EUGINE CONTRIBUTION TO THE EC PUBLIC CONSULTATION ON ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN

Similar documents
COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

We appreciate your feedback

Input to public consultation on ENERGY MARKET DESIGN

Consultation on the Notice on the notion of State aid. A EURELECTRIC response paper

FUTURE-PROOF THE ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN

Delivering the internal market in electricity and making the most of public interventions

CLEAN ENERGY FOR ALL EUROPEANS CLEAN ENERGY FOR ALL EUROPEANS

Generation Adequacy. Generation Adequacy. market measures to secure it and methodology for assessment

ROUNDTABLE OF EUROPEAN ENERGY INDUSTRIALISTS // CONCRETE PROPOSALS FOR THE WINTER PACKAGE AND BEYOND

1. How can Ofgem ensure that sharper Cash Out incentives from the Significant Code Review:

Vattenfall response to: ACER pre-consultation Energy Regulation: a bridge to 2025

Delivering a flexible, resilient and secure market: IOGP response to the proposal on Power Market Design

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

Smart Grids, New Downstream & the New Deal for EU Electricity Consumers

POSITION ON GENERATION ADEQUACY, CAPACITY MECHANISMS AND THE INTERNAL MARKET IN ELECTRICITY

Overview of the financing framework for the German Energiewende

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids

Our position. Corporate power purchasing of renewable energy and the Clean Energy Package

Energy and Environmental State aid Guidelines Frequently asked questions

CEOs OF LEADING EUROPEAN ENERGY COMPANIES CONTRIBUTION TO THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL, MARCH 2014

A European Electricity Market Design Fit for the Energy Transition

Placing competitiveness at the heart of the Energy Package. 7 March, 2017

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION. Final Report of the Sector Inquiry on Capacity Mechanisms. {SWD(2016) 385 final}

THE CLEAN ENERGY PACKAGE State of Play

1. First of all, the CREG analysed the way in which the market operates. Its conclusions are as follows:

The Clean Energy package. Position of the Austrian electricity industry

ACER public consultation on draft Framework Guidelines on Electricity Balancing

Responses to: ACER public consultation on the influence of existing bidding zones on electricity markets

Fortum s policy messages. April 2015

The Internal Energy Market

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids. Retail energy market: Supplementary response to the European Commission s public consultation

TRILOGUE on Market Design Directive and Regulation. CEDEC Key Priorities

Integration of Renewable Energy Sources in the Electricity System - Grid Issues -

Resource Adequacy and Capacity Mechanisms Ágnes Csermely Head of Market Monitoring and Surveillance

15 December Message to the Energy Council meeting on 18 December 2017

Innovative business models making use of the flexibility of the industrial electricity demand for integrating wind energy

About Energy UK. Introduction

Clean Energy for all Europeans

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids

BUSINESSEUROPE S VIEWS ON ELECTRICITY MARKET REGULATION

Energy Regulation: A Bridge to 2025 Conclusions Paper September 2014

ENTSO-E RECOMMENDATIONS TO HELP ACHIEVE EUROPE S ENERGY AND CLIMATE POLICY OBJECTIVES

PHOTOVOLTAIC OBSERVATORY POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS 2011

European transmission tariff structures Cambridge Economic Policy Associates

CLEAN ENERGY PACKAGE

5 key policy asks to ensure that market design proposals within the Clean Energy for all Europeans package deliver a sustainable, affordable and

Introduction: from regulated to liberalized markets in electricity

The EU energy targets leading to 2050, the transition to a low-carbon economy and the role of energy regulation

CLEAN ENERGY FOR ALL EUROPEANS CLEAN ENERGY FOR ALL EUROPEANS

Presentation based on study for IEA RETD

Need for Flex & Capacity

The influence of existing bidding zones on electricity markets

The European Power System in 2030: Flexibility needs & integration benefits

Regulatory challenges in developed markets

CEP Market Design Council General Approach. eurelectric informal input

Capacity mechanisms for improving security of supply: quick fixes or thoughtfully rethinking the way electricity is traded? Prof.

ANEC/BEUC JOINT POSITION CONSUMER EXPECTATIONS ON THE ACTION PLANS ON SUSTAINABLE CONSUMPTION AND PRODUCTION AND ON SUSTAINABLE INDUSTRIAL POLICY

Improving the Electricity Market

European Commission DG Energy Unit B2: Wholesale markets, electricity & gas Office: DM24, 6th floor Rue De Mot 24 B 1049 Brussels/Belgium

ERDF s response to ACER s public pre-consultation on «Energy Regulation: A bridge to 2025»

EU electricity markets: one of a kind?

EUROPEAN COMMISSION Competition DG. Environmental and Energy Aid Guidelines CONSULTATION PAPER

Council of the European Union Brussels, 30 November 2017 (OR. en)

Head Office: 119 Chaussée de Charleroi B Brussels. Tel: Fax:

Energy Storage in EU energy policies

Intermittent power generation: Market implications. IEEE Workshop. Bern, April 28 th 2011

Installed power by end 2015, depending on connection point and technology

EWEA response on the CEER consultation on regulatory aspects of the integration of wind generation in European electricity markets

ACER s Consultation on the draft list of Organised Market Places under REMIT. A EURELECTRIC response paper

Concept note: Energy regulators contribution to fight climate change

ENTSO-E Cross Border Electricity Balancing Pilot Projects

What are the key challenges and obstacles to the development of a European energy policy? - Lessons from the 2020 EU energy strategy

The new energy market design: how the EU can support energy communities and citizens to participate in the energy transition

A New Market Design for the German Electricity Market Local and European Context

Council of the European Union Brussels, 20 December 2017 (OR. en)

Cefic Response to EC Consultation on the Review of Directive 2012/27/EU on Energy Efficiency

Clean Energy for all Europeans

Mergers: Commission clears proposed merger between Telefónica Deutschland (Telefónica) E-Plus subject to conditions-frequently asked questions

ENTSO-E Response to EC public consultation on risk preparedness in the area of security of electricity supply

BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive

Cross-border wholesale markets and network interconnection

Abbreviations Article 1 Article 2 Article 3 Article 4 Article 5 Article 6 Article 7 Article 8 Article 9 Article 10

- Position Paper - Europex reactions to the CEER study on the Future Role of Gas

PÖYRY S VIEW ON MAIN ISSUES FOR PHASE II OF THE REVIEW OF THE SEM HLD 14 October 2013 Gary Keane

Identification pin : Energy regulation : a bridge to 2025 Answers of GDF SUEZ on the ACER preconsultation

Overview of Study Background of Study

Committee on Industry, Research and Energy Committee on the Internal Market and Consumer Protection

Power market challenges and the European Energy Security Strategy

GIE s answer to Public Consultation on the Renewable Energy Strategy

Council of the European Union Brussels, 2 December 2016 (OR. en) Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union

Guidelines for implementation of transitional peak load arrangements. Proposal of Nordel

Corporate Sourcing of Renewable Energy Cillian O Donoghue, Climate & Energy Manager, Eurometaux - European Non-Ferrous Metals Association

IOGP response to the DG Energy "Consultation on an EU strategy for. for liquefied natural gas and gas storage.

Regulating Power Market (RPM) Review Study

Counter activations in PICASSO. Overview of the options and their implications

BRIEF POLICY. Moving the Electricity Transmission System Towards a Decarbonised and Integrated Europe: Missing Pillars and Roadblocks

EU ETS Reform EURELECTRIC Statement on the Impact of Overlapping Policies on the EU ETS. A EURELECTRIC statement

Gas Target Model. Electricity and Gas Interactions Workshop. Keelin O Brien 3 rd July 2014

Transcription:

EUGINE Diamant Building, Boulevard A. Reyers 80 1030 Brussels Belgium Contact Phone Fax E-mail Date Gaëtan Claeys (+32 2) 7 06 82 97 (+32 2) 7 06 82 10 gaetan.claeys@eugine.eu 6 October 2015 EUGINE CONTRIBUTION TO THE EC PUBLIC CONSULTATION ON ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN SHORT-TERM MARKETS 1) Would prices which reflect actual scarcity (in terms of time and location) be an important ingredient to the future market design? Would this also include the need for prices to reflect scarcity of available transmission capacity? Any market reform should focus on supporting the goals of the European energy policy: achieving a power system that is secure, affordable, sustainable and increasingly integrating renewable energy sources. Two different market design options are currently under discussion at EU level: the establishment of Capacity Mechanisms (CM) or the further improvement of the Energy Only Markets (EOM), including prices which reflect actual scarcity. EUGINE would like to highlight that only the further improvement of the energy-only market is a suitable solution, providing the right investment signals and which is compatible with the internal energy market. In a CM, the primary investment signal for new plants is the level and availability of the capacity payment on offer (either through a central procurement mechanism or through a decentralised capacity market). Capacity developers are incentivised to deliver generation technologies that are likely to be awarded a capacity contract, which may not have the flexibility characteristics requested by the market. With a CM in place, a pre-determined capacity margin is procured on a regular basis and investment cycles are thus absent from reading changes in the energy market price. Moreover, CM are often a highly-administrative, complex and costly option like in Spain where retail prices have been quickly and strongly increasing due to the system of capacity payments in place. Finally, CM established at a national level tend to focus only on the national capacity available and by this restrict cross-border trade in electricity and hinder the whole internal energy market. EUGINE Transparency Register ID number 033807913798-84 www.eugine.eu European Engine Power Plants Association President Kari Hietanen Secretary General Ralf Wezel Brussels Office Diamant Building Boulevard A. Reyers 80 1030 Brussels, Belgium Phone +32 (0)2 706-8297 Fax +32 (0)2 706-8210 gaetan.claeys@eugine.eu Head Office Lyoner Str. 18 60528 Frankfurt am Main Germany Phone +49 (0)69 6603-1936 Fax +49 (0)69 6603-2936 info@eugine.eu

In an EOM the marginal plant receives a contribution for recovery of its fixed and capital costs when supplies are scarce. Supplies can be scarce across different timeframes, including in the spot markets, which means that providers of energy in these markets should be able to offer prices above their short run marginal costs if there are few flexible providers of energy left in these timeframes. This acts as a signal for the new entry of flexible plants. In an EOM, expectations of average energy prices (affected by spikes in short term prices) would be to rise as capacity exits the market as part of the normal investment cycle. Of course, freely fluctuating prices on the wholesale market (no price caps, so higher prices in times of scarcity) send an economic signal to the market to develop new capacity, and so the cycle starts again. In addition to freely fluctuating prices on the wholesale market (which does not necessarily have an impact on the retail market), the EOM should empower market participants to reduce imbalances: balancing responsibility applying to them all, costreflective imbalance charges and marginal balancing energy prices would create very strong incentives for a balanced energy system with a very high level of security of supply. The third energy package of the EU achieved a very successful liberalisation of the European energy market. We believe an improved EOM with prices reflecting actual scarcity and proper balancing arrangements is a further market-based reform of the electricity arrangements, required to prepare the market for the future generation portfolio, leading to a competitive and functioning energy market where any distorting effects are eliminated. However, if existing CM are kept in the system or new CM are set-up in the future, the European Union should adopt a set of minimum requirements minimising their potential negative impact on the internal energy market: any CM should be market-based, be open for cross-border participation, solve proven problems related to the security of supply, value flexibility solutions and be a temporary scheme. 2) Which challenges and opportunities could arise from prices which reflect actual scarcity? How can the challenges be addressed? Could these prices make capacity mechanisms redundant? Prices which reflect actual scarcity on the wholesale market and proper balancing arrangements would definitely help fix the energy-only market, re-create incentives for investments and thus foster flexibility solutions in the EU power system. These measures are a prerequisite to a strong and sustainable EU energy system. The joint declaration for regional cooperation on security of electricity supply in the framework of the internal energy market, 12 electricity neighbours (10 EU Member - 2 -

States and 2 neighbouring countries) stated on 8 June 2015: we will allow flexible prices; we will particularly not introduce legal price caps and we will avoid that national measures have the effect of indirect price caps. This is a proof that prices which reflect actual scarcity are already becoming a reality and that decision-makers in member states are aware of the fact that advantages clearly outweigh potential disadvantages. Prices which reflect actual scarcity and proper balancing arrangements would probably make capacity mechanisms useless because all market players would be incentivised to provide the right type and quantity of capacity for the system. The German government recently decided to further improve the Energy-Only Market (EOM 2.0), not to introduce a capacity market, but to set-up a less-distortive additional mechanism: a capacity reserve with specific capacities kept outside of the market. This move shows that a country with a high share of variable renewables in its energymix does not necessarily need a fully-fledge, complex and costly market mechanism to ensure security of supply: an improved EOM is the best way to create the right incentives and to strengthen the internal energy market. If the EU wants to secure properly functioning electricity markets with clear price signals, electricity markets should be protected from distortive effects of often poorly designed national capacity remuneration mechanisms locking Europe into old and polluting power plants. The EU should rather adopt common standards for adequacy assessment and restrictive criteria for capacity remuneration mechanisms to avoid that diverging national mechanisms question the whole EU energy policy. A solution might be to restrict the establishment of such state aid mechanisms to only so-called strategic reserves, for specific emergency cases and a limited time. As long as it is ensured that such capacities are kept outside the regular market, strategic reserves might be the less distortive option and a useful solution in case of sensible fears of market failure. As such strategic reserves are intended to be used as a measure of last resort, also the strategic reserve capacity needs to be flexible enough to react in a fast manner when required. 3) Progress in aligning the fragmented balancing markets remains slow; should the EU try to accelerate the process, if need be through legal measures? The upcoming network code on electricity balancing should play a major role in developing and integrating balancing markets at regional and then EU level. In principle, EUGINE would like to see this network code adopted and implemented - 3 -

rapidly. However, it is even more important that this regulation is perfectly drafted to ensure a proper functioning of the EU balancing system. On the one hand EUGINE welcomes the relatively clear message contained in the draft network code on electricity balancing regarding the upcoming proposed pricing method which shall be based on marginal pricing (pay-as-cleared), unless [ ]. (article 42 of the version recommended by ACER to the European Commission on 20 July 2015). On the other hand, EUGINE regrets the confusing wording on price caps: Balancing Energy prices shall not be capped. In case TSOs identify that caps are needed for consistency with other market timeframes, they may develop within a proposal for harmonised pricing method for Balancing Energy a proposal for harmonised maximum and minimum Balancing Energy prices to be applied in all control areas. [ ] (article 42). Furthermore, EUGINE stresses that the key principles of balancing responsibility for all market participants (including producers of electricity from renewable energy sources) and cost-reflective imbalance charges should have been applied at EU level and be enshrined in this regulation to develop real incentives for flexibility investments and security of supply. EUGINE believes that the three aforementioned issues should still be solved by the European Commission before adopting the network code on electricity balancing. To sum up, EUGINE pleads for both a correction and an acceleration of the integration process of balancing markets. 4) What can be done to provide for the smooth implementation of the agreed EU-wide intraday platform? The cross-border intraday (XBID) solution will help market participants trade electricity across borders close to gate closure and balance their own positions. This will ease the integration of increasing shares of electricity generated from variable renewable energy sources. However, EUGINE would like to stress that cross-border interconnection capacities are a precondition to making the cross-border intraday project a reality. In this respect, EUGINE pleads for a balanced approach: in order to keep the costs to a minimum level, only cost-efficient interconnection projects should be financed, based on a solid cost-benefit analyses. - 4 -

LONG-TERM MARKETS TO ENABLE INVESTMENTS 5) Are long-term contracts between generators and consumers required to provide investment certainty for new generation capacity? What barriers, if any, prevent such long-term hedging products from emerging? Is there any role for the public sector in enabling markets for long term contracts? EUGINE would like to distinguish two different types of long-term contracts: simple hedging contracts on the one hand and compulsory long-term contracts between suppliers and generators on the other hand. On the one hand, EUGINE fully supports hedging contracts as described in the consultative communication on the energy market design: Market participants, including renewables producers, should be able to hedge against price volatilities and volume risks translating the uncertainties connected to price peaks into planned and secure revenue. EUGINE believes that such hedging contracts (like the EEX hedging product named Cap Futures ) are key to reduce uncertainties for the market players, to decrease imbalances in the system and to foster investments in flexibility solutions. They represent an essential building block of an improved EOM. However, market players should be free to make use or not of such contracts. On the other hand, EUGINE has not been convinced so far by the Latin-American examples of markets for long-term contracts where suppliers are required to cover their forecasted demand through long-term contracts, as described in the recent document published by the European Commission on investment perspectives in electricity markets. For example the Brazilian system has not been very successful so far. For EUGINE, such markets seem to be quite similar to capacity markets and might have also the same drawbacks. Therefore, EUGINE pleads for the quick development of simple long-term hedging products to be used by the market participants willing to do so. This principle should be supported and fostered by the European Commission and the national authorities concerned. 6) To what extent do you think that the divergence of taxes and charges 1 levied on electricity in different Member States creates distortions in terms of directing investments efficiently or hamper the free flow of energy? 1 These may be part of general taxation (VAT, excise duties) or specific levies to support targeted energy and/or climate policies. - 5 -

RENEWABLE GENERATION 7) What needs to be done to allow investment in renewables to be increasingly driven by market signals? The Guidelines on State aid for environmental protection and energy 2014-2020 are an essential tool paving the way to the integration of renewables in the market. EUGINE highly supports the principle enshrined in these guidelines that for energy from renewable sources subsidies and exemptions from balancing responsibilities should be phased out in a digressive way. It is of utmost importance to ensure as of 1 January 2016 the proper and harmonised application of the concrete provisions of these guidelines (premiums instead of feed-in tariffs, balancing responsibility for all, no electricity generation under negative prices). In parallel, the EU emission trading scheme (ETS) needs to be further reinforced to deliver strong signals for investments in low-carbon technologies, including power production from renewable energy sources and gas technologies. The adoption of the Market Stability Reserve is a step forward. Now, EUGINE supports a very ambitious long-term reform for the post-2020 period. A strong ETS would foster investments in renewables on the long run and would progressively make costly national support schemes useless. 8) Which obstacles, if any, would you see to fully integrating renewable energy generators into the market, including into the balancing and intraday markets, as well as regarding dispatch based on the merit order? EUGINE believes in a technology neutral approach of the European energy policy. As technologies using renewable energy sources are progressively becoming mature technologies, they should be gradually benefitting from the same rights and duties as the other technologies. For example, the principle of balancing responsibility for all market participants (including RES producers) is already successfully applied in several EU Member States and should be extended to all EU countries. There is no reason to further exempt certain mature RES technologies from general rules applying to the other technologies. 9) Should there be a more coordinated approach across Member States for renewables support schemes? What are the main barriers to regional support schemes and how could these barriers be removed (e.g. through legislation)? - 6 -

DEMAND RESPONSE 10) Where do you see the main obstacles that should be tackled to kick-start demandresponse (e.g. insufficient flexible prices, (regulatory) barriers for aggregators / customers, lack of access to smart home technologies, no obligation to offer the possibility for end customers to participate in the balancing market through a demand response scheme, etc.)? Apart from specific technical or financial problems, the main obstacle to the development of demand-response may be the same as for the other flexibility solutions: it is twofold, the lack of technology-neutral incentives to invest in flexibility solutions in the EU energy system on the one hand and the establishment of marketdistortive Capacity Mechanisms in various EU Member States on the other hand. As a consequence, the EU should rapidly adopt a legislation defining restrictive criteria for Capacity Mechanisms and empowering all market participants to reduce their imbalances and to directly or indirectly (contracts with other market participants) invest in flexibility solutions. COOPERATION BETWEEN SYSTEM OPERATORS 11) While electricity markets are coupled within the EU and linked to its neighbours, system operation is still carried out by national Transmission System Operators (TSOs). Regional Security Coordination Initiatives ("RSCIs") such as CORESO or TSC have a purely advisory role today. Should the RSCIs be gradually strengthened also including decision making responsibilities when necessary? Is the current national responsibility for system security an obstacle to cross-border cooperation? Would a regional responsibility for system security be better suited to the realities of the integrated market? ADAPTING THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK 12) Fragmented national regulatory oversight seems to be inefficient for harmonised parts of the electricity system (e.g. market coupling). Would you see benefits in strengthening ACER's role? - 7 -

13) Would you see benefits in strengthening the role of the ENTSOs? How could this best be achieved? What regulatory oversight is needed? 14) How should governance rules for distribution system operators and access to metering data be adapted (data handling and ensuring data privacy etc.) in light of market and technological developments? Are additional provisions on management of and access by the relevant parties (end-customers, distribution system operators, transmission system operators, suppliers, third party service providers and regulators) to the metering data required? 15) Shall there be a European approach to distribution tariffs? If yes, what aspects should be covered; for example framework, tariff components (fixed, capacity vs. energy, timely or locational differentiation) and treatment of own generation? 16) As power exchanges are an integral part of market coupling should governance rules for power exchanges be considered? EUROPEAN DIMENSION TO SECURITY OF SUPPLY 17) Is there a need for a harmonised methodology to assess power system adequacy? Yes, the past has shown that EU Member States are considering diverse criteria and objectives when assessing the adequacy of their power systems. At a time when national energy policies are more and more interdependent on one side and interlinked with the overall EU energy policy on the other side, such moves should be coordinated through the adoption of a harmonised methodology. This harmonised methodology should not only focus on the calculation method for available capacities but also on the definition of the required capacity, i.e. on the specific type of capacities which will be needed in the short-to-long term. As the share of variable renewable energy sources is growing in the EU energy mix, the EU and its Member States should focus on securing enough highly flexible back-up capacities (quick start-up and ramp-up times) rather than on relatively old-fashioned baseload capacities which will not be able to quickly react to sudden increases and decreases in electricity production by solar and wind power sources. - 8 -

EUGINE is pleased that the joint declaration for regional cooperation on security of electricity supply in the framework of the internal energy market of 8 June 2015 states that the twelve countries concerned will develop a common methodology to assess generation adequacy and will work towards further harmonisation of security of supply indicators and a common understanding of security of supply as well as towards a joint regional generation adequacy assessment, to complement the work carried out at national level. This is a very important step in the right direction. 18) What would be the appropriate geographic scope of a harmonised adequacy methodology and assessment (e.g. EU-wide, regional or national as well as neighbouring countries)? If the EU wants to increase the efficiency of its energy system, reduce costs and protect smaller Member States from the effects of national support schemes set-up by bigger Member States, a European approach may be the best option for a harmonised adequacy methodology and assessment. However, taking into account the existing diverging national adequacy systems, a two-steps approach may be considered as well: a regionalisation and then a Europeanisation of the existing adequacy systems. 19) Would an alignment of the currently different system adequacy standards across the EU be useful to build an efficient single market? Yes, common system adequacy standards across the EU would be a more efficient solution because capacities installed behind the borders would be taken into account and distortive state aids may be considered as useless and be reduced within the internal energy market. 20) Would there be a benefit in a common European framework for cross-border participation in capacity mechanisms? If yes, what should be the elements of such a framework? Would there be benefit in providing reference models for capacity mechanisms? If so, what should they look like? - 9 -

21) Should the decision to introduce capacity mechanisms be based on a harmonised methodology to assess power system adequacy? Yes, EU Member States planning to establish a Capacity Mechanism should first demonstrate that there is an adequacy issue and that cross-border trade as well as the further improvement of the energy-only market could not solve this problem. To avoid undistorted competition within the internal energy market, such a demonstration should be based on a harmonised methodology to assess power system adequacy. As aforementioned, this harmonised methodology, should not only focus on the capacity calculation methods but also on the capacity capabilities which should be available on the market to ensure a high level of electricity security of supply. - 10 -