Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis

Similar documents
On-The-Job Search in a Labor Market Model: Ex Ante Choices and Ex Post Outcomes

Import Competition in the High-Wage Sector and Trade Policy Effects on Labor

MIGRATION AND POLLUTION *

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp

ECON 450 Development Economics

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Tetsuya Nakajima. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University. Hideki Nakamura. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Labor Market Core Course

Rural to Urban Lecture 17

Review Questions. Unions and Collective Bargaining. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

EXAMINATION 1 VERSION A "Labor Supply and Demand" February 24, 2014

A Welfare Economic Analysis of Labor Market Policies in the Harris-Todaro Model

Labour Economics: An European Perspective Inequalities in EU Labour Market

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing

Macroeconomics II Unemployment

Econ190 May 1, No baseball caps are allowed (turn it backwards if you have one on).

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model

Labour Economics: An European Perspective Inequalities in EU Labour Market

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

Queen s University Department of Economics ECON 111*S

The Effect of Benefits on Unemployment when the Wage Bargaining Regime is Endogenous

EXAMINATION #3 VERSION A Firms and Competition October 25, 2018

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 5

Search Frictions, Efficiency Wages and Equilibrium Unemployment BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- NoDerivs 3.0 Licence.

Chapter 5. Market Equilibrium 5.1 EQUILIBRIUM, EXCESS DEMAND, EXCESS SUPPLY

6. The law of diminishing marginal returns begins to take effect at labor input level: a. 0 b. X c. Y d. Z

Unemployment, Environmental Policy, and International Migration* Kenji Kondoh. And. Shigemi Yabuuchi. Abstract

University of Toronto June 14, ECO 100Y INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 1

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

Government Intervention - Taxes and Subsidies (SOLUTIONS)

Policy Evaluation Tools. Willingness to Pay and Demand. Consumer Surplus (CS) Evaluating Gov t Policy - Econ of NA - RIT - Dr.

Application: the effect of immigration on domestic wages

AP Microeconomics Review With Answers

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

FINAL EXAMINATION VERSION A

****** 1. How is the demand for an input dependent upon the demand for an output? 2. Given a wage, how does a firm decide how many people to hire?

A Correlation of. To the Mississippi College- and Career- Readiness Standards Social Studies

Proposal 1: Require that each medical student complete one rotation at a qualified geriatric care facility.

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Quasi-Fixed Labor Costs and Their Effects on Demand

Keynes' Labor Market: A Reply. By Allan H. Meitzer

Labour Economics: An European Perspective Inequalities in EU Labour Market

Wage Floors and Economic Development

ECON 101 KONG Midterm 2 CMP Review Session. Presented by Benji Huang

Structural Change and Development

Lecture 2. Lecturer: Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour. Priscilla T. Baffour 2016/17 1

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Review Questions. The Own-Wage Elasticity of Labor Demand. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

The last lecture discussed data, not how the economy works. This lecture begins with the task of developing a simple economic model.

ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT LEVEL 1 PAPER 3 STUDY TEXT

Chapter 12 outline The shift from consumers to producers

Problem Set #3 Revised: April 2, 2007

ECONOMICS STUDY TEXT

T ( P ( ) * FA F D A S

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI)

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

Price setting problem: Rigidities

Midterm 2 - Solutions

The Backward-Bending Supply Curve of Gender Specific Work Ethics In Emerging Third World Countries

Practice for Master Class 3 Chapter 5

Chapter 28 The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle

Chapter 14. Chapter Outline

Chapter Outline McGraw Hill Education. All Rights Reserved.

2. Three Key Aggregate Markets

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

EXAMINATION 2 VERSION A "Equilibrium and Differences in Pay" March 29, 2018

Chapter 2. Practice Quiz -

Volume 29, Issue 2. A malthusian model for all seasons

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

CURRICULUM COURSE OUTLINE

Economics N. Gregory Mankiw. The Markets for the Factors of Production. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions CHAPTER

Econ 353 Final Project: Computational Forms of Economic Development Models

Volume Title: Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. Volume URL: Chapter URL:

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Government Policy, Efficiency, and Welfare

Trade Liberalization, Division of Labor and Welfare under Oligopoly. Kenji Fujiwara i Keita Kamei ii

The Effects of Fairness and Equality on Employment Levels. in a Two Firm/Two Worker Type Model. Una E. Flores

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

Final Exam - Answers

Agricultural Productivity and Structural Change

ECON 1001 A. Come to the PASS workshop with your mock exam complete. During the workshop you can work with other students to review your work.

Reconsidering of the Lewis Model : Growth in a Dual Economy

First Exam in the Course: Labor Economics for Diplom/Master. 10 August 2011

Productivity, Output, and Employment. Chapter 3. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

12) What determines the distribution of goods and services in a market economy?

TRADE REFORMS AND INFORMAL SECTOR WAGES: A THEORETICAL CONTRIBUTION

Competition and Discrimination: a not so Obvious Relationship

Transcription:

Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Articles and Chapters ILR Collection 1997 Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis Gary S. Fields Cornell University, gsf2@cornell.edu Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles Part of the International and Comparative Labor Relations Commons, and the Labor Economics Commons Thank you for downloading an article from DigitalCommons@ILR. Support this valuable resource today! This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the ILR Collection at DigitalCommons@ILR. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles and Chapters by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@ILR. For more information, please contact hlmdigital@cornell.edu.

Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis Abstract This paper analyzes the effect of a wage floor on unemployment. Using a model with covered and noncovered sectors, comparative static analysis is performed with respect to the size of the wage floor, the elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector, and the elasticity of the wage in the noncovered sector with respect to the size of the noncovered sector labor force. It turns out, contrary to the existing literature, that for none of these parameters is the comparative static effect unidirectional. Keywords wage floors, unemployment, minimum wage Disciplines International and Comparative Labor Relations Labor Economics Comments Required Publisher Statement Elsevier. Final version published as: Fields, G. S. (1997). Wage floors and unemployment: A two-sector analysis. Labour Economics, 4(1), 85-91. doi: 10.1016/S0927-5371(96)00022-X Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved. Suggested Citation Fields, G. S. (1997). Wage floors and unemployment: A two-sector analysis[electronic version]. Retrieved [insert date], from Cornell University, ILR School site: http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1120 This article is available at DigitalCommons@ILR: http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1120

Wage Floors and Unemployment 1 Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis Gary S. Fields School of Industrial and Labor Relations and Department of Economics, Cornell University Labour Economics (1997), 4, 85-91 Tel: (+1) 607-255.4561; fax: (+1) 607-255.4496; e-mail: gsf2@comell.edu.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 2 Abstract This paper analyzes the effect of a wage floor on unemployment. Using a model with covered and noncovered sectors, comparative static analysis is performed with respect to the size of the wage floor, the elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector, and the elasticity of the wage in the noncovered sector with respect to the size of the noncovered sector labor force. It turns out, contrary to the existing literature, that for none of these parameters is the comparative static effect unidirectional. Keywords: Wage floors; Unemployment; Minimum wage

Wage Floors and Unemployment 3 1. Introduction This paper examines the economic effects of wage floors. By definition, a wage floor is the lowest wage that any employer may pay or that any worker may receive. The wage floor may be caused by a minimum wage set by the government, public policy facilitating unions engaging in collective bargaining aimed at raising the wages of their members, or some other public intervention. 1 I shall by the forces of supply and demand. In the balance of this paper, I examine one consequence of wage floors, namely, the unemployment effect. I ask, when will the amount of unemployment resulting from a wage floor be large and when small? I work with a two-sector model consisting of a covered and a noncovered sector. 2 The two-sector model is a stylized representation of differential applicability of minimum wages or compliance with them, larger union wage effects in some sectors of the economy than in others, etc. Comparative statics are performed with respect to three parameters of interest: the size of the wage floor; the elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector; the elasticity of the wage in the noncovered sector with respect to the size of the noncovered sector labor force. It turns out, contrary to the existing literature, that for none of these parameters is the comparative static effect unidirectional. 1 It may also be caused by efficiency wages, but that is a whole other story. 2 This framework was developed by Harris and Todaro (1970) and Harberger (1971) in the context of rural-urban migration in developing countries. It was used subsequently by Mincer (1976, 1984) and Grämlich (1976) to analyze the economics of minimum wages in an economy with covered and noncovered sectors and extended by Fields (1975, 1989) to analyze the determinants of unemployment. For a more intuitive discussion of these models without the proofs, see Fields (1994).

Wage Floors and Unemployment 4 2. The model The model used here features wage dualism and open unemployment. Expected wage maximization is the central behavioral postulate on the supply side of the labor market. 3 Workers are assumed to be risk-neutral and to decide between supplying their labor to one sector or the other on the basis of the expected value of the wages to be earned in each, taking account of possible unemployment. Any temporary differential between expected wages in the two sectors will be eroded as migration brings expected wages into balance. Thus, expected wages, not nominal wages, are equalized across sectors in equilibrium: E(W C ) = E(W N ). Firms demand for labor curves are assumed to be inverse functions of the wage in the sector in question. Following the established literature, labor demand in one sector is assumed to be independent of wages in the other sector. Before the imposition of a wage floor, competition in the labor market is assumed to O equalize wages in the two sectors at a level denoted by W O. E C workers are assumed to be O employed in the covered sector and the remaining L E C members of the labor force to be employed in the noncovered sector. Suppose now that a wage floor is imposed on some sectors of the economy but not others. In the covered sector, the wage is raised by γ%: W C = W O (1 + γ) 3 For ease of presentation, the model is a single-period one, hence uses expected wages instead of expected present values. The multi-period model found in Fields (1975), Mincer (1976), and Gramlich (1976) is more complicated than is needed for present purposes.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 5 where γ = (W C W O ) W O. This lowers employment in the covered sector by ηγ percent, where η is the (arc) wage elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector evaluated between W O and W C : E C = E O C (1 + ηγ) The reduction in employment in the covered sector and the higher wage there will affect the expected wage in that sector. Workers will reallocate themselves such that the expected wages in the two sectors are again equalized. Express the probability of employment in the covered sector as the ratio of covered sector employment (E C ) to covered sector labor force (L C ) including both employed and unemployed; this is a special case of a formulation initiated by Todaro (1969) and used subsequently by Mincer (1976) and Grämlich (1976). Thus E(W C ) = W C (E C L C ) The equilibrium condition (1) becomes W C (E C L C ) = W N The wage in the noncovered sector, W N, adjusts to clear the market, so that the supply of noncovered sector workers and the number demanded in that sector are equal. The total labor force is the sum of the covered and noncovered sector labor forces: L C + L N = L Unemployment (U) is defined as U = L C E C It remains now to close the model by specifying W N. Because our purpose is to show that comparative static results are ambiguous, it suffices to present conditions consistent with the general model under which opposite effects obtain. This can be done using two special cases.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 6 Model I makes a special simplifying assumption: that the wage in the noncovered sector is invariant with respect to the size of that sector s labor force. This simplifying assumption has been made by a number of authors who have extended the Harris-Todaro model including Fields (1975), Anand and Joshi (1979), Heady (1981), Stiglitz (1982), Sah and Stiglitz (1985), and Bell (1991), among others. Thus, Model I is closed by assuming that the wage in the noncovered sector is constant and given by W N (L N ) = W N O = W O Model II makes a different simplifying assumption: that total wages in the noncovered sector do not change with the size of that sector s labor force. This could arise under two circumstances. One is in a classic labor surplus situation of the type modeled by Lewis (1954) and Fei and Ranis (1964), wherein labor in the noncovered sector has zero marginal product, and instead is paid its average product. W N = Q L N Alternatively, suppose labor is not in surplus and the production function is given by Q N = Φ(K N ) ln L N. If K N and P N, the price of the product, are fixed over the relevant range, then the value of the marginal product of labor in the noncovered sector equals P N Φ(K N )/L N. Denoting P N Φ(K N ) by Q and equating the value of marginal product to the wage, we obtain W N = Q/L N which is of the same form as Eq. (9) but derived under alternative circumstances. Model I thus consists of Eqs. (l)-(7) and Eq. (8), Model II of Eqs. (l)-(7) and Eq. (9). We turn now to the comparative static results in these two models.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 7 3. Unemployment in the two-sector model: Comparative static results 3.1. Ambiguous effect of the size of the wage floor (γ) To see the ambiguity, consider Model I. The unemployment rate can be solved for explicitly in this model as U I = γe C O (1 + ηγ) A higher wage floor means higher γ. This lowers unemployment if and only if η < 1 γ. Thus, 2 although a higher wage floor may result in more unemployment, an extremely elastic demand for labor in the covered sector produces the surprising result that a higher wage floor may result in less unemployment. 3.2. Ambiguous effect of the elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector (η) Write unemployment in Model I explicitly as U I = ((W C /W O ) 1)E I C = γe O C (1 + ηγ) O I where E C and E C are, respectively, initial and final employment in the covered sector, γ is the wage increment due to the wage floor, and η is the elasticity of demand for labor in the covered sector. Eq. (11) shows that given γ and E O C, the more negative is η in this model, the less unemployment there will be. The opposite possibility that a more elastic demand for labor might result in more unemployment may be demonstrated using Model II, in which W N = Q/L N. Denote the results for the less elastic demand curve by prime superscripts and the results for the more elastic

Wage Floors and Unemployment 8 O demand by double-primes; W C denotes the common covered sector wage floor. For the less elastic demand, the equilibrium condition (5) becomes W O C (E C /L C ) = Q/L N L C /L N = K, where K = W O C E C /Q Substitution of Eq. (12) into the definition of unemployment yields U = L C E C = (K /(1 + K ))L E C By analogy, U " = L " C E " C = (K " /(1 + K " " )) L E C where K = W O C E " C /Q The difference between the two unemployment amounts is The term (E C E " C ) is positive, because the prime term corresponds to the less elastic labor demand curve, for which employment is greater. Suppose that for certain parameter values, the ratio of the two terms in square brackets in Eq. (13) is less than one. Then the term in curly braces will be negative. In this event, U " > U, i.e., unemployment is greater for the more elastic labor demand curve. The requisite parameter values can be found by establishing conditions under which the denominator in square brackets exceeds the numerator. A sufficient condition for this to hold is simply that E C + E " C > L.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 9 3.3. Ambiguity of the elasticity of the wage in the noncovered sector with respect to the size of that sector's labor force ( ) Eqs. (l)-(7) may be combined to yield W O E O C (1 + γ + ηγ + ηγ 2 ) = W N L C If the term in parentheses is greater than 1, then W N L C must increase as a result of the wage floor. This requires that labor move into the covered sector, by the following reasoning. Suppose L C increases and hence L N falls. When L N falls, W N rises. Therefore, W N L C rises when labor moves into the covered sector. Likewise, if the term in parentheses is less than one, labor must be moving out of the covered sector. For a given wage floor, the term in parentheses will be greater than one if η > 1/(1 + γ) and negative otherwise. That is, any sufficiently elastic demand for labor in the covered sector (where sufficiently elastic means elasticity η > 1/(1 + γ) implies that labor moves out of the covered sector, else labor moves in. The ambiguity of the effects of the elasticity of the wage in the noncovered sector with respect to the size of that sector s labor force may be demonstrated by comparing Models I and II. Model I has constant per capita wage in the noncovered sector and Model II constant total O wage bill in the noncovered sector. For given covered sector wage W C and covered sector employment E O C, the amounts of unemployment are given by U I = ((W O C /W O ) O 1) E C in Model I and U II = L II C E O C = ((L II C /E O C ) 1) E O C = ((W O C /W II N ) 1) E C O = ((W C O /(Q/L N II )) 1) E C O

Wage Floors and Unemployment 10 in Model II. From Eqs. (15) and (16), it is seen that U I >=< U II as W O C <=> W II N, i.e., if in Model II, the wage in the noncovered sector is greater/same/lower than initially. And since, in Model II, the noncovered sector wage is greater/same/lower than initially as the noncovered sector labor force is smaller/same/greater than initially, and since the noncovered sector labor force is smaller/same/greater than initially as the demand for labor in the covered sector is sufficiently inelastic/knife-edge/sufficiently elastic, it follows that U I >=< U II as the demand for labor in the covered sector is sufficiently inelastic/knife- edge/sufficiently elastic. 4. Conclusion The reader should remember that the model used in this paper is a special case of the two-sector models of Mincer (1976) and Gramlich (1976). When ambiguous results are found in a special case of a model, the more general model is necessarily ambiguous as well. The ambiguity of these comparative static results has not been demonstrated previously.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 11 References Anand, Sudhir and Vijay Joshi, 1979, Domestic distortions, income distribution and the theory of optimum subsidy, The Economic Journal, June. Bell, Clive, 1991, Regional heterogeneity, migration, and shadow prices, Journal of Public Economics, Oct. Fei, John C.H. and Gustav Ranis, 1964, Development of the labor surplus economy (Irwin, Homewood, IL). Fields, Gary S., 1975, Rural-urban migration, urban unemployment and underemployment, and job search activity in LDCs, Journal of Development Economics, June. Fields, Gary S., 1989, On-the-job search in a labor market model: Ex ante choices and ex post outcomes, Journal of Development Economics, Jan. Fields, Gary S., 1994, The unemployment effects of minimum wages, International Journal of Manpower 15, nos. 2/3. Gramlich, Edward M., 1976, Impact of minimum wages on other wages, employment, and family incomes, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2. Harberger, Arnold C, 1971, On measuring the social opportunity cost of labour, International Labour Review, June. Harris, John R. and Michael P. Todaro, 1970, Migration, unemployment and development: A two-sector analysis, American Economic Review, March. Heady, Christopher J., 1981, Shadow wages and induced migration, Oxford Economic Papers. Lewis, W. Arthur, 1954, Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor, The Manchester School.

Wage Floors and Unemployment 12 Mincer, Jacob, 1976, Unemployment effects of minimum wage, Part 2, Journal of Political Economy, July/Aug. Mincer, Jacob, 1984, The economics of wage floors, In: R. Ehrenberg, ed., Research in labor economics, Vol. 6 (JAI Press, Greenwich, CT). Sah, Raaj Kumar and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1985, The social cost of labor and project evaluation: A general approach, Journal of Public Economics. Stiglitz, Joseph E., 1982, The structure of labor markets and shadow prices in LDCs, In: Richard H. Sabot, ed., Migration and the labor market in developing countries (Westview Press, Boulder, CO). Todaro, M.P., 1969, A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less developed countries, American Economic Review, March.