An Empirical Analysis of Spatial Arbitrage: Examining Arbitrageur Behavior and the. Effect of Electronic Commerce

Similar documents
DOES ELECTRONIC TRADING IMPROVE MARKET EFFICIENCY? EVIDENCE FROM SPATIAL ARBITRAGE IN THE AUTOMOTIVE MARKET

Electronic and Physical Market Channels: A Multi-Year Investigation in a Market for Products of Uncertain Quality

Electronic and Physical Market Channels: A Multi-Year Investigation in a Market for Products of Uncertain Quality

Chapter 2 E-Marketplaces: Structure, Mechanisms, Economics, and Impacts

Chapter 21. channels of distribution. Section 21.1 Distribution. Section 21.2 Distribution Planning

University of Benghazi Faculty of Information Technology. E-Commerce and E-Marketing (IS475) Instructor: Nasser M. AMAITIK (MSc IBSE) Lecture 02

A General Model of E-Government service Adoption: Empirical Exploration

Chapter 2. E-Marketplaces: Structures, Mechanisms, Economics, and Impacts

CHAPTER 2. Presented By: Raghda Essam Dina El-Haddad Samar El-Haddad Menna Hatem. E-Marketplaces: Structures, Mechanisms and Impacts

Definitive Guide to Sourcing More Profitable Wholesale Vehicles

Low-quality, low-trust and lowadoption: Saharan Africa. Jakob Svensson IIES, Stockholm University

Competitive Markets. Jeffrey Ely. January 13, This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License.

Electronic Animal Identification Systems at Livestock Auction Markets

SUSTAINABLE REVERSE LOGISTICS

Explaining Price Dispersion in the Manhattan Beer Market: Information Acquisition, Geographic Distribution and Searching under the Influence

Feature Kelley Blue Book Values in Your Selling Process

Competition and Fraud in Online Advertising Markets

THE RULE OF THIRDS. by John Schnitzler. Changing the way the world markets and sells

AutoCheck Score SM. does a number on traditional vehicle history reports. White paper

Income Distribution Comparison of Farms With Innovative Activities: A Probabilistic Approach

Generative Models for Networks and Applications to E-Commerce

Reserve Prices, Stumpage Fees, and Efficiency

MGT301 Solved 3 rd Quiz solved By Cuter Killer and Masood Khan June 2011

Evaluating Pricing Strategy Using ecommerce Data: Evidence and Estimation Challenges. October 15, 2005

Full file at

Drivers of the Cash Conversion Cycle in Retail: a Test of Resource Dependency Theory

Building Market Linkages for Smallholder Farmers in Uganda. Lauren Falcao and Paul Gertler, UCB Craig McIntosh, UCSD

Real Estate Appraisal

Does banking relationship configuration affect the risk-taking behavior of French SMEs?

How Hyundai changed course to improve the customer journey

Adaptive Mechanism Design: A Metalearning Approach

Japan's Wholesale Sector Gets a Facelift

Analysis of Herding on the Internet An Empirical Investigation of Online Software Download

Advanced B2B Procurement on the Internet

Benin Indicator Survey Data Set

Improving Urban Mobility Through Urban Analytics Using Electronic Smart Card Data

Designing Full Potential Transportation Networks

Chapter 1. Overview of Electronic Commerce

UNDERSTANDING E-BUSINESS AND E- COMMERCE I

Chapter 12 Marketing Channels and Supply Chain Management

DRIVING INDIRECT CHANNEL SUCCESS

Marketing Channels: Delivering Customer Value Chapter 12 BUS 101 WEEK 7

Identifying Neighborhood Eects among Firms: Evidence from the Location Lotteries of the Tokyo Tsukiji Fish Market

How Physical Retail Channels Impact Customers Online Purchase Behavior?

Testing the Signaling Theory of Advertising: Evidence from Search Advertisements

I ll start with a story in the high-school physics: the story about Isaac Newton s Law of Universal Gravitation.

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage

WTO Business FOcus GrOup 1 MsMes and e-commerce Final report September 2016

Lecture 13 - Price Discrimination

WHITE PAPER. Results Delivers Value

CHAPTER 5 SOCIAL WELFARE MAXIMIZATION FOR HYBRID MARKET

Behavioral Biases in Auctions: an Experimental Study $

B2B Customer Surveys. Unique Aspects of B2B Marketing and Research

TDWI strives to provide course books that are contentrich and that serve as useful reference documents after a class has ended.

Transfer Pricing. 2. Advantages and Disadvantages of Decentralization

The process of updating the sample for the Swedish Producer and Import Price Indices

ICT, Innovation, and Productivity Growth Connect or Disconnect

Online Price Dispersion: An International Comparison

Purchasing Power Case Study Finding solutions for fleet parts programs

VALUE OF SHARING DATA

PART 3.4 DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION AND WORKS USE OF GOVERNMENT VEHICLES

Impacts Consumer Demand

Why Fishbowl Manufacturing and Fishbowl Warehouse Are #1 Among QuickBooks Users

DATA AND THE ELECTRICITY GRID A ROADMAP FOR USING SYSTEM DATA TO BUILD A PLUG & PLAY GRID

Bargaining in technology markets: An empirical study of biotechnology alliances

Exam #2 (100 Points Total) Answer Key

NAMA NEWS MARCH Dear Colleagues

welcome packet Version

ONLINE RETAIL MARKETING

MIS 300 Exam 1 Spring 2011

Mobile Inventory Management

Are you Capitalizing on the New Automotive Shopper Journey?

Measuring online impact on offline conversations

Experienced Bidders in Online Second-Price Auctions

CHAPTER 3 MARKET INSTITUTIONS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

Whitepaper Series Cross-Docking Trends Report Secondary Packaging Outsourcing Report

Chapter 5. Understanding Organizational Markets and Buying Behavior. Copyright 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

REDESIGNING BITCOIN S FEE MARKET arxiv:

Unit 6 Retailing Key Vocabulary

HEADER BIDDING: A BYTE-SIZED OVERVIEW

The San Gorgonio Pass Business Survey 2010

Global Supply Chains Step by Step: How to Develop

Robust Multi-unit Auction Protocol against False-name Bids

Chapter 12 Textbook Summary Notes Marketing Channels Delivering Customer Value

The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs

Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure

MIDDLE MARKET M&A OUTLOOK 2018

When designing price contracts, one of the major questions confronting managers is how many blocks there

Unravelling Airbnb Predicting Price for New Listing

Cambridge David Newbery Richard Green Karsten Neuhoff Paul Twomey

Memorandum Issue Date September 2012

Chapter 1. The Demand for Audit and Other Assurance Services

Effects of the monitors distribution channel on the process of dumping in Tehran market with a new solution to improve the channel

Optimize Your Incentive Strategy

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

OPTIMIZING GOOGLE SHOPPING: STRUCTURE. Taking a closer look at optimizing Google Shopping and how it is structured

Ebusiness: A Canadian Perspective for a Networked World, 4e Chapter 2 Internet Business Models and Strategies

FORECASTING & REPLENISHMENT

Predictive Planning for Supply Chain Management

Transcription:

An Empirical Analysis of Spatial Arbitrage: Examining Arbitrageur Behavior and the Effect of Electronic Commerce By: Hemang Subramanian and Eric Overby, Scheller College of Business, Georgia Institute of Technology Abstract: Arbitrage plays a fundamental role in economic theory such as the law of one price and the efficient markets hypothesis, yet we know alarmingly little about it empirically. This is because the coarseness of most available data makes arbitrage transactions difficult to observe. As a result, we know very little about how arbitrageurs behave or how market innovations such as electronic trading affect arbitrage activity. We overcome this by using highly granular data from the wholesale used vehicle industry from 2003 to 2010, with which we can observe spatial arbitrage at a transaction level with a high degree of precision. We find that arbitrageurs choose where to source products based on (among other factors) geographic location and density and the degree to which the potential source location is wired for electronic trading. We also use the prevalence of spatial arbitrage to measure how the diffusion of electronic trading affects market integration/efficiency. This measure has many advantages over the price-based measures used in prior research on electronic commerce and market efficiency. We study the effect of two distinct forms of electronic trading. We conclude that electronic trading facilitates better buyer/seller matching across geographic space, thereby disintermediating the arbitrageur middleman and improving market integration/efficiency. This shows how information technology can improve market function by helping balance supply and demand. 1

2

1 Introduction Arbitrage is a key mechanism in many fundamental economic theories such as the law of one price and the efficient markets hypothesis. If markets are inefficient, then theory suggests that arbitrageurs will exploit the inefficiencies by purchasing in low-priced markets and reselling in high-priced markets. In this way, arbitrageurs are the key agents who keep markets efficient by rebalancing supply and demand. However, there is surprisingly little empirical evidence about arbitrage, which is alarming given arbitrage s central place in theory. A traditional limiting factor in empirical examination of arbitrage is that arbitrage transactions are difficult to observe: a researcher must be able to observe a trader i who purchases an item in market j and then resells the same item in market k. This requires unique trader and item-level identifiers that are consistent across different markets. Because such data are elusive, there are many largely unanswered questions about arbitrage, including how arbitrageurs behave and how market innovations such as electronic trading affect arbitrage activity. We overcome this by using highly granular data to study a specific type of arbitrage. Spatial arbitrage is the purchase and subsequent resale of the same product in different geographic locations in order to exploit a price discrepancy (Coleman 2009). 1 Spatial arbitrage occurs in many product markets, including those for agricultural goods, metals, vehicles, and heavy equipment. Our data permit us to identify instances of spatial arbitrage with a high degree of precision, allowing us to pose the following research questions about arbitrageur behavior and overall arbitrage activity. First, how do arbitrageurs choose where to source products for arbitrage? Second, how does the diffusion of electronic commerce affect arbitrage activity? The first question is important because many theoretical predictions about arbitrage are largely 1 To limit definitional confusion, we do not consider instances in which buyers (sellers) eschew buying (selling) at one location in favor of another because of price differences, to be arbitrage. This is because arbitrage, as we define it, requires both a purchase and a sale. 3

untested. Despite a maintained belief that arbitrageurs behavior helps keep markets efficient, we simply don t know much about how arbitrageurs behave. The second question is important because electronic commerce has the potential to improve how markets function by improving the efficiency of buyer/seller matching. As discussed below, observing spatial arbitrage activities is a powerful way to measure whether this is occurring, because a high level of arbitrage activity would suggest relatively poor buyer-seller matching (and thereby low efficiency). We study these questions in the context of the wholesale used vehicle market, where we track the trading history of each vehicle based on its unique Vehicle Identification Number (VIN). Our data also contain unique and consistent identifiers for the traders and market locations. This allows us to observe instances in which a trader i engages in spatial arbitrage by buying a vehicle at a source location j for price p and then quickly reselling the same vehicle at a different destination location k for a higher price p. Another advantage of studying spatial arbitrage in this context is that this market has recently adopted two distinct electronic trading mechanisms: a) a webcast channel that allows electronic access to the traditional physical market, and b) a stand-alone electronic market in the form of an online store. We study both mechanisms, which has the following advantages. First, we can examine differential effects of different types of electronic trading. This contributes to the growing body of research that recognizes that not all forms of electronic commerce are the same, including research that has examined differences between electronic commerce via mobile phones vs. PCs (Ghose et al. 2013). Second, the different electronic channels permit a nuanced understanding of how electronic commerce influences spatial arbitrage. On one hand, electronic commerce might decrease the prevalence of spatial arbitrage by helping buyers and sellers trade with each other across geographic space directly, thereby eliminating the arbitrageur middleman. On the other hand, electronic commerce 4

might also increase the prevalence of spatial arbitrage by helping arbitrageurs identify mispriced products that can be profitably arbitraged. Analyzing both channels helps us disentangle these two possibilities to some extent. We use discrete choice methods to analyze where arbitrageurs choose to source products. Our results indicate that arbitrageurs base this decision on (among other things) the likelihood of finding underpriced vehicles, geographic location and density, and the degree to which the potential source location is wired for electronic trading. These results document novel findings about arbitrageur behavior and show that arbitrageurs tend to avoid source locations at which electronic trading is prevalent. We extend this latter result by leveraging the phased implementation of electronic trading across the market to conduct natural experiments to examine the effect of the electronic channels on spatial arbitrage. We find that the webcast channel reduces spatial arbitrage by helping buyers and sellers trade with each other directly, thereby disintermediating arbitrageurs. The standalone electronic market may have a similar effect, but its design also helps arbitrageurs identify mispriced vehicles to arbitrage, and we find that this market actually fosters spatial arbitrage. Overall, the webcast effect dominates, such that increasing levels of electronic trading have led to an overall decrease in spatial arbitrage. The decrease in spatial arbitrage reflects an overall increase in market integration / efficiency. The paper proceeds as follows. In section 2, we review prior research on spatial arbitrage, market integration/efficiency, and electronic commerce. In section 3, we describe the empirical setting, and we develop our hypotheses in section 4. In section 5, we present our analyses and results. In section 6, we summarize our results and discuss implications and limitations. 2 Prior literature 5

In this section, we review two streams of literature that relate to our research questions about arbitrageur behavior and the effect of electronic commerce on spatial arbitrage. The first stream is the empirical research on spatial arbitrage, and the second stream is the effect of electronic commerce on market integration/efficiency. 2.1 Empirical evidence of spatial arbitrage activities and behaviors There is relatively little empirical evidence of spatial arbitrage activity (or of any other type of arbitrage activity) at a transaction-level. There are two main reasons for this. First, because spatial arbitrage happens relatively infrequently and constitutes a small fraction of the total trade volume in any market, empirical analysis of spatial arbitrage requires very large datasets (Sephton 2003; Tostão and Brorsen 2005). Second, observation of spatial arbitrage also requires unique (and consistent) identifiers for individual products, traders, and locations so that the trading history of products can be tracked (Alderman 1993; McNew 1996). Because these data are often unavailable, scholars have turned to price-based measures such as price dispersion and co-movement of price time series across locations to study spatial arbitrage (Alexander and Wyeth 1994; McNew 1996; Ravallion 1986). One drawback to these alternative approaches is that they do not permit examination of arbitrage activity or arbitrageur behaviors. One of the contributions of our research is that our data permit an examination of arbitrageur behaviors, and we focus specifically on how arbitrageurs choose where to source products. 2.2 The effect of electronic commerce on spatial arbitrage and market integration / efficiency To frame the literature review on how electronic commerce affects spatial arbitrage and why this is important, we first discuss spatial market integration. Spatially integrated markets are those in which buyers and sellers can easily trade across geographic space with minimal friction caused by informational, infrastructural, or regulatory barriers. If markets are well-integrated 6

spatially, then goods can move easily from geographic regions with abundant supply to regions of scarcity. If markets are not well-integrated, then prices for scarce goods may rise dramatically in regions experiencing high demand, creating hardship in those regions. Similarly, if a seller is unable to reach buyers in geographically remote regions, then a technological innovation that boosts her production may simply create excess supply in her local region, leading to price drops that may negate potential gains and discourage innovation. Given the importance of wellintegrated markets, measuring market integration and assessing what factors foster or inhibit it are important social science research topics (Baulch 1997). Electronic commerce has the potential to foster market integration by increasing the visibility of price information and by facilitating trade across regions, thereby helping buyers and sellers distribute demand and supply efficiently. However, it has been challenging to determine the effect of electronic commerce (or of any other IT-based innovation) on market integration because of difficulty measuring the degree to which a market is integrated. As alluded to above, scholars have measured market integration using price-based measures such as geographic price dispersion and the co-movement of prices at different locations over time (Aker 2010; Jensen 2007). These methods are not optimal because: a) they may not properly consider the transaction costs of trading across geographic distance, and b) they may be inaccurate due to unobserved product quality differences across locations (Badiane and Shively 1998; Barrett 2008; Goletti and Babu 1994). To overcome these limitations, we use a different measure of market integration: the prevalence of spatial arbitrage. Spatial arbitrage should be rare in well-integrated markets, because buyers (sellers) can shift demand (supply) to low-priced (high-priced) locations directly, thereby eliminating the need for arbitrageurs to serve as middlemen. By contrast, if markets 7

are not well-integrated, then spatial arbitrage opportunities will abound. Indeed, spatial arbitrage has been considered prima facie evidence for a lack of market integration (Baulch 1997). The prevalence of spatial arbitrage is a useful measure of a market s integration for three reasons. First, it is based on the micro-level behavior of the traders (the arbitrageurs) who are most aware of supply/demand imbalances that signal a lack of market integration. Second, it implicitly accounts for the transaction costs of trading across distance, because there would be no arbitrage if these costs were higher than the potential arbitrage profits. Third, it is immune to potential quality differences across products, because the same product is traded in both locations. Spatial market integration is similar to market efficiency, although the former is arguably the more precise term when the geography of a market is considered. Several scholars have examined how electronic commerce affects market efficiency. In general, these studies examine price dispersion to measure whether supply and demand are distributed efficiently within a market (Brynjolfsson and Smith 2000; Chellappa et al. 2011; Clemons et al. 2002; Ghose and Yao 2011). Several studies conduct cross-channel comparisons to assess whether price dispersion is lower online than in brick and mortar stores (Brown and Goolsbee 2002; Brynjolfsson et al. 2009; Ellison and Ellison 2006). A popular motivation for these comparisons is that because electronic commerce reduces search costs, it will lead to more efficient distribution of supply and demand, causing price dispersion to be lower online than offline (Bakos 1997; Bakos 1998). Empirical support for this is mixed (Baye and Morgan 2001) although several studies focused on geographic trading show that electronic trading has led to reduced price dispersion(aker 2010; Jensen 2007; Overby and Forman 2009). We extend this research in two ways. First, we study how electronic commerce affects spatial arbitrage rather than price dispersion, which has several advantages discussed above. Second, we 8

examine the effects of two distinct types of electronic commerce: a) a webcast channel that permits electronic access to the traditional physical market, and b) a stand-alone electronic market. This allows us to explore the differential effects of different types of electronic channels, which is important because not all forms of electronic commerce are the same. It also helps us disentangle whether a change in spatial arbitrage attributable to electronic commerce reflects a change in market integration or simply a change in arbitrageurs ability to exploit a given level of market non-integration. 3 Empirical Context The empirical context for our study is the U.S. wholesale used vehicle market. Buyers in this market are used vehicle dealers who use the market as a primary source of inventory for their retail lots. Sellers are of two types: a) used vehicle dealers who use the market to sell vehicles that they cannot (or choose not to) sell retail, and b) institutional sellers such as rental car firms who use the market to sell vehicles retired from their fleets. Data were provided by an intermediary in the market that facilitates trades between buyers and sellers. The intermediary operates over 80 physical market facilities in the U.S. as well as the webcast channel and standalone electronic market alluded to above and described below. The data consist of 40,657,724 successful transactions facilitated by the intermediary from Jan 1 st 2003 to Dec 31 st 2010. There were 34,510,905 unique vehicles traded in the sample, as some vehicles were traded more than once. Traditionally, the U.S. wholesale used vehicle market has functioned as a physical market in which buyers, sellers, and vehicles are collocated at market facilities. Each facility has a large parking lot for vehicle storage and a warehouse-type building equipped with multiple lanes, which are essentially one-way streets. Transactions occur as follows. Vehicles are driven down a lane one at a time where buyers interested in that vehicle will have gathered. A human 9

auctioneer solicits bids for each vehicle and awards the vehicle to the highest bidder, assuming he meets the seller s reserve price. This process takes 30-45 seconds, after which another vehicle is auctioned. It is common for vehicles to be auctioned in multiple lanes at the same facility concurrently. Approximately 10 years ago, the intermediary who operates these facilities began simulcasting via the Internet the physical auctions as they were occurring at the facilities. This allows buyers to experience the live audio and video of the auctions via an Internet browser, and it also permits them to bid on vehicles in competition with the buyers who are physically collocated at the facility. As such, this webcast channel provides buyers with electronic access to the auctions occurring in the physical market. The webcast channel was implemented in phases. This is because implementing the channel required that camera, microphone, and other equipment be implemented in each lane at each facility. 2 This means that we observe many instances in which highly similar vehicles were auctioned at the same facility on the same day, some in lanes that were equipped for webcast and some in lanes that were not. As discussed below, we leverage this in a natural experiment to assess the effect of the webcast channel on transaction outcomes, including the probability that a purchased vehicle is later arbitraged. The left panel of Figure 1 shows how the percentage of vehicles sold at physical auctions available via webcast increased as the channel was deployed. 2 We estimated the implementation date for each lane/facility combination (i.e., lane 1 in Houston, lane 2 in Houston, etc.) as follows. The data denote whether a vehicle sold in the physical market was purchased by a buyer using the traditional physical channel or the webcast channel. For each lane/facility combination, we recorded the date of the first webcast purchase and used that as the webcast implementation date for that lane/facility. We considered all vehicles offered in that lane/facility from that date forward to be available via webcast. We used this: a) to measure the percentage of vehicles offered at each facility that were available via webcast on day t, and b) to determine whether any given vehicle was available via webcast. Because there could be a lag between webcast implementation and the date of the first webcast transaction for a lane, we reran our analysis after adjusting the webcast implementation date by subtracting 1 week, 3 weeks, and 6 weeks. This does not affect our results. 10

The intermediary also operates a stand-alone electronic market that functions similar to ebay. In this market, sellers post listings of their vehicles, and buyers have the option to purchase them for a fixed Buy Now price or to bid for them. It is important to note that sellers choose to offer a vehicle either: a) at a physical market facility, where the vehicle is available to buyers present at that facility and to buyers accessing that facility via webcast (if enabled), or b) in the standalone electronic market, where the vehicle is available to buyers who use the stand-alone electronic market. Variables are described in Table 1. Table 1. Description of variables in the dataset Variable name Description Descriptive statistics (mean, Std dev) facilityid Denotes the facility at which the vehicle was located. - facilityzip Zip code corresponding to the facility. - traderid A unique identifier for the trader. The same ID is used regardless of whether the trader is the buyer - or seller in a transaction. buyerzip Zip code corresponding to the buyer s location. (Zip codes are not always recorded for the seller s - location.) SaleDate Date of sale of the vehicle. - VIN The vehicle s unique Vehicle Identification Number (VIN). - vehiclemake The make of the vehicle, e.g., Ford, Honda, etc. - vehiclemodel The model of the vehicle, e.g., Taurus, Civic, etc. - vehicleyear The model year of the vehicle. - vehiclesalesprice The vehicle s sales price. Mean: 10435 vehiclevaluation vehiclemileage electronicmarket buyerdistance sellertype laneid The vehicle s market value as estimated by the intermediary that provided the data. Odometer reading of the vehicle. Denotes whether the vehicle was offered in the standalone electronic market or the physical market. 1=Standalone electronic market; 0=Physical market Distance between buyerzip and facilityzip. Denotes the type of seller(institutional or dealer.) 1=institutional; 0=dealer Denotes the lane at the facility in which the vehicle was auctioned. Std. dev: 7913 Mean: 11081.8 Std. dev: 8526.7 Mean: 64799.9 Std. dev: 49953 Mean: 0.0209 Std. dev: 0.1433 Mean: 204.6 Std. dev: 343.4 Mean: 0.5704 Std. dev: 0.4950-11

Webcast Denotes whether the vehicle offered in the physical market was purchased by a buyer using the webcast channel. 1=webcast buyer; 0=nonwebcast buyer Mean:0.0865 Std. dev: 0.2811 3.1 Identification of spatial arbitrage Following Overby and Clarke (2012), we identify instances of spatial arbitrage as follows. First, we identify what we refer to as flips. A flip is a pair of transactions for the same vehicle (identified by its unique VIN) in which the buyer in the first transaction is the seller in the second transaction (as identified by his unique traderid). Flips may occur because an arbitrageur is engaging in spatial arbitrage, but they may also occur for other reasons. For example, a buyer may flip a vehicle if he is unable to retail it and chooses to liquidate it in the wholesale market. A dealer may also flip a vehicle after making improvements to it (e.g. repairing dents, replacing tires). There are 2,749,524 flips in the sample. We delineate spatial arbitrage from other types of flips in two ways. First, we limit our focus to cross-facility flips, i.e., those in which the two transactions that comprise the flip occur at different facilities (as identified by the unique facilityids). Second, we only consider those flips that are completed within α days to be spatial arbitrage. We set α=7 in our primary analysis and varied α to 5, 15 and 28 for robustness. The 7 day interval is reasonable because of the time needed to: a) complete paperwork at the source facility where the vehicle was purchased, b) transport the vehicle to another facility, and c) register the vehicle for sale at the destination facility. Increasing the α threshold increases the probability that we will falsely classify a flip as arbitrage, because a longer time period increases the probability that the vehicle has been changed/improved or that the dealer is liquidating a vehicle that he failed to retail. An example of an instance of spatial arbitrage is as follows: traderid #111 purchased a vehicle with VIN 49567xxxxxxx at the Miami facility on February 10, 2003 and then sold the vehicle at the New Orleans facility on February 15, 2003. 12

The right panel of Figure 1 illustrates trends for the percentage of vehicles that were arbitraged (using α=7) over the sample period. Two things are particularly noteworthy. First, spatial arbitrage is rare; there is less than a 1% chance that any given vehicle will be spatially arbitraged. This is consistent with theoretical work about arbitrage (Shleifer and Vishny 1997), although very few studies have attempted to quantify the amount of arbitrage occurring in a market. Second, the prevalence of arbitrage fell over time, although an increasing percentage of arbitrage transactions began with the arbitrageur purchasing the vehicle from the stand-alone electronic market. We explore these trends more formally below. Figure 1: Total vehicles sold by year via webcast-enabled lanes and percentage of vehicles arbitraged by year. 100.0% 87.5% 75.0% 62.5% 50.0% 37.5% 25.0% 12.5% 00.0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 0.7% 0.6% 0.5% 0.4% 0.3% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Percentage of vehicles available on webcastenabled lanes by year. Percentage of vehicles arbitraged by year (top line). The middle and bottom lines show the breakdown of arbitrage transactions sourced from the physical market (either via the traditional physical channel or the webcast channel) and from the standalone electronic market. 4 Hypotheses 4.1 Arbitrageur behavior and the effect of the webcast channel on spatial arbitrage Spatial arbitrageurs seek to identify and purchase vehicles that are undervalued at one facility (the source facility) and sell them for a profit at a different facility (the destination facility). These opportunities exist because buyers at the arbitrageurs destination facilities are either 13

unaware of better prices at other facilities, unable to access other facilities, or both. A key feature of the webcast channel is that it allows buyers to check prices at facilities across the country simply by opening a browser window and observing the auctions via the webcast stream. The webcast channel also allows buyers to purchase vehicles from remotely-located facilities without having to travel. As a result, we posit that implementation of the webcast channel increasingly enabled remotely-located buyers to locate and purchase undervalued vehicles that an arbitrageur would have otherwise purchased. As such, we posit that implementation of the webcast channel negatively affected arbitrageurs ability to source vehicles for arbitrage. This leads to the following hypothesis. Hypothesis 1(H1): When sourcing vehicles, arbitrageurs are more likely to choose facilities where deployment of the webcast technology is relatively low. Based on the same logic, we also test the following hypotheses. Hypothesis 2a (H2a): Vehicles sold on webcast-enabled lanes are less likely to be spatially arbitraged than vehicles sold on non-webcast-enabled lanes. Hypothesis 2b (H2b): Vehicles sold on webcast-enabled lanes are more likely to be purchased by remotely located buyers than vehicles sold on non-webcast-enabled lanes. 4.2 The effect of the stand-alone electronic market on spatial arbitrage Sourcing undervalued vehicles offered at the physical market facilities may be difficult for arbitrageurs because of the 30-45 second window within which vehicles are auctioned. The short bidding window means that: a) an arbitrageur won t know if a vehicle is undervalued until the bidding begins, and b) he must be actively bidding on the vehicle during the 30-45 second window to purchase it. This is true regardless of whether the arbitrageur is bidding on vehicles offered at physical facilities in person or via the webcast channel. These constraints are relaxed 14

in the stand-alone electronic market, which may make it a more fruitful environment for arbitrageurs to source vehicles. First, many of the vehicle listings in the stand-alone electronic market include a posted Buy Now price. As such, arbitrageurs can monitor the market for vehicles with unusually low Buy Now prices, purchase them, and profitably arbitrage them. Second, bids may be placed on vehicles in the electronic market over a span of 1-3 days rather a span of 30-45 seconds. As such, arbitrageurs can routinely submit low bids for multiple vehicles, in the hopes that at least some of those bids will be accepted. Both of these behaviors may yield profitable arbitrage opportunities, and neither is possible for vehicles offered at the physical market facilities. Thus, we posit the following. Hypothesis 3 (H3): Vehicles sold in the stand-alone electronic market are more likely to be arbitraged than vehicles sold in the physical market. If arbitrageurs are able to identify mispriced vehicles more readily in the standalone electronic market than in the physical market, then they should be more likely to achieve a profit when they source from the electronic market. Given this, we also test the following hypothesis. Hypothesis 4 (H4): Arbitraged vehicles sourced from the stand-alone electronic market are more likely to yield a profit than vehicles sourced from the physical market. It is important to recognize that H3 and H4 do not posit that the stand-alone electronic market will cause the market to become less integrated by increasing the amount of spatial arbitrage. Instead, H3 and H4 posit that the electronic market will help arbitrageurs exploit a given level of market non-integration by helping them find mispriced vehicles that can be profitably arbitraged. 5 Analysis and Results We structure this section based on our two research questions. 5.1 How do arbitrageurs choose where to source products for arbitrage? 15

For each arbitrage transaction, the arbitrageur made a choice to source the vehicle from a particular facility as opposed to some other facility. We examined how they made this choice via a discrete choice model (Train 2003), which allows us to test our first research question and H1. Discrete choice models are based on the assumption that decision-makers are faced with a set of alternatives and that they choose the alternative that maximizes their utility. Fitting a choice model requires the researcher to define the set of alternatives available to the decision-maker and to specify a utility function for each alternative. We defined the set of alternatives (referred to as the choice set) for each arbitrage transaction conducted by arbitrageur j on day t as those facilities: a) at which arbitrageur j ever made a purchase during the sample period, and b) that were open on day t. We model the utility of each facility i to arbitrageur j at time t as U ijt = β 0,i + β 1 *PctOfferedWebcast it + β 2 *Distance ij + β 3 *Supply it + β 4 *Supply 2 it + β 5 *PctSold i(t- 30) + β 6 *GeoPriceVariability i(t-30) + β 7 *NearbyFacilities i *PctOfferedWebcast it + β 8 *PctSoldLowPrice i(t-30) + ε ijt. We describe the variables in Table 2. We used lagged variables for PctSoldLowPrice, PctSold, and GeoPriceVariability because the contemporaneous values of these variables are unknown to arbitrageurs when they choose the facility at which to purchase. We used contemporaneous variables for the other variables because arbitrageurs either already know them (viz., Distance ij ) or can calculate them based on the pre-sale list of vehicles posted in advance on the intermediary s web site. We included alternative-specific constants to capture the latent utility of each facility i (represented as the β 0,i term) and fitted the model using the conditional logit specification. Results appear in Table 3. Our focal results are based on defining spatial arbitrage using the α=7 threshold, and we varied this threshold for robustness. 16

Table 2: Variables used in the choice model where arbitrageurs source vehicles. Variable Description Mean (St. Dev.) PctOfferedWebcast it The percentage of vehicles at facility i on day t that were offered in webcast-enabled lanes. 0.62 (0.41) Distance ij Distance between facility i and arbitrageur j. 535.23 (528.18) Supply it The number of vehicles offered at facility i on day t. 783.40 (765.07) PctSold i(t-30) The percentage of vehicles offered at facility i in the 30 days prior to day t that were sold. 0.61 (0.12) GeoPriceVariability i(t-30) The average geographic price variance of the 1537.77 vehicles offered at facility i in the 30 days prior (242.00) to day t. a The number of facilities within 350 miles of NearbyFacilities i facility i. 20 (8) PctSoldLowPrice i(t-30) Percentage of vehicles at facility i in the 30 days prior to day t that sold for less than 90% of their market valuation. 0.20 (0.10) Notes: a Results are robust to other mileage thresholds besides 350. As shown in Table 3, the coefficient for PctOfferedWebcast it is negative and significant, indicating that arbitrageurs were less likely to purchase vehicles from facilities at which webcast deployment was high. We used the model estimates to simulate the economic size of this effect as follows. We simulated the percentage change in the number of times an arbitrageur chose facility i when PctOfferedWebcast it = 24% vs. when PctOfferedWebcast it = 71%, which are the mean values for this variable in 2003 and 2004, respectively. 3 We did this for each facility. On average, this reduced the probability that an arbitrageur would choose the facility by 30%. The coefficient for the NearbyFacilities i *PctOfferedWebcast it interaction term is positive and significant. This indicates that the disutility of PctOfferedWebcast it is minimized if facility i is surrounded by other market facilities. This is likely because arbitrageurs will be less sensitive to PctOfferedWebcast it if a facility is surrounded by several other facilities, because the other facilities represent nearby destination locations at which they might complete arbitrage flips. 3 This also represents close to a one standard deviation increase. 17

Despite this density effect, arbitrageurs still preferred nearby source locations. We simulated the economic size of the Distance effect by simulating the percentage change in the number of times an arbitrageur chose facility i when Distance = 250 vs. when Distance = 750. This reduced the probability of choosing a facility by 17%. Also, increasing PctSoldLowPrice from 20 percent to 40 percent increased the probability of choosing a facility by approximately 20%. Table 3: Results of the conditional logit model of arbitrageurs choice of facility. Focal Result Robustness Checks (α=7 days) (α=5 days) (α=15 days) (α=28 days) PctOfferedWebcast it (β 1 ) -0.8965 *** (0.0423) -0.6811 *** (0.0970) -0.7329 *** (0.0395) -0.6882 *** (0.0389) Distance ij (β 2 ) -1.1947 *** (0.0140) -2.4341 *** (0.0426) -1.0890 *** (0.0129) -1.0694 *** (0.0127) Supply it (β 3 ) 3.5520 *** (0.0218) 3.4865 *** (0.0458) 3.2040 *** (0.0196) 3.1218 *** (0.0192) Supply it *Supply it (β 4 ) -0.5503 *** (0.0054) -0.5561 *** (0.0111) -0.5001 *** (0.0050) -0.4877 *** (0.0049) PctSold i(t-30) (β 5 ) -2.1942 *** (0.0606) -2.2501 *** (0.1309) -1.8308 *** (0.0557) -1.7617 *** (0.0548) GeoPriceVariability i(t-30) (β 6 ) -0.0358 (0.1031) -0.4128 (0.2299) -0.1568 (0.0898) -0.1353 (0.0867) NearbyFacilities i *PctOffered Webcast it (β 7 ) 0.0270 *** (0.0018) 0.0250 *** (0.0041) 0.0238 *** (0.0016) 0.0226 *** (0.0016) PctSoldLowPrice i(t-30) (β8) 1.1026 *** (0.1073) 1.0492 *** (0.2399) 0.9224 *** (0.1016) 0.8907 *** (0.1004) Alternative specific constants Included Included Included Included Number of choices in choice set 2,5.9,48 2,5.9,48 2,6.0,49 2,6.0,49 (Min,avg,max) n (total number of choices) 698057 159058 744468 753299 Log Likelihood -115480-23631 -129599-132702 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 Notes: 1) α is the number of days used to delineate spatial arbitrage. 2) So that coefficients are of similar magnitude for reporting purposes we divided Supply, Distance, and GeoPriceVariability by 1000. 3) Note that NearbyFacilities i cannot enter the model directly because it is perfectly collinear with the alternative specific constants. 4) The number of choices for α=7, 15, and 28 is similar. This is because the number of choices reflects distinct instances in which an arbitrageur sourced vehicles from facility i on day t. If he flips at least one of the sourced vehicles within 7 days, then that instance will appear in the α=7 estimation. The only time an instance will appear in the α=15 estimation but not the α=7 estimation is if the arbitrageur flips at least one sourced vehicle within 15 days but none within 7 days, which is relatively rare. 18

These results contribute several novel findings about arbitrageur behavior. First, arbitrageurs are sensitive to geographic distance and location, preferring locations that are nearby but that are also surrounded by other market locations. Second, arbitrageurs prefer locations that are not heavily wired, which we explore further below. Third, arbitrageurs prefer locations where there has been a recent history of vehicles selling for below their market value. 5.2 How does the diffusion of electronic commerce affect arbitrage activity? 5.2.1 The effect of the webcast channel: The above results indicate that a high level of webcast enablement makes facilities unattractive source locations for arbitrageurs. We examined this further by leveraging the phased adoption of the webcast channel to conduct a natural experiment. This allows us to test H2a. Because the webcast technology was deployed at different times for each lane at each facility, we observe many instances in which very similar vehicles were sold at the same facility on the same day, some in lanes that were webcast-enabled and some in lanes that weren t. We considered vehicles sold in non-webcast-enabled lanes to be potential control vehicles and vehicles sold in webcast-enabled lanes to be potential treated vehicles. We matched control vehicles to treated vehicles on facility, sale date, vehicle year, make, model, mileage, valuation, and seller type (see Table 1). If the vehicles are matched adequately, then the only material difference between the control and treated groups are that the control vehicles were sold on non-webcast-enabled lanes while the treated vehicles were sold on webcast-enabled lanes. This allows us to attribute any significant differences in transaction outcomes for these vehicles (such as whether they are later arbitraged) to the treatment effect of being sold in a webcast-enabled lane. See Iacus et al (2011) and Imbens (2004) for a discussion of using matching techniques to estimate causal treatment effects. 19

We matched vehicles using exact matching and coarsened exact matching ( CEM ). Each treated vehicle could only be matched to a control vehicle with the same facilityid, vehicleyear, vehiclemake, vehiclemodel, and sellertype. We coarsened vehiclevaluation and vehiclemileage into bins of width 1,000 and 2,000, respectively, and only allowed matches between vehicles in the same bins. For example, a treated vehicle whose vehiclevaluation was between $10,000 and $11,000 and whose vehiclemileage was between 20,000 and 22,000 could only be matched to a control vehicle whose vehiclevaluation and vehiclemileage were within the same ranges 4. We also restricted matches to vehicles sold in the same week. Because there were essentially no potential control vehicles available after 2007 (because the webcast channel was almost fully deployed by then; see Figure 1), we restricted the analysis to observations from January 1, 2003 to December 31, 2007. The matching procedure yielded 45,933 matched strata/cells that each contained at least one treated vehicle and at least one control vehicle. For example, the procedure produced a stratum/cell for 2004 Dodge Neon s with between 15,051 and 16,749 miles and a market value between $8011 and $8075 sold at the Atlanta facility by institutional sellers in week 18 of 2004; there were six treated vehicles and one control vehicle in this stratum. In all, there are 106,950 treated vehicles and 73,633 control vehicles contained within the 45,933 strata in the matched sample. This procedure yields highly precise matches. To examine the quality of the matches, we examined the balance between the treated and control observations as follows. First, we calculated the means of vehiclemileage and vehiclevaluation for the treated and control vehicles 4 Coarsened exact matching temporarily coarsens each chosen variable into bins and exact matches on those bins, yielding a matched sample of control and treated observations. CEM then restores the original (not-coarsened) values of the variables for analysis. The CEM matching procedure may match an uneven number of control observations to treated observations. To account for this, CEM generates weights. Using these weights in an analysis procedure (such as a regression model) generates the sample average treatment effect. See Iacus et. al (2011) for details. 20

in each of the 45,933 strata in the matched sample, referred to as the strata means. We then used a t-test to test whether these strata means differed significantly between the treated and control groups. As shown in Table 4, we find no significant difference between the two groups for vehiclemileage, and the difference between groups for vehiclevaluation is negligible (about $2.17). Overall, we believe that our matches are precise enough to satisfy the un-confoundedness condition (aka, selection on observables) for valid matching estimation (Iacus et al. 2011; Imbens 2004). Table 4. Balance between treated and control observations in the matched sample Measure N (strata) N (treatment) N (control) Mean (treatment) Mean (control) Difference (t-stat) vehiclevaluation 45933 106950 73633 11707.61 11705.44-2.1736 (-2.374) vehiclemileage 45933 106950 73633 43984 43955.26-28.742 (-.9637) We used the following regression model to test the treatment effect of webcast enablement on the likelihood that a vehicle is arbitraged: is_arbitraged k = β 0 + β 1 *WebcastEnabled k + ε, where k subscripts the vehicle. is_arbitraged k is set to 1 if the vehicle was later arbitraged and 0 otherwise. WebcastEnabled k is set to 1 if the vehicle was sold in a webcast-enabled lane and 0 otherwise. We fitted the model on the matched sample using weighted least squares, with the weights provided by the CEM procedure (see footnote 5.) Table 5 shows the results. We used α=7 to delineate whether a vehicle was arbitraged in our focal model, and we varied this for robustness. Given the binary nature of the dependent variable, we also used logistic regression; these results are consistent with the weighted least squares estimates we report. 21

Table 5: Treatment effect of the vehicle being purchased on a webcast enabled lane on the probability that the vehicle is later arbitraged. Focal result Robustness results (α=7 days) is_arbitraged k (α=5 days) is_arbitraged k (α=15 days) is_arbitraged k (α=28 days) is_arbitraged k webcastenabled k ( β 1 ) -0.0013 *** (0.0003) -0.0008 ** (0.0003) -0.0033 *** (0.0005) -0.0041 *** (0.0006) Intercept ( β 0 ) 0.0057 *** (0.0003) 0.0034 *** (0.0002) 0.0118 *** (0.0004) 0.0165 *** (0.0004) N 180583 180583 180583 180583 Standard errors in parentheses ( * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001) α denotes the number of days in between flips. The intercept (β 0 ) represents the average probability that a vehicle sold in a non-webcastenabled lane was later arbitraged. Alternatively, it can be thought of as the percentage of vehicles sold in non-webcast-enabled lanes in the matched sample that were later arbitraged (0.57% with α=7). The treatment effect of webcast enablement is captured by β 1. The effect is negative and significant; vehicles sold in webcast-enabled lanes were approximately 23% less likely to be arbitraged. This indicates that webcast reduces the prevalence of spatial arbitrage. To examine the potential mechanism behind this result and to test H2b, we estimated the following additional regression. The regression specification is remotebuyer k = β 0 + β 1 *WebcastEnabled k + ε, where remotebuyer k = 1 if the distance between the buyer and the facility at which the vehicle was located was at least one standard deviation above the mean (see Table 1). remotebuyer k = 0 otherwise. For robustness, we also set remotebuyer k = 1 if the distance between the buyer and the facility at which the vehicle was located was at least two standard deviations above the mean. Results appear in Table 6. 22

Table 6: Treatment effect of webcast enablement on the probability that the buyer s distance is greater than 1 and 2 standard deviations above the mean. remotebuyer k remotebuyer k (distance > mean + std. dev) (distance > mean+ 2*std. dev) WebcastEnabled k (β 1 ) 0.0180 *** (0.00219) 0.0151 *** (0.0018) Intercept(β 0 ) 0.146 *** (0.00168) 0.0914 *** (0.00139) N 113433 113433 Standard errors in parentheses ( * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001) α is 7 days for the reported result. However, similar effects hold for 5, 15 and 28 days The results in Table 6 show that webcast enablement increases the probability of a remote buyer by 15%-17%, depending on the measure of a remote buyer. This is consistent with our logic that the webcast channel reduces the prevalence of spatial arbitrage by helping remotelylocated buyers who might otherwise be potential downstream customers for arbitrageurs purchase vehicles directly from source locations, thereby dis-intermediating the arbitrageur. 5.2.2 The effect of the stand-alone electronic market: It is possible that the effects of electronic commerce on spatial arbitrage vary based on the nature of the electronic channel. In this section, we test whether the effects for the webcast channel also hold for the stand-alone electronic market. To examine the effect of the stand-alone electronic market on spatial arbitrage and to test H3, we used a similar matching procedure as above, with one major change. We considered vehicles sold in the standalone electronic market to be potential treated vehicles, with vehicles sold in the physical market regardless of whether they were sold in a webcast enabled lane as potential control vehicles. We ran the matching procedure using the data from January 1, 2005 to December 31, 2010, as we observe minimal transaction volume in the standalone electronic market prior to 2005. The matching procedure yielded 45,636 matched strata, and the balance between treated and control observations was good, as shown in Table 7. 23

Table 7: Balance between treated and control groups in the matched sample. Measure N (strata) N (treatment) N (control) Mean (treatment) Mean (control) vehiclevaluation 45636 57722 115855 14750.71 14749.72 vehiclemileage 45636 57722 115855 25517.04 25522.56 Difference (t-stat) -0.9887 (-1.27) 5.5197 ( 1.630) Similar to above, the regression specification is: is_arbitraged k = β 0 + β 1 *ElectronicMarket k + ε. We fitted the regression using weighted least squares (with the weights provided by the CEM procedure, as above) and logistic regression. The weight least squares estimates appear in Table 8; logistic regression results are similar. We used different values of the α threshold for delineating spatial arbitrage for robustness. Table 8. Treatment effect of purchasing a vehicle in a standalone electronic channel on the probability that it is spatially arbitraged. Focal result Robustness result (α=7 day) is_arbitraged k (α=5 day) is_arbitraged k (α=15 day) is_arbitraged k (α=28 day) is_arbitraged k ElectronicMarket k (β 1 ) 0.0028 *** (0.0004) 0.0028 *** (0.0003) 0.0041 *** (0.0005) 0.0049 *** (0.0006) Intercept(β 0 ) 0.0047 *** 0.0025 *** 0.0099 *** 0.0146 *** (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0004) N 173577 173577 173577 173577 Standard errors in parentheses ( * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001) α denotes the number of days in between flips β 1 is positive and significant. Vehicles purchased in the electronic market are 73% more likely to be arbitraged than vehicles in the physical market (with α=7). To examine this further and to test H4, we examined the likely profits for each arbitrage transaction by subtracting the price at the source location from the price at the destination location. As shown in Table 9, the proportion of vehicle yielding a positive return (i.e., Destination Price > Source Price) is significantly higher (p<0.01) for vehicles source in the stand-alone electronic market than for 24

those sourced in the physical market. This suggests that sourcing on the electronic market is less risky for arbitrageurs than sourcing in the lane, potentially because the electronic market makes it easier for arbitrageurs to identify clearly mispriced vehicles, as discussed above. Table 9. Proportionality ratio test comparing the ratio of arbitrage transactions that yielded a positive return when sourced from the standalone electronic market vs. the physical market. Proportion of arbitrage transactions sourced on the standalone electronic market for which the destination price exceeded the source price. Proportion of arbitrage transactions sourced on the physical market for which the destination price exceeded the source price. Difference 0.96 0.85 0.11 *** (p<0.01) The overall effect of multichannel electronic commerce on spatial arbitrage: Our results indicate that webcast enablement reduces the probability that a vehicle was arbitraged and, by the same token, a high level of webcast enablement makes facilities unattractive source locations for arbitrageurs. However, we also find that the standalone electronic market fosters spatial arbitrage. The negative effect of webcast appears to dominate the positive effect of the standalone electronic market, because the overall percentage of spatial arbitrage decreased over time (see Figure 1). This is likely because there is relatively little transaction volume in the standalone electronic market (see Figure 2). Thus, an increase in arbitrage activity originating in this market cannot compensate for the decrease in arbitrage activity originating in the physical market due to the deployment of the webcast channel. Figure 2: Percentage of total vehicles sold by year via the webcast channel (top line) and via the standalone electronic market (bottom line). 0.18% 0.15% 0.12% 0.09% 0.06% 0.03% 0.00% 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 25

6 Conclusion Despite arbitrage s central place within economic theory, data limitations have made arbitrage transactions notoriously difficult to observe. As a result, a key mechanism in economic theory about efficient markets has been left largely unexamined; we have either taken it on faith or measured it indirectly. We overcome this by using highly granular data from the wholesale used vehicle market to measure spatial arbitrage at a transaction-level, which allows us to document novel insights about how arbitrageurs behave and how the diffusion of electronic commerce affects spatial arbitrage. We focus on how arbitrageurs choose where to source vehicles and find that this decision depends on geographic location and density, the likelihood of finding underpriced vehicles, and the degree to which the potential source location is wired for electronic trading. We believe that these insights into arbitrageur behavior are of inherent interest, because we know very little about how these economic actors who are critical to theories such as the law of one price and the efficient markets hypothesis actually behave. We also find that the diffusion of electronic commerce has affected the prevalence of spatial arbitrage, which is important because spatial arbitrage represents a useful (and untapped) measure of market integration/efficiency. Spatially-integrated markets are important for the stability and success of the economy, and electronic commerce has the potential to improve market integration by increasing price visibility and facilitating trade across geographic locations. We contribute to the research in this area by measuring market integration based on the prevalence of spatial arbitrage, which has several advantages over more common price-based measures, including accounting for transaction costs and unobserved product quality. Another contribution of our study is that we examine how two different types of electronic commerce influence spatial arbitrage and market integration. We find that the webcast channel decreases 26