICS PROBLEM SET NO.3 COMPETITIVE MARKETS AND MONOPOLY

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam. Prepared by Katharine Rockett Dieter Balkenborg. Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition

Social Interactions in Demand

7.1 The concept of consumer s surplus

Lesson-9. Elasticity of Supply and Demand

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Consumer and Producer Surplus and Deadweight Loss

Other examples: tourism (lodging, car rental, etc.), tobacco and alcoholic beverage excise, real estate transfer

Chapter 14. Chapter Outline

Chapter Outline McGraw Hill Education. All Rights Reserved.

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Econ 200: Lecture 6 October 14, 2014

Social Interactions in Demand

ON EQUILIBRIUM IN MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION

Problem Set 3 Eco 112, Spring 2011 Chapters covered: Ch. 6 and Ch. 7 Due date: March 3, 2011

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

PICK ONLY ONE BEST ANSWER FOR EACH BINARY CHOICE OR MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTION.

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Class Agenda. Note: As you hand-in your quiz, pick-up graded HWK #1 and HWK #2 (due next Tuesday).

ECON 251. Exam 1 Pink. Fall 2013

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior

Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics

Price MCI MSC MEC. q1 Firm output. Industry output

1 Budget Set, Preferences, Consumer s Optimum

Economics. In an economy, the production units are called (a) Firm (b) Household (c) Government (d) External Sector

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

Commerce 295 Midterm Answers

Competitive Markets: Applications

LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

1. True or False. If the marginal product of labor is decreasing, then the average product of labor must also be decreasing. Explain.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

Discussion Handout 2 6/22/2016 TA: Anton Babkin

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Economics 3070 Summer Introduction and Review: Chapters 1, 2 (plus corresponding study guide)

Intermediate Microeconomics Spring 2005 Midterm Exam

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

Practice Final Exam. Write an expression for each of the following cost concepts. [each 5 points]

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Answers to RSPL/2. Section - A

MICROECONOMICS SECTION I. Time - 70 minutes 60 Questions

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION

MPC MPC. Under a Pigouvian subsidy, s, the firm s MPC curve shifts up to MPC = MPC + s. This is less

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101, sections 2 and 6, S06 Schroeter Exam #2, Red. Choose the single best answer for each question.

Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm

Fundamentals of Markets

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Gregory Clark Econ 1A, Fall Midterm 2. Closed book exam. No cell phones, calculators, or other electronic aids allowed.

Gregory Clark Econ 1A, Fall Midterm 2. Closed book exam. No calculators, cell phones, or other electronic aids allowed.

Chapter 2: The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply. Multiple Choice Questions

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Analyzing Accumulated Change Integrals in Action. Improper Integral

Practice Test for Midterm 2 Econ Fall 2009 Instructor: Soojae Moon

1. Suppose that policymakers have been convinced that the market price of cheese is too low.

2) All combinations of capital and labor along a given isoquant cost the same amount.

Subtleties of the Supply and Demand Model: Price Floors, Price Ceilings, and Elasticity

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Imperfect Competition

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

T ( P ( ) * FA F D A S

BCA 2/4/97 1 of 5. Consumer and producer surplus are the main measures of the net welfare changes a policy generates.

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 3-4

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Additional Questions. Externalities and Public Goods.

14.01 Fall 2010 Problem Set 6 Solutions

Chapter 1: The Ten Lessons in Economics

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August IMPORTANT. You are expected to adhere to the following guidelines in completing the exam:

Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

Other examples of monopoly include Australia Post.

The Basics of Supply and Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 9: Externalities and Public Goods

CGN Computer Methods. Numerical Methods Lecture 4 - Numerical Integration / Differentiation

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Problem Set 5. The price will be higher than the equilibrium price. There will be a surplus of cheese.

Index. Cambridge University Press A Short Course in Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Roberto Serrano and Allan M.

Elasticity and Its Applications PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS (ECON 210) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

Homework 2 Answer Key

Problem Set #2 - Answers. Due February 2, 2000

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key March 31, 2008

The total final is worth 30 points. Each question is worth 2 points, and each sub question is worth an equal share of the two points.

Transcription:

Economics 230a, Fall 2017 Lecture Note 4: Ecess Burden and Basic Optimal Taation Deadweight loss measures the economic cost of market distortions; when one is referring to the distortions caused by taation, the deadweight loss is referred to as the ecess burden of taation, because it is the economic cost to tapayers over and above the ta revenue collected. Although deadweight loss is an intuitive concept, it may be defined in more than one way, depending on the conceptual eperiment one has in mind. Consider the case of a representative consumer. Let y be the consumer s initial income endowment and be the initial price vector the consumer faces. Assume that this price vector represents the undistorted prices charged by producers, and that these prices are fied, for eample set by world markets. Now, suppose government imposes a ta vector t to raise revenue, with the resulting new price vector p1 = + t. One definition of deadweight loss is the amount that one would have to give the consumer to compensate for the taes, net of the revenue the government collects. Assuming the individual s indirect utility function is V(p, y), this leads to the following epression for deadweight loss: (1) DWL1 = E(p1, V(, y)) y t c (p1, V(, y)) where E( ) is the household s ependiture function and c ( ) is the vector of the household s compensated demands. The first two terms indicate how much the individual must be compensated to remain at the initial level of utility (the Hicksian measure known as compensating variation), and the third term indicates how much ta revenue is available for compensation. Note that, for consistency, we calculate this revenue assuming that the compensation is occurring, i.e., that the consumer remains on the original indifference curve. Or, we could define deadweight loss as the amount we could take from the consumer, beyond the revenue we give up; to offset gains from removing the ta (the Hicksian equivalent variation): (2) DWL2 = y E(, V(p1, y)) t (p1, y) How do these measures relate? Using the identities y = E(, V(, y)) = E(p1, V(p1, y)), (p1, y) = c (p1, V(p1, y)), and t = p1, we may rewrite these two epressions as: (1 ) DWL1 = E(p1, V(, y)) E(, V(, y)) (p1 ) c (p1, V(, y)) (2 ) DWL2 = E(p1, V(p1, y)) E(, V(p1, y)) (p1 ) c (p1, V(p1, y)) (1 ) and (2 ) differ only in the level of utility (pre-ta or post-ta) at which the calculation is made; the two measures will generally differ. Figure 3 in Auerbach-Hines provides a graphical illustration of DWL2, and a similar measure can be drawn for DWL1. It is also customary to illustrate these measures graphically in price-quantity diagrams. Assume that there are two goods, a numeraire commodity that is untaed and has a price of 1, and a taed commodity with price p and quantity. Then measure DWL1 (similarly for DWL2) reduces to an epression that replaces the price and quantity vectors with scalars relating to the taed good:

(3) DWL1 = E(p1, V(, y)) E(, V(, y)) (p1 ) c (p1, V(, y)) Using the fact that E(p1, u) E(, u) = p p1 Revenue DWL pp 1 pp 0 cc (pp, uu)dddd, we graph epression (3) as: It is important to note that deadweight loss relates to the compensated demand curve, because the distortion is to relative prices; responses to lump-sum taes also have income effects, but there is no associated distortion. The deadweight loss area, approimately triangular in shape, is known as a Harberger triangle; its size is approimately ½t. One may also derive the vector version of this approimation for many taes imposed simultaneously from epression (1 ) or (2 ) as a second-order Taylor approimation, equal to ½t, around the undistorted equilibrium. Some Observations about Deadweight Loss 1. Deadweight loss rises roughly with the square of the ta. From the approimation we can see this, since when the ta rate t is twice as large, so, roughly, is the reduction in, (this is eact only if the demand curve is linear). For intuition, consider doubling the ta in the above graph: p p2 p1 t t D B C A Increasing the ta so that the price rises from p1 to p2 incurs not only another Harberger triangle, B, but also a rectangle, C; whereas A and B are secondorder terms, C is a first-order term it does not vanish as the additional ta becomes small. This is because the additional ta is imposed starting at a distorted point. In other words, it is more costly to eacerbate an eisting distortion. For the additional ta, say t, the second-order DWL approimation is (t + ½ t ). Another way to view the etra distortion, C, is that it is the revenue loss due to a decline in taed-goods consumption. That is, additional revenue from the ta increase is D C, not D. It is even possible for area C to eceed area D in size, in which case revenue would decline with the increase in the ta, indicating that the ta rate is higher than the revenue-maimizing rate, i.e., to the right of the peak of revenue as a function of the ta rate (also known as a Laffer curve). 2. Deadweight loss rises roughly in proportion to the elasticity of demand. Since is approimately t c / p = (t/p) p c / p = (t/p) ε, where ε is the own compensated demand elasticity (defined so that it is nonnegative), we can rewrite the second-order approimation for DWL as (t/p) 2 p ε. Graphically, we can see that a larger elasticity of demand increases deadweight loss and reduces revenue for a given ta rate. 2

p p1 D 1 D2 3. Ecess burden applies for subsidies as well as taes. With a subsidy, an individual will be better off, but by less than if the government had transferred the revenue directly: p F E Here, area E represents DWL, equal to the revenue cost of reducing the price to p3, E+F, net of the individual gain, F. As before, DWL -½ t, where now t < 0 and > 0. p3 4. Ecess burden applies to supply distortions as well, for eample the labor supply decision; we could represent this using a horizontal curve for labor demand and an upward sloping compensated labor supply curve. We can also measure deadweight loss in markets where both demand and supply are not infinitely elastic. (See Auerbach and Hines, sec. 2.2.) The basic formula still applies, in particular that the distortion is proportional to the change in quantity,. Can t we avoid ecess burden by imposing taes at the same rate on all commodities? If the consumer s budget constraint is p = y, why not impose taes at a constant rate, θ, so that the household s budget constraint becomes (1+θ)p = y p = y/(1+θ) effectively, a lump-sum income ta? The problem is that most of what we call income results from individual choices, for eample how much labor to supply. That choice would be distorted by the proposed scheme. Suppose that income equals w(ll - l), where the term in parentheses is labor endowment less leisure; then we can rewrite the budget constraint as p + wl = wll. Taing everything on the left-hand side at a uniform rate would give us a nondistortionary ta, but it would require that we be able to ta leisure, l, separately from the labor endowment, LL. If the government taes leisure net of labor endowment at a constant rate, this feasible ta, applied to p + w(l - LL ), will raise no revenue. Given that a realistic ta system will involve distortions, how should we choose taes to minimize deadweight loss? The discussion above suggests that we should avoid high rates of ta on any one commodity, and be especially concerned about taing commodities with high response elasticities. But this intuition is based on analysis of a ta on a single margin. 3

Optimal Taation The basic optimal ta problem seeks to maimize a representative agent s utility given that the government must raise a certain amount of revenue, R, using proportional commodity taes, which may include taes on supplies of factors, such as labor. (As Auerbach and Hines discuss, this is equivalent to minimizing one of the definitions of deadweight loss derived above.) We also assume, initially, that producer prices, q, are fied, and that the household has no truly eogenous income y. This means that the initial budget constraint is q = 0, and hence that proportional taes on all commodities raise no revenue, as just discussed. We can therefore arbitrarily set one ta rate equal to zero, say for good 0. (The same analysis would apply for y > 0 due to the eistence of pure profits, if we assumed that such pure profits could be taed away, ecept that the government would then face the task of raising the remaining R-y rather than R.) We also choose this good as numeraire: = q0 = 1, where p is the price the consumer faces. The Lagrangian for the problem is L = V(p,0) - µ[r (p q) ]. We can maimize with respect to p directly; since dti/dpi =1, choosing t is the same as choosing p.) First-order conditions are: dddd jj λλ ii + μμ ii + tt jj = 0 ii dddd ii jj where λ is the marginal utility of income. Using the Slutsky equation, dddd jj dddd ii = ss jjjj ii dddd jj dddd, and grouping terms in i, we get: dddd (4) μμ λλ + μμ tt jj jj jj ii + μμ jj tt jj ss jjjj = 0 jj tt jj ss jjjj dddd = μμ αα μμ ii ii where α can be thought of as the social marginal utility of income. As Auerbach and Hines discuss, µ α, i.e., the marginal shadow cost of revenue must be at least as high as the marginal social utility of income increasing revenue entails additional deadweight loss. To interpret epression (4), which is referred to as the Ramsey rule, note that the term jj tt jj ss jjjj is the ecess burden introduced by the additional ta on good i (the t terms). Also, revenue collected from an additional ta on good i, holding utility fied, is ii + jj tt jj ss jjjj. Thus, (4) says that, at an optimum, where small feasible variations in ta instruments have no first-order effects on utility, ddwl/dti = (µ - α)(dr/dti ddwl/dti)/µ ddwl/dti = (µ - α)(dr/dti)/α That is, we should choose taes so that the marginal deadweight loss associated with each ta is the same proportion of marginal revenue, (µ - α)/α; put another way, the marginal cost of public funds per dollar of revenue, which taking account of the ecess burden of taation, should be equal for all taes when we are trying to meet a revenue target with minimum deadweight loss. What do optimal taes look like? Consider a three-commodity model, with two consumption goods and labor as the untaed numeraire. Stacking the two first order conditions, ss 11 ss 21 ss 12 ss 22 tt 1 tt2 = μμ αα μμ 1 2, 4

we invert the matri in Slutsky terms to obtain the following epression for the ratio of ta rates, in terms of compensated cross-elasticities of demand, εij, (5) tt 1 pp 1 tt 2 pp 2 = εε 22 εε 12 εε 11 εε 21 = εε 20+εε 12 +εε 21 εε 10 +εε 12 +εε 21 where the second version of the epression follows from the condition (implied by the envelope theorem) that ii pp ii ss iiii = 0. (To see this, note that dddd ddpp jj uu = ii UU ii ss iiii = λλ ii pp ii ss iiii = 0. ) In (5), were we to ignore the cross-elasticities ε12 and ε21, the first version would call for ta rates that are inversely proportional to the own demand elasticities. This inverse elasticity rule is consistent with the intuition developed earlier when looking at a single distortion, but it does not hold when the distortions interact (i.e., when s12 0). The second version says that we should ta more heavily the good with the smaller value of εi0 the good that is more complementary to leisure. The logic is that taing goods 1 and 2 discourages labor supply (since either ta lowers the real wage the wage relative to the price of consumer goods), so taing more heavily the good that is complementary to leisure helps lessen this distortion, but at the cost of a new distortion, between goods 1 and 2. This illustrates the general principle of second-best that once we have one distortion, in this case the labor-leisure distortion, we may improve welfare by introducing another distortion, in this case to the margin of choice between goods 1 and 2. Application: The Taable Income Elasticity Sometimes, we observe a tapayer response that reflects several decisions. For eample, when we see taable income respond to the income ta rate, this reflects not only the decision of how much to work, but also the mi of compensation between taed and untaed forms (e.g., fringe benefits like health insurance) and the mi of ependitures between ta-deductible forms (e.g., mortgage interest, charitable contributions, etc.) and non-deductible ones. In such a case, the relevant elasticity will, under certain assumptions, be the overall response. Following Feldstein (1999), consider a household with a utility function, U(C, l, E, D), facing the budget constraint: C + (1-t)D= (1-t)[w(LL -l) E] where E is the portion of compensation taken in the form of goods that are ecluded from taation and D is ta-deductible household spending. We can rewrite the budget constraint as: C = (1-t)[w(LL -l) E D] from which it is clear that the relevant elasticity affecting the deadweight loss of an income ta is the elasticity of demand for non-deductible consumption, C, which equals the taable income elasticity the elasticity of taable income [w(ll -l) E D] with respect to the ta rate. As Feldstein emphasized, this elasticity may be substantially larger in magnitude than the labor supply elasticity, suggesting more deadweight loss for a given ta rate. Note that the taable income elasticity matters here only because we have assumed that ta rates cannot be set separately on E and D. Indeed, the taable income elasticity depends on the ta structure (Kopczuk, J. Pub. Econ. 2005); for eample, if no spending were deductible (D 0) 5

and all compensation taable (E 0), then the taable income elasticity would equal the labor supply elasticity. It might seem obvious that such base broadening would reduce deadweight loss, as it would leave only labor-supply responses to taation. That conclusion would hold if labor-supply responsiveness were invariant to base broadening, but this is generally not the case: the labor-supply response to an increase in t, when there are deductions and eclusions, equals the direct response to a reduction in the real wage, (1-t)w, plus the cross-effects from reductions in the prices of E and D, (1-t), which effectively increase the real wage. Intuitively, if an individual epects to pay ta on only a portion of marginal labor income (because of additional deductions and eclusions from such income), the labor supply elasticity to a change in ta rates may be smaller. In a model where taes can be set independently on all goods, having a ta base equal to labor income will be optimal precisely when the optimal taes on the other three goods, c, E, and D, are equal (and hence can all be set to zero in the presence of a ta on labor income). Application: Internet Sales Most individual US states rely heavily on sales taes as a source of revenue. But constitutional issues limit, to an etent, which states can require out-of-state vendors to collect sales ta on remote (e.g., internet and mail-order) purchases by state residents. This means that residents face sales ta on direct purchases from retail stores and remote sellers but effectively not on remote purchases from out-of-state sellers. The paper by Einav et al. finds online purchases to be quite sensitive to state ta rates using data from ebay, where potential buyers find out whether a seller is in the same state (and hence required to collect sales ta) only after epressing interest in an item. Their results also show that when a state sales ta is higher, residents purchase more on the internet (relative to in-state retail purchases) but less from remote in-state vendors. From an optimal-ta perspective, one might see this case as one with two very closely-related commodities, direct purchases and remote out-of-state purchases, with a high cross-elasticity of demand, where the state can impose ta only on one good. The high demand elasticity of the taable commodity is likely to limit the etent to which the state might wish to ta it. Also, there may be large efficiency gains from relaing the restrictions states face on internet sales. Application: The Choice of Ta Salience Ta salience has been an active area of research, dating from the paper by Chetty, Looney and Kroft (AER, 2009), who found that individuals respond more to sales taes when they are included in prices than when they are posted but not included. As in the previous two applications, government may have more policy options than just determining the ta rate. In this case, it may be possible to vary the etent to which a particular ta is salient to tapayers (as by deciding whether to require that it be included in the posted price). It might seem desirable to limit salience, since this will limit tapayer responses. However, there is an offsetting distortion when tapayers ignore a ta they allocate too little of their budget to other ependitures. That is, there is no deadweight loss if a tapayer s response displays only an income effect in response to a ta (as would be true in the case of a lump-sum ta). But if a tapayer does not respond at all, then there is no substitution effect (which reduces deadweight loss) but also no income effect (which increases deadweight loss). Goldin s paper derives the optimal degree of salience and points out that if there are two taes on a single good, one salient and the other not salient, then a combination of the two taes can mimic a lump-sum ta, since the salient ta leads to too little consumption of the taed good (relative to under a lump-sum ta) and the non-salient ta leads to too much consumption of the taed good (because the consumer ehibits on income effect). 6