Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector. Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector. Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS)"

Transcription

1 Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS) Ian M. Sheldon (Ohio State University) Current version: November 2017 Paper prepared in consideration for presentation at NBER Conference on Agriculture and Trade, May 17-18, 2018, Cambridge, MA. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and may not be attributed to the Economic Research Service or the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

2 Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector Abstract: In this paper, a structural gravity model is presented which features intra-sector heterogeneity in agricultural productivity systematically linked to land and climate characteristics. The systematic heterogeneity (SH) gravity model predicts that countries with similar land and climate characteristics will tend to specialize in the same agricultural products. Agricultural trade flow elasticities then depend on comparative advantage, with larger-magnitude trade flow responses predicted among countries more likely to specialize in similar agricultural products and thus compete head-to-head in foreign markets. This is in contrast to standard log-linear gravity models, which impose a restrictive pattern of trade flow elasticities that depend only on absolute advantage in the agricultural sector. We also show how the SH gravity model can accommodate product-specific trade costs. This allows the model to analyze changes in the dispersion of trade costs across products. Such analysis cannot be carried out in a standard gravity model, in which trade costs are assumed constant. Our results confirm economically and statistically significant heterogeneity in the effects of the variables that typically proxy for trade costs in gravity models and demonstrate that the SH gravity model is able to overcome the limitations imposed by the restrictive pattern of elasticities in a standard gravity model. Keywords: Agricultural trade, gravity, trade costs

3 Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector 1. Introduction The gravity model is a workhorse of applied international trade analysis. However, standard gravity models derived from a structural relationship in the most common trade models impose a restrictive pattern on the elasticity of bilateral trade flows with respect to changes in trade costs, which Heerman, Arita and Gopinath (2015) refer to as the Independence of Irrelevant Exporters (IIE) property. In models that feature the IIE property, the magnitude of the response of a country s export flows to a competitor s trade costs depends only on its absolute advantage in agriculture, irrespective of whether the competitor is likely to specialize in similar agricultural products. This is a particularly strong assumption in agriculture, where fundamental characteristics of its climate and geography have a strong influence on the specific set of products in which a country has comparative advantage and thus the set of countries against which it competes most intensely. We present a structural gravity model, the systematic heterogeneity (SH) gravity model, which features intra-sector heterogeneity in productivity linked to land and climate characteristics. The model predicts that countries with similar land and climate characteristics will systematically tend to specialize in the same products. Trade flow elasticities then depend on comparative advantage, with larger-magnitude predicted trade flow responses among countries more likely to specialize in similar products and thus compete head-to-head in foreign markets. 1

4 A no-less advantageous additional benefit of the SH gravity model is that it can accommodate product-specific trade costs. Transportation, marketing and other costs vary tremendously and systematically across agricultural products due to differences in perishability and policy treatment, among others. As such, the extent to which trade costs obscure comparative advantage varies within the sector. More practically, there is great demand for applied analysis of the production and trade implications of changes in agricultural policy. Although the agricultural sector represents a small share of the global economy, it is often pivotal in international trade relations. In the context of international negotiations, agricultural policy issues are typically considered at the product level. The SH gravity model s ability to capture changes in the distribution of trade costs across products is thus a substantial asset. The SH gravity model specifies the relationship between trade flows and trade costs as a random coefficients logit model (Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes, 1995). This is more complex than the linear methods used to estimate the standard gravity model. However, it requires little additional data. In the next section we elaborate on the features of the standard structural gravity model that impose restrictions on trade elasticities and the implications of those restrictions. Next we present the SH gravity model, describe our data and estimation technique, and carry out a test that finds that the IIE property does not hold in agricultural trade data. Finally, we present the results of our model and demonstrate its ability to overcome the restrictions of the standard gravity model. 2

5 2. Background Until recently, the conventional view in international economics was that the gravity equation lacked microeconomic foundations (Head and Mayer, 2014). However, it is now considered general enough to be applied beyond a sub-set of countries or sectors (Eaton and Kortum, 2002; Anderson and Wincoop, 2003; Arkolakis, Costinot, and Rodríguez-Clare, 2012), and that importer and exporter fixed effects can be used to account for the multilateral trade resistance terms derived from different theoretical models (Feenstra, 2004). In addition, evaluating a standard gravity equation on the basis of exports (imports) to (by) country n, at the firm/industry/sector-level as opposed to the economy-wide level using bilateral trade, has a clear analytical justification, drawing on a range of trade theories, e.g., Melitz (2003); Anderson and Wincoop (2004); Chaney (2008); Anderson and Yotov (2010a; 2010b; 2012); Costinot, Donaldson, and Komunjer (2012); and Costinot and Rodríguez-Clare (2014). As a result, robust estimation of firm/industry/sector-level gravity equations using export (import) data is now common in the agricultural economics literature, some recent applications including: Reimer and Li (2010) (crop trade); Jayasinghe, Beghin, and Moschini (2010) (US corn seed exports); Cardamone (2011) (fruit exports); Chevassus-Lozza and Latouche (2012) (French firms agri-food exports); Xu (2015) (agricultural trade); and Dal Bianco et al. (2016) (wine exports). An important characteristic of the range of structural gravity models is that the quantitative implications that can be drawn from them are very dependent upon a key parameter: the elasticity of trade with respect to trade frictions such as tariffs (Simonovska and Waugh, 2014). Arkolakis et al. (2012) argue that the elasticity of trade, denoted asε, is one of two 3

6 sufficient statistics necessary for calculating the welfare effects of trade, the other being the share of expenditure within a specific country on domestically produced goods denoted as λ. They show that the change in a country s real income, Wˆ = W / W, resulting from say a reduction in trade costs can be calculated as ˆ ˆ ε W = λ 1/, where ˆ λ = λ / λis the change in the share of domestic expenditure on imports. Importantly, changes in welfare are independent of the class of trade model, i.e., the source of the gains from trade depends on the type of trade model being estimated, but the aggregate gains from trade do not. Arkolakis et al. (2012) show that the welfare formula can be derived from three different structures: an Armington model (see Anderson and Wincoop, 2003), a Ricardian model (see Eaton and Kortum, 2002), and a heterogeneous firms model (see Melitz, 2003), where the margin of adjustment occurs respectively through consumption, reallocation of labor across sectors, and reallocation across firms within sectors. For this equivalence result to hold, Arkolakis et al. (2012) impose a key restriction on the partial elasticities: the import demand system is CES. Given the elasticities capture the percentage change in relative imports by country n from country i given a change in trade costs τ ni, the CES assumption implies that: there is a symmetric impact on relative demand XX nnnn /XX nnnn for imports by n for all exporters i n; and, any change in a third country s trade costs τ ni has the same proportional impact on X ni and X nn. In other words, changes in relative demand depend only on changes in trade costsτ ni. Given this result, Arkolakis et al. (2012) show that these effects can be recovered from a simple logarithmic gravity equation, the estimated parameter for changes in trade costs being treated as an estimate of the trade 4

7 elasticityε, and the change in real income of country n due to the trade shock being estimated as, W ˆ = ˆ λ 1/, irrespective of the margin of adjustment. n ε n Turning to trade in agricultural products, we argue that the CES assumption is overly restrictive, i.e., the elasticity of each exporter i s trade flows with respect to a given competitor s, i, trade flows is constant and directly proportional to the exporter s market share in n, irrespective of whether or not i competes with i. As noted earlier, Heerman et al. (2015), refer to this restriction as the IIE property, i.e., changes in a third country s trade costs τ ni are irrelevant to the ratio of any two competitors market share in a given import market n. The results of Arkolakis et al. (2012) indicate that IIE is implicitly imposed in trade models such as Eaton and Kortum (2002), Melitz (2003) and Anderson and Wincoop (2003). Heerman et al. (2015) argue that the IIE property is very unlikely to hold in the case of agricultural trade due to characteristics of natural endowments (land, soil, and climate) and production requirements being non-random drivers of comparative advantage within the agricultural sector. Consequently, econometric results assuming IIE will likely be imprecise, and any predictions about the effect of changes in trade costs on bilateral agricultural trade and production patterns, along with any estimated welfare effects, may be quite misleading. For example, suppose we consider the fact that the United States has recently chosen not to ratify the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) free trade agreement (FTA), but that the remaining 11 countries have chosen to proceed with the FTA. An expected benefit of TPP for U.S. agricultural sector would have been increased access to the Japanese market (Burfisher et al., 2014), but as a result of its withdrawal, Japanese tariff reductions will only be offered to remaining member countries such as Australia, Canada and Malaysia. If the IIE 5

8 property holds, the reduction in agricultural tariffs under TPP would imply that Japanese buyers substitute to Australian, Canadian and Malaysian products and away from its non- TPP trading partners such as the United States in a constant and direct proportion to their initial market shares. However, this makes little sense if we consider that Australia, Canada and the United States have similar land endowments and climate characteristics, and therefore systematically specialize in a similar set of agricultural products, which contrasts with Malaysia which has little available land and has a tropical climate. Consequently, one would expect that exclusion from TPP will result in the United States losing a proportionately larger market share in Japan relative to Australia and Canada than it will lose relative to Malaysia. In the context of this paper, the focus is on an extension of Eaton and Kortum (2002). The latter assumes that comparative advantage within manufacturing is a function of a random productivity variable that is independently distributed across products in the sector. Specifically, no two countries are more likely to compete against each other exporting the same products than any other country, i.e., the IIE property is assumed to hold. Extensions of Eaton and Kortum (2002) to multisector analysis by, inter alia, Burstein and Vogel (2010), Chor (2010), Costinot et al. (2012), Shiker (2011, 2012), Caliendo and Parro (2015), Tombe (2015), and Kerr (2017) implicitly recognize the limitation of this assumption, allowing average productivity, and in some cases the dispersion of productivity to vary across sectors, generating non-random patterns of trade specialization across sectors and sub-sectors. However, these models still maintain the assumption of random heterogeneity within each sector or sub-sector, the IIE property holding at that level. In addition, there are practical 6

9 limitations to a multi sub-sector approach within agriculture (Heerman, 2016). First, the researcher has to be able to define sub-sectors of like products such that specialization of a country within that sub-sector can be assumed to be randomly determined ex ante. For example, Reimer and Li (2010) focused on trade in crop agriculture, a well-defined subsector, but this still ignores the fact that agricultural product-specific farm and trade policies may be enough to distort any underlying forces of comparative advantage for crops that are substitutes in production. Second, disaggregation to sub-sectors requires considerably more bilateral trade and production data, and in the case of agriculture, where many products are thinly traded, there is the critical empirical issue of dealing with zero trade flows. The key departure in this paper is the introduction of systematic heterogeneity into the agricultural sector. Specifically, the likelihood a country has a comparative advantage in a set of products depends not only on a randomly drawn technological productivity-augmenting parameter, but also a set of country and product-specific characteristics including land and climate. For example, agricultural R&D in the United States might generate a diseaseresistant variety of bananas, but the land and climate requirements for growing bananas means the United States is unlikely to be a competitive exporter, and would therefore not be affected by any changes in the banana-importing regime of the European Union (EU). Alternatively the United States has a technological advantage in producing geneticallymodified corn for which it also has the appropriate land and climate requirements, and would likely lose some its Mexican export market share to Brazil if the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) were to collapse in the current round of renegotiations. 7

10 Allowing for systematic heterogeneity also means that trade costs may vary across products and countries within sectors. This matters in agriculture where trade costs can differ significantly due to the intrinsic characteristics of products and/or the types of trade and other policies applied to those products. For example, compared to Brazil, the United States has very low trade costs of exporting corn and soybeans to Mexico, partly due to geographical proximity, but also because it has a very efficient storage and transportation system that minimizes the cost of spillage etc. So any increase in trade barriers to Mexican imports from the United States would be partially mitigated by the higher costs of importing more corn and soybeans from Brazil. Likewise, the costs of the United States exporting processed pork products to Mexico will have higher handling costs than corn due to the risks of perishability and the need for refrigerated transportation. Importantly, the relative difference between these advantages are not likely to be constant. Trade policies also vary significantly across countries, with average MFN applied tariff rates in agriculture ranging from 1.2 percent in Australia, through 33.5 percent in India, to 66.7 percent in Egypt (Bagwell, Bown and Staiger, 2016). These average differences in tariffs can be captured in standard gravity models, but hide significant differences across products. Applied agricultural tariffs exhibit a good deal of heterogeneity across both products and countries. For example, Jales et al. (2005) report that developed countries typically have a number of very high agricultural tariffs and a large number of low tariffs, implying low mean tariffs with a high degree of tariff dispersion. By contrast, developing countries tend to have higher mean agricultural tariffs, and less tariff dispersion. In the case of tariff-rate quotas (TRQs), 1,400 have been introduced since 1995, with over-and in-quota tariffs averaging 123 and 63 percent respectively (Jales et al., 2005). 8

11 3. The Model The SH gravity model environment is comprised of II countries engaged in bilateral trade. Importers are indexed by nn and exporters by ii. The agricultural sector consists of a continuum of products indexed by jj [0,1]. To produce quantity qq ii ( jj) of product jj requires labor (NN ii ), land (LL ii ), and intermediate inputs QQ ii combined according to the function: Equation 1 qq ii (jj) = zz ii (jj) NN ii ββ (aa ii (jj)ll ii ) 1 ββ αα QQ ii 1 αα where zz ii ( jj) represents product jj-specific technological productivity and aa ii ( jj) represents product jj-specific land productivity. Technological productivity is modeled as an independently distributed Fréchet random variable with mean parameter TT ii and dispersion parameter θθ as in Eaton and Kortum (2002). Exporters with high values of TT ii have a greater probability of a high realization of zz ii ( jj) for any given agricultural product. Product-specific land productivity, aa ii ( jj), reflects the suitability of exporter ii s environment for product jj. We assume aa ii ( jj) follows a parametric density that is a deterministic function of exporter ii s agro-ecological characteristics and product jj s production requirements. For example, countries with a climate like Ecuador will systematically tend to have higher values of aa ii ( jj) for jj=bananas. Markets are perfectly competitive. The price offered by exporter ii for product jj in market nn is therefore equal to the unit cost of producing in country ii and marketing in country nn. Exporters face additional costs, ττ nnnn ( jj) > 1 to sell product jj in import market nn. Trade costs 9

12 are assumed to take the iceberg form, with ττ nnnn ( jj) = 1 and ττ nnnn ( jj) ττ nnnn ( jj)ττ llll ( jj). We assume ττ nnnn ( jj) follows a parametric density across products that is a deterministic function of product-specific policies and other marketing requirements. Productivity and trade cost distributions are assumed independent of each other. Trade occurs as buyers in each import market seek out the lowest price offer for each product. Heerman (2016) shows that for an individual product, the probability exporter ii offers the lowest price in market nn is: Equation 2 ππ nnnn (jj) = TT ii (aa ii (jj)cc ii ττ nnnn (jj)) θθ TT ll (aa ll (jj)cc ll ττ nnnn (jj)) θθ II ll=1 Exporter ii s total share of importer market nn agricultural expenditure is the unconditional probability it offers the lowest price for an agricultural product: Equation 3 Pr pp nnnn (jj) = pp nn (jj) ππ nnnn = TT ii(aa ii cc ii ττ nnnn ) θθ TT ll (aa ll cc ll ττ nnnn ) θθ ddff aann (aa )ddff ττnn (ττ) II ll=1 where aa ii (jj) = aa ii (jj) ααaa (1 ββ AA), cc ii is the cost of an input bundle, and ddff aann (aa )ddff ττnn AA (ττ) is the joint density of aa = [aa 11,, aa II ] and ττ AA = [ττ AA nnnn,, ττ II(II 11) ] over agricultural products consumed in import market nn. Equation 3 is a gravity-like relationship between market share on the one hand and exporter characteristics and bilateral trade costs on the other. It is a weighted sum of ππ nnnn ( jj), where the weights reflect the importance of each product in market nn consumption. AA 10

13 An expression equivalent to Equation 3 can also be derived from a demand-side model, as in the structural gravity equation outlined in Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and others. In that case TT ii is a share parameter that is an outcome of the Armington assumption and θθ = 1 σσ, where σσ is the elasticity of substitution (Anderson and Yotov, 2010a). In a demand side setting, the parameter aa ii (jj) could be used to represent product-specific preferences linked to characteristics of product jj produced in country ii. We leave the details of this extension for future work. Trade Elasticity Heerman et al. (2015) shows that in the SH gravity model, elasticity of market share with respect to a change in bilateral trade costs between exporter ii and the importing country nn can be written: Equation 4 ππ nnnn ττ nnnn ττ nnnn ππ nnnn = θθ (1 ππnnnn ) 1 vvvvvv ππ ππ nnnn (jj) nnnn ll = ii θθ cccccc ππ ππ nnnn (jj), ππ nnnn (jj) + ππ nnnn ππ nnnn ll ii nnnn Elasticities depend on cross-product differences in ππ nnnn (jj), with vvvvvv ππ nnnn (jj) and cccccc ππ nnnn (jj), ππ nnnn (jj) functions of the distributions of aa ii (jj) and ττ nnnn (jj). The direct effect of lower bilateral trade costs is decreasing in vvvvvv ππ nnnn (jj). This implies that market share is less elastic for exporters that specialize in products for which competition is less intense, or for which trade costs remain high. The indirect effect of a change in a competitor s bilateral trade costs is increasing in cccccc ππ nnnn (jj), ππ nnnn (jj). The indirect elasticity will therefore be larger 11

14 among competitors with similar distributions of aa ii (jj), and further augmented when ττ nnnn (jj) is also similar. In a standard gravity model ππ nnnn (jj) = ππ nnnn : The probability of comparative advantage in an individual product does not depend on product or exporter characteristics. Every exporter is thus equally likely to offer the lowest price in every agricultural product and vvvvvv ππ nnnn (jj) = cccccc ππ nnnn (jj), ππ nnnn (jj) = 0. Therefore, trade elasticities are a constant proportion of market share. Equation 5 ππ nnnn ττ nnnn = θθ(1 ππ nnnn) ll = ii ττ nnnn ππ nnnn θθππ nnnn ll ii These elasticities are a representation of the IIE property, which is imposed in every structural gravity model derived from a trade model that assumes a CES import demand system. 4. Specification and Data We estimate parameters of the productivity and trade cost distributions for agriculture as in Heerman et al. (2015) by specifying Equation 3 as a random coefficients logit model. We begin as in Eaton and Kortum (2002) by defining SS ii = ln(tt ii ) θθ ln(cc ii ). This is exporter ii s average technological productivity adjusted for unit production costs. Land Productivity Distribution We specify aa ii ( jj) as a parametric function of exporter land and climate characteristics and product land and climate requirements: 12

15 Equation 6 llll(aa ii ( jj)) = XX ii δδ( jj) = XX ii δδ + XX ii (EE( jj)λλ) + XX ii (νν EE ( jj)σσ EE ) where XX ii is a 1 kk vector of variables describing country ii s characteristics; δδ is a kk 1 vector of coefficients; EE( jj) is a 1 mm vector of product jj-specific production requirements that can be observed and quantified; ΛΛ is an mm kk matrix of coefficients that describes how the relationship between elements of XX ii and land productivity varies across products with EE( jj); and νν EE ( jj) is a 1 kk vector that captures the effect of unobservable product jj-specific requirements with matrix ΣΣ EE. We specify three types of exporter characteristics, climate, elevation and agricultural land: XX ii = [aall ii eeeevv ii ttttpp ii ttttpp ii bbbbrr ii ] where aall ii is the log of arable land per capita, eeeevv ii is the share of rural land between 800 and 3000 meters above sea level, and the remaining elements are the shares of total land area in tropical, temperate, and boreal climate zones. The vector jj = [EE( jj) νν EE ( jj)] defines products in terms of their suitability for production under the conditions defined by XX ii. We define: EE( jj) = [aaaaaa( jj) eeeeee( jj) tttttt( jj) tttttt( jj) bbbbbb( jj)] where aaaaaa( jj) describes product- jj land requirements, eeeeee( jj) captures its elevation requirements, and tttttt( jj), tttttt( jj), and bbbbbb( jj) describe climate requirements. These variables relate exporter ii s characteristics to absolute advantage in agriculture through XX ii δδ, 13

16 and describe how they systematically influence the set of products within the agricultural sector in which it has comparative advantage through XX ii (EE( jj)λλ). Note that we define the land intensity of product jj production using data on land per agricultural worker, whereas we use agricultural land per capita in XX ii. Elements of XX ii represent the factors that influence exporter ii s potential comparative advantage, whereas elements of EE( jj) represent the ideal conditions under which product jj is produced. Trade Cost Distribution We specify product- jj trade costs as: Equation 7 llll(ττ nnnn ( jj)) = tt nnnn ββ( jj) = tt nnnn ββ + eexx ii + tt nnnn (νν ttnn ( jj)σσ tt ) + ξξ nnnn where tt nnnn is a 1 mm vector describing the relationship between exporter ii and import market nn, ββ is an mm 1 vector of parameters; eexx ii is an exporter-specific trade cost captured by a fixed effect as in Waugh (2010); νν ttnn ( jj) is a 1 mm vector that captures the effect of unobservable product jj-specific trade costs with scaling matrix ΣΣ tt, and ξξ nnnn captures unobservable or unquantifiable bilateral trade costs that are common across products and orthogonal to the regressors. We define: tt nnnn = [bb nnnn ll nnnn rrrraa nnnn dd nnnn ] 14

17 where bb nnnn, ll nnnn and rrrraa nnnn equal one if the two countries share a common border or language or are members of a common regional free trade agreement. The 1 6 vector dd nnnn assigns each country pair to one of six distance categories as defined in Eaton and Kortum (Table 1). Table 1: Definition of distance variables Variable Distance, miles Distance 1 [0,375) Distance 2 [375,750) Distance 3 [750,1500) Distance 4 [1500,3000) Distance 5 [3000,6000) Distance 6 [6000, maximum] Estimating Productivity and Trade Cost Distribution Parameters Using our definitions of aa ii ( jj) and ττ nnnn ( jj) in Equation 3, we obtain a random coefficients logit model of agricultural market share: Equation 8 ππ nnnn = exp{ss ii + θθαα ii (1 ββ ii )XX ii δδ(jj) θθtt nnnn ββ(jj)} II ddff {SS ii + θθαα ll (1 ββ ll )XX ll δδ(jj) θθtt nnnn ββ(jj)} EEnn (EE)ddFF νν nn (νν) ll=1 where ddff EEnn (EE)ddFF νν nn (νν) is the empirical density of products imported by market nn defined jointly by their land and climate characteristics, unobserved agro-ecological requirements and trade costs. We estimate Equation 8 using a simulated method of moments approach similar to that in Berry et al., (1995), which is detailed in Nevo (2000) and Train (2009). To evaluate the integral, we use the smooth simulator suggested by Nevo (2000): 15

18 Equation 9 ns ππ nnnn = 1 nnnn exp SS ii + θθαα ii (1 ββ ii )XX ii δδ(jj) θθtt nnnn ββ(jj) II SS ii + θθαα ll (1 ββ ll )XX ll δδ(jj) θθtt nnnn ββ(jj) j=1 ll=1 where SS ii = SS ii + θθαα ii (1 ββ ii )XX ii δδ is a country fixed effect. We use the minimum distance procedure suggested by Nevo (2000) to obtain SS ii and δδ from SS ii. Data Parameters of the productivity and trade cost distributions are estimated using production and trade data from Bilateral market shares (ππ nnnn ) are calculated by dividing bilateral import value by total domestic expenditure, calculated as the sum of production value and net exports. Domestic market share is calculated as ππ nnnn = 1 ii nn ππ nnnn. Our data consists of a sample of 63 countries and 134 agricultural items for which data on both bilateral trade and the gross value of production in U.S. dollars are available (FAO, 2013). These are mostly primary agricultural products. Elements of tt nnnn are obtained from the CEPII gravity data set (Head, Mayer and Ries, 2009). While land and climate requirements for each product are not directly observable to the economist, we do observe conditions of their production around the world. We therefore use observable characteristics of exporting countries to construct observable product requirements matrix EE( jj) for each of the JJ = 134 items for which the FAO publishes both production and trade data. This approach is valid under two assumptions: First, EE( jj) is distributed across products following the empirical distribution of requirements for agricultural products defined at the item level by the FAO. Second, exporting is positively correlated with high values of aa ii (jj). We measure eeeeee( jj) and aaaaaa( jj) 16

19 as in Heerman et al. (2015) as the export-weighted average of exporters share of land at high elevation (eeeevv ii ) and arable land per agricultural worker (aaaaww ii ) using data on arable land per capita and land per agricultural worker from World Bank (2012) and elevation data from CIESIN (2010), respectively. A drawback of defining product requirements as export-weighted averages of country characteristics is that it is not very precise. Many important agricultural exporters have varied terrain and climate within their borders. For example, roughly 20 percent of global wheat exports originated in Canada in However, while a large share of total Canadian land area is in the boreal climate zone, its wheat production is concentrated in temperate regions. A trade-weighted average of climate distributions thus misrepresents wheat s climate requirements. We are able to improve on the measurement of product-specific climate requirements used in Heerman et al. (2015), taking advantage of information on product-specific production across climate zones within countries provided by the GTAP land use database (Lee et al., 2005). As part of an effort to model the impact of climate change on the agricultural sector, the database provides estimates of land rent for ten product categories in 18 agro-ecological zones (AEZs) within in each of several countries. An AEZ is a defined zone based on soil, landform and climactic characteristics. A country s estimated land rent in AEZ xx for crop yy is calculated by by apportioning the crop s total land rent across AEZ s in proportion to its share in the value of crop yy production. To calculate product climate requirements, we assign each of the crops in our data set to one of the ten GTAP aggregates. We then calculate the share of land rent in each zone and aggregate these 17

20 shares into a distribution of land rent across tropical, temperate and boreal climate zones for each product, country pair. Finally, we define product jj climate requirements as the export-weighted average of these land rent distributions. The GTAP land use database does not calculate a distribution of land rent across climate zones for animal products. We use export-weighted averages of country climate distributions, as we did for land and elevation intensity, to calculate [tttttt( jj) tttttt( jj) bbbbbb( jj)] for these products. The nnnn = 900 products used to evaluate Equation 9 for each importer and its trading partners are drawn from ddff EEnn (EE)ddFF νν nn (νν). We construct this density as in Heerman et al. (2015), first using FAO item level import data to estimate ddff EEnn (EE), the empirical distribution of EE( jj) across products imported by each market by compiling a list of 1000 imported items defined by the vector EE( jj) for each market nn. Unique values of EE( jj) are represented in ddff EEnn (EE) in proportion to the associated FAO item s share in total imports. That is, if 15% of importer nn s total agricultural imports are of the FAO item wheat, then EE(wwheeeeee) makes up 150 entries on ddff EEnn (EE). Next we draw values of EE( jj) using uniform draws from each country s distribution. The distribution is completed by associating each item on the list with νν nn ( jj) = [νν EE (jj) νν ttnn (jj)] drawn from a standard multivariate normal distribution, effectively generating a data set of 900 unique products imported by each market. 5. A Test for the IIE Property If the IIE property holds in the data, the standard gravity model adequately captures trade elasticities and welfare can be calculated following the simple approach described in Arkolakis et al. (2012). That is, when all heterogeneity can be assumed independent, Equation 3 becomes: 18

21 Equation 10 Pr pp nnnn (jj) = pp nn (jj) ππ nnnn = TT ii(cc ii ττ nnnn ) θθ TT ll (cc ll ττ nnnn ) θθ II ll=1 The ratio ππ nnnn /ππ nnnn can then be log-linearized, delivering a standard gravity model. Using the trade cost specification described above, this is: Equation 11 ln ππ nnnn ππ nnnn = SS ii SS nn θθαα ii (1 ββ ii )XX ii δδ θθtt nnnn ββ A test of whether the IIE property holds in the data is suggested by those developed for its demand-side parallel, the independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA) (Greene 2003). McFadden and Train (2000) describe a test that can be used to evaluate whether IIE holds in our agricultural trade data. The idea behind this test is that if all heterogeneity in price offers is independently distributed, market shares should be uncorrelated across exporters and deviations from average trade costs will not have a statistically significant impact on bilateral market share. The formal hypothesis is that market share can be represented by Equation 10 against the alternative that comparative advantage is not independently distributed across products. To conduct the test, parameter estimates from Equation 11 are used to calculate estimated market shares ππ nnnn. These estimates are then used to construct artificial variables, which take the form: zz nnnn = 1 2 (tt nnnn tt nn ) 2 19

22 II where tt nn = ll=1 tt nnnn ππ nnnn and tt nnnn is an element of tt nnnn. McFadden and Train (2000) show that if the coefficients on these artificial variables are jointly insignificant, the null hypothesis that heterogeneity is independently distributed across products cannot be rejected. We calculate artificial variables for border, language, distance and RTA and then estimate: Equation 12 ln ππ nnnn = SS ππ ii SS nn θθαα ii (1 ββ ii )XX ii δδ θθtt nnnn ββ + zz nnnn dd zz nnnndd ββ dd nnnn 10 dd=1 where XX ii and tt nnnn are defined as above and zz nnnn is the artificial variable constructed from the dd dd tth element of the vector of trade cost variables for exporter ii in market nn and ββ dd is the corresponding coefficient. A test of the null hypothesis that the artificial variables are jointly equal to zero is firmly rejected at any reasonable level of significance with an FF-statistic equal to Econometric Results Land Productivity Distribution Table 2 presents estimates for the land productivity distribution parameters δδ, ΛΛ, and ΣΣ EE. The total effect of each exporter characteristic in XX ii on ππ nnnn ( jj) is the sum of the mean effect in the first column and the product-specific effects in the columns that follow. 20

23 Table 2: Land Productivity Distribution Parameter Estimates Exporter Characteristics (XX ii ) Mean Effects (δδ) Unobser ved Reqs (ΣΣ EE ) Agro-Ecological Requirements (ΛΛ) eeeeee(jj) aaaaaa(jj) tttttt(jj) tttttt(jj) bbbbbb(jj) ln Arable Land per Ag Worker 0.17*** *** 0.42*** 1.81*** 0.33*** High Elevation 1.14*** *** 0.44*** 1.31*** *** Tropical Climate Share 0.7*** -0.16** -3.96*** 0.73*** 6.86*** Temp. Climate Share 0.19*** *** -0.53*** -2.8*** 0.7*** 2.1 Boreal Climate Share -0.88*** 0.19** 2.5*** -0.2*** -4.06*** -0.89*** 4.94 ***significant at the 1% level, ** significant at the 5% level, *significant at the 10% level. Note: Values in this table are inclusive of the term θθαα ii (1 ββ ii ) Coefficients on all climate variables are normalized to sum to zero. As such, coefficients on exporter climate characteristics are interpreted with respect to the average climate, and the effects of product-specific climate requirements are interpreted with respect to the average production requirement. For example, the positive mean effect on tropical land share (δδ tttttt = 0.7) implies that having a larger than average share of land in a tropical climate increases agricultural market share on average. The positive and larger coefficient on tttttt( jj) (λλ tttttt,tttttt = 6.86) implies this effect is increasing for products that are more intensively tropical than average. A negative coefficient implies the advantage of tropical land is decreasing for more intensively boreal products (λλ tttttt,bbbbbb = 7.4). Figure 1 illustrates the distribution of the total effect of high elevation land across the products in our constructed data set. High elevation land decreases the probability of having the lowest price for some products, but raises it for most. The positive mean effect on elevation (δδ eeeeeeee = 1.14) implies that having more land at high elevation increases agricultural market share on average. This advantage is greatly magnified for products 21

24 intensively produced at high elevations (eeeeee(jj) = 47.96) and products that are more intensely boreal than the average product (λλ eeeeeeee,bbbbbb = 11.01). It is diminished for products more intensively produced in temperate climates than the average product (λλ eeeeeeee,tttttt = 12.32). The statistically and economically insignificant value of the estimated coefficient on unobservable differences in the effect of high elevation (σσ eeeeeeee = 0.21), implies that variation in the effect is sufficiently explained by the product requirements in EE( jj). Figure 1. Frequency plot - High elevation land effect Number of traded products Product-specific effect Estimates for SS ii are listed in Table 7 in the Appendix. These values are normalized to sum to zero and are thus interpreted as average sector-level productivity relative to the average country, and in the average product. Recall that SS ii is increasing in average technological and land productivity, but decreasing in costs of production cc ii. A country with high average productivity may nevertheless have a small SS ii if it has, e.g., very high wages or land rental rates. 22

25 Trade Costs Table 3 contains estimates for the trade cost distribution parameters ββ and ΣΣ tt. Positive coefficient values in ββ imply higher trade costs, but lower expected market share. Elements of ΣΣ tt capture heterogeneity in the effect of each element of tt nnnn across agricultural products and can be interpreted like a standard error around the mean effect. exporters. Table 3: Trade Cost Distribution Parameters Country Pair Mean Unobserved Characteristics Effect (ββ AA ) Heterogeneity (ΣΣ tt ) Common Border -1.76*** 3.13*** Common Language 1.24*** 0.95*** Common RTA 0.19** Distance *** 2.36*** Distance *** 2.33*** Distance *** Distance *** 1.37*** Distance *** Distance *** 0.64*** *** significant at 1%, ** significant at 5%, *significant at 10%. Note: Values in this table are inclusive of the term θθ. In the agricultural sector, positive mean effects imply that sharing a common language and participating in an RTA increase market share on average, while negative coefficients imply distance tends to decrease it. The negative mean effect of sharing a border (ββ bb = 1.76) is counterintuitive. However, the relatively larger magnitude of the estimated standard error (σσ bb = 3.13) implies sharing a border increases market share for some products and decreases it for others. Sharing a border may reduce trade in individual products for a 23

26 number of reasons. For example, domestic agricultural policies often systematically advantage domestic producers relative to their close competitors. Values of eeee ii are reported in Table 7 in the Appendix. The values are normalized to sum to zero, so positive (negative) values imply that exporter ii is a lower (higher)-than-averagecost exporter. Our results suggest that Belgium, Canada and the United States are the lowestcost exporters in our data set. Total Bilateral Trade Cost Distribution As in a standard gravity model, bilateral trade costs vary across exporters depending upon the characteristics in Table 3. In the SH gravity model, heterogeneity in the effect of these characteristics captures additional variation across products. In Figure 2 we illustrate the distribution of trade costs faced by two high income countries in the U.S. market. The figure confirms that on average, Japanese products face higher costs to enter the U.S. market than Canadian products. In addition to a difference in the location of the distribution, which can be captured in a standard gravity model, higher moments of the distribution appear markedly different. For Canada, trade costs are low on most products, but a few face very high costs to enter the U.S. market. In contrast, trade costs facing Japanese imports are distributed tightly around the median. This can be traced to the relatively large values for the standard deviation around common border (σσ bb = 3.13) and the closest distance categories (σσ 1 = 2.36, σσ 2 = 2.33). Differences in the distribution across products are explained in part by differences in options for modes of transport from near versus far, but also on regulatory and other policies that affect bilateral trade asymmetrically across products and countries. 24

27 Figure 2. Frequency plot of trade costs faced in U.S. market Number of products Canada ln(τ ni ) Number of products Japan ln(τ ni ) Elasticities Parameter estimates in Table 2 and Table 3 allow us to calculate predicted market share (Equation 9) and elasticities using the formulas underlying Equation 4. 1 To see how the SH gravity model overcomes the limitations of imposing the IIE property highlighted in Arkolakis et al. (2012), we first show that the predicted elasticities are not a constant proportion of market share, as the standard model predicts (Equation 5 ). We calculate the ratio of the elasticity to Mexican trade costs to market share in Canada, that is ππ nnnn ττ nnnn ττ nnnn ππ nnnn /ππ nnnn, where ll =Mexico, ii Mexico and nn=canada. Since the relevant elasticity is a direct elasticity for ii=mexico, we divide the elasticity by (1 ππ CCCCCCCCCCCC ). This ratio would be a the same (equal to θθ) for every country in the standard model. In the SH model the ratio varies dramatically depending on characteristics of the exporter and the products they export to Canada. Table 4 reports this ratio for the countries with the largest share of θθ ππ 1 ππ nnnn ττ nnnn ππ nnnn (jj) 1 ππ nnnn (jj) ddff aa (aa )ddff ττnn (ττ) = nnnn ττ nnnn ππ nnnn θθ ππ ππ nnnn (jj)ππ nnnn (jj)ddff aa (aa )ddff ττnn (ττ) nnnn Integrals are simulated as in Equation 9. iiii ll = ii ooooheeeeeeeeeeee 25

28 Canadian expenditure on the products in our data set. The SH gravity model predicts that Colombia, Chile and Indonesia would gain disproportionately from higher Mexican trade costs, whereas gains in Canadian and U.S. market share will be proportionately smaller. Table 4. Trade elasticities are not constant Source ππ nnnn ττ nnnn /ππ country ττ nnnn ππ nnnn nnnn Canada 0.15 USA 0.30 Mexico** 3.70 Chile Indonesia Colombia nn = Canada, ll = Mexico, ii = Source country **The elasticity of Mexico with respect to Mexican trade costs is divided by (1 ππ cccc,mmmmmm ) As discussed earlier in this paper, Arkolakis et al. (2012) highlight two consequences of these restrictive elasticities implied by the IIE property. First, an increase in ττ nnnn has a symmetric effect on relative expenditure (XX nnnn /XX nnnn ) for all countries regardless of the characteristics of markets for the agricultural products they export. To illustrate how the SH gravity model overcomes this restriction, we calculate the elasticity of ππ nnnn with respect to ττ nnnn for each country ii and nn = Canada, and use it to calculate new values for relative market share, ππ nnnn /ππ nnnn. Although relative expenditure and relative market share are equivalent by definition, we present our results in terms of market share since it is the object we calculate. Table 5 presents the ratio ππ nnnn ππ nnnn ππ nnnn for the foreign countries with the largest share of ππ nnnn Canadian expenditure in our data set. The ratio is greater than the median value for each of these exporters. It would be identical for every country in the standard model. 26

29 The SH model finds that relative market share generally declines less for countries with a larger initial share of the Canadian market. However, the value o the ratio does not decline monotonically with market share. For example, a larger ratio (0.963 versus 0.960) suggests that Indonesian exports face less head-to-head competition in the Canadian market than do those of Chile, which represent a larger share of Canadian expenditure in the base model. A particularly small decline suggests that U.S. exporters generally face less intense price competition in the Canadian market. This is a substantial advantage, likely due to geographical and cultural proximity as well as trade preferences. Table 5. Changing trade costs do not have symmetric effects on relative demand ππ nnnn ππ nnnn ππ nnnn Country ππ nnnn USA Mexico Chile Indonesia Colombia Costa Rica Median nn = CCCCCCCCCCCC, ii = SSSSSSSSSSSS cccccccccccccc The second consequence discussed in Arkolakis et al. (2012) is that relative market share is unaffected by a change in a third country s trade costs. This is essentially a statement of the IIE assumption and a straightforward parallel to the red bus-blue bus problem referenced extensively in the literature on discrete choice demand systems. 2 The standard gravity 2 Train (2009) describes this famous problem of modeling consumer choice between traveling to work by blue bus or by car. In a model that assumes the IIA, the introduction of a new red bus that is otherwise equivalent to the blue bus will predict that consumers substitute toward the red bus in proportion to their use of the blue bus and car. 27

30 model predicts that higher trade costs will drive Canadian buyers to substitute away from Mexican products and toward all other sources proportionately such that ππ nnnn ππ nnnn (ii MMMMMMMMMMMM) is unchanged, regardless of whether country ii is likely to specialize in products that are substitutable for those Mexico exports to Canada. To explore the extent to which the SH model overcomes this restriction we use the elasticities with respect to Mexican trade costs in the Canadian market from Table 4 to calculate predicted new values for relative market ππ nnnn share: ππ nnnn. Table 6 presents the ratio ππ nnnn for the countries with the largest and ππ nnnn smallest values. This would be exactly equal to one for every country in the standard gravity model. ππ nnnn ππ nnnn Table 6. Changing third country trade costs do not have a proportional impact on relative market share Source ππ nnnn ππ Country ππ nnnn * nnnn ππ nnnn Costa Rica Honduras Venezuela Australia Kazakhstan USA Median nn = CCCCCCCCCCCC, ii = SSSSSSSSSSSS cccccccccccccc The variation produced by the SH model is small the relative market share of the most responsive country increases by only 0.4 percent more than the least responsive. 3 However, the variation in elasticities is in the direction we expect: The SH model predicts that Mexico s neighbors with similar climates Costa Rica and Honduras gain proportionately more from 3 Values less than one imply that domestic (Canadian) producers gain proportionately more market share than the United States and Kazakhstan. 28

31 Mexico s lost access. Larger changes in trade costs and changes in the dispersion of trade costs can translate into more substantial differences in predicted trade flows. 7. Conclusions In this paper we have detailed two disadvantages of the standard gravity model for applied analysis of agricultural trade and presented a tractable alternative, the SH gravity model. We have shown that the SH gravity model can overcome the limitations on bilateral trade elasticities embodied by the IIE property. We discuss the work of Arkolakis et al. (2012), who explain that it is the assumption of a CES import demand system that delivers a gravitylike structural relationship in the most common trade models, but also imposes the IIE property. The SH gravity model loosens the CES import demand system assumption while maintaining a gravity-like structural relationship. The model is specified as a randomcoefficients logit model (Berry et al., 1995). Using interactions between exporter land and climate characteristics and product land and climate production requirements, it identifies countries likely to have comparative advantage in similar products. These countries trade flows are then more elastic to each other s trade costs. We have also shown how the SH gravity model can accommodate product-specific trade costs. This allows the model to analyze changes in the dispersion of trade costs across products. Such analysis cannot be carried out in a standard gravity model, in which trade costs are assumed constant. Our results confirm economically and statistically significant heterogeneity in the effects of the variables that typically proxy for trade costs in gravity models. 29

32 In our ongoing work developing the SH gravity model, we seek to improve the model and its general equilibrium extension on several fronts, with an explicit objective of enhancing its usefulness for applied analysis of agricultural trade policy. First, in addition to updating the trade and production data, we are exploring alternative approaches to constructing the distribution of products consumed. Currently, we assume that the distribution of products consumed is adequately represented by the distribution of imported products. However, if high product-specific tariffs sufficiently limit imports of a given product, it will be underrepresented and the estimates of gains from reducing those tariffs will be under-estimated. Second, we are gathering data and adapting the estimation methodology in order to introduce observable sources of trade cost heterogeneity arising from policy differences like tariffs and non-tariff measures, as well as from intrinsic characteristics like perishability. Finally, we are pursuing methodological changes to improve product and sub-sector level analysis within the model, allowing for a better understanding of the distributional consequences of changes in trade costs. 30

. Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector

. Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector . Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector Kari E.R. Heerman, Economic Research Service, USDA Ian Sheldon, Ohio State University NBER Trade and Agriculture

More information

Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector. Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS)

Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector. Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS) Gravity and Comparative Advantage: Estimation of Trade Elasticities for the Agricultural Sector Kari E.R. Heerman (USDA-ERS) keheerman@ers.usda.gove Ian M. Sheldon (Ohio State University) sheldon.1@osu.edu

More information

. Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region

. Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region . Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region What might be the potential impact on agricultural trade? Kari E.R. Heerman, Economic Research Service, USDA Ian Sheldon, Ohio State University

More information

Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region: What might be the potential impact on agricultural trade?

Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region: What might be the potential impact on agricultural trade? Increased economic integration in the Asia-Pacific region: What might be the potential impact on agricultural trade? Kari E.R. Heerman (keheerman@ers.usda.gov) Ian Sheldon (sheldon.1@osu.edu) Selected

More information

Asia-Pacific Integration with China vs. the United States: Examining trade patterns under heterogeneous agricultural sectors

Asia-Pacific Integration with China vs. the United States: Examining trade patterns under heterogeneous agricultural sectors Asia-Pacific Integration with China vs. the United States: Examining trade patterns under heterogeneous agricultural sectors Kari E.R. Heerman, Shawn Arita and Munisamy Gopinath USDA-ERS, 355 E Street

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Today s Plan 1 2 3 4 Revisiting New Trade Theory with firm heterogeneity Multiple

More information

CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11

CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11 CANADIAN AGRIFOOD EXPORT PERFORMANCE AND THE GROWTH POTENTIAL OF THE BRICS AND NEXT- 11 CATPRN Trade Policy Brief 2012-05 December 2012 Alexander Cairns Karl D. Meilke Department of Food, Agricultural

More information

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Economics Working Paper Series 2016/012 Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade Kwok Tong Soo The Department of Economics Lancaster University Management School Lancaster LA1 4YX UK Authors All

More information

Impacts of Chinese Tariffs on Soybeans and other Ag Commodities and the Renegotiated NAFTA Agreement

Impacts of Chinese Tariffs on Soybeans and other Ag Commodities and the Renegotiated NAFTA Agreement Impacts of Chinese Tariffs on Soybeans and other Ag Commodities and the Renegotiated NAFTA Agreement Wallace Tyner Purdue University In collaboration with Farzad Taheripour, Dominique van der Mensbrugghe,

More information

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (Ph.D.) Introduction In this class, we will see two papers that will be used as building blocks of most of this

More information

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE YAO PAN

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE YAO PAN COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE YAO PAN FREE TRADE: VIETNAM & EU 2/16 THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE Trade based on differences: in technologies: Ricardo in factor endowments: Hecksher-Ohlin(H-O) èinter-industry

More information

Sessions 3/4: Summing Up and Brainstorming

Sessions 3/4: Summing Up and Brainstorming Niehaus Center, Princeton University GEM, Sciences Po ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research: Behind the Border Gravity Modeling Friday, December 19, 2008 Outline 1 The Gravity Model From

More information

Competition and Welfare Gains from Trade: A Quantitative Analysis of China Between 1995 and 2004

Competition and Welfare Gains from Trade: A Quantitative Analysis of China Between 1995 and 2004 Competition and Welfare Gains from Trade: A Quantitative Analysis of China Between 1995 and 2004 Wen-Tai Hsu Yi Lu Guiying Laura Wu SMU NUS NTU At NUS January 15, 2016 Hsu (SMU), Lu (NUS), and Wu (NTU)

More information

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow, Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Guelph, Canada and Lecturer, WFP

More information

Testing the Market Integration in Regional Cantaloupe and Melon Markets. between the U.S. and Mexico: An Application of Error Correction Model

Testing the Market Integration in Regional Cantaloupe and Melon Markets. between the U.S. and Mexico: An Application of Error Correction Model Testing the Market Integration in Regional Cantaloupe and Melon Markets between the U.S. and Mexico: An Application of Error Correction Model Yan Xia, Dwi Susanto and Parr Rosson* Abstract: This paper

More information

CHAPTER 3. Quantitative Demand Analysis

CHAPTER 3. Quantitative Demand Analysis CHAPTER 3 Quantitative Demand Analysis Copyright 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill Education. Chapter Outline

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics University of Minnesota June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING AND PRODUCTION ECONOMICS FIELD Instructions: Write your code

More information

The Decision to Import

The Decision to Import March 2010 The Decision to Import Mark J. Gibson Washington State University Tim A. Graciano Washington State University ABSTRACT Why do some producers choose to use imported intermediate inputs while

More information

ADBI Working Paper Series SERVICES POLICIES AND MANUFACTURING EXPORTS. Ben Shepherd. No. 908 December Asian Development Bank Institute

ADBI Working Paper Series SERVICES POLICIES AND MANUFACTURING EXPORTS. Ben Shepherd. No. 908 December Asian Development Bank Institute ADBI Working Paper Series SERVICES POLICIES AND MANUFACTURING EXPORTS Ben No. 908 December 2018 Asian Development Bank Institute Ben is a principal at Developing Trade Consultants. The views expressed

More information

International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) After Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 36 Announcement 1 Problem Set 4 has

More information

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling Organized by Economics and Social Commission for Western Asia (September 29, 2017) Beirut Presented by: Yves Surry: Professor at the Swedish

More information

Tools for trade policy analysis: examples from impact assessment of FTAs

Tools for trade policy analysis: examples from impact assessment of FTAs Myanmar and the Asia-Pacific region: Role of policy research in economic and trade reforms 19-21 February 2015, Yangon Tools for trade policy analysis: examples from impact assessment of FTAs Witada Aunkoonwattaka

More information

Impacts of WTO Policy Reforms on U.S. Rice

Impacts of WTO Policy Reforms on U.S. Rice Impacts of WTO Policy Reforms on U.S. Rice by Eric J. Wailes and Alvaro Durand-Morat University of Arkansas, Fayetteville Division of Agriculture Paper prepared for presentation at the World Trade Organization

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURED AGGREGATE GAINS FROM INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Ariel Burstein Javier Cravino

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURED AGGREGATE GAINS FROM INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Ariel Burstein Javier Cravino NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURED AGGREGATE GAINS FROM INTERNATIONAL TRADE Ariel Burstein Javier Cravino Working Paper 17767 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17767 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

The Trans-Pacific Trade Partnership: What might it mean for US agriculture? Ian Sheldon Andersons Professor of International Trade

The Trans-Pacific Trade Partnership: What might it mean for US agriculture? Ian Sheldon Andersons Professor of International Trade The Trans-Pacific Trade Partnership: What might it mean for US agriculture? Ian Sheldon Andersons Professor of International Trade Trans-Pacific Trade Partnership (TPP), signed October 5, 2015 largest

More information

Modelling Competitiveness. Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi

Modelling Competitiveness. Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi Modelling Competitiveness Biswajit Nag Indian Institute of Foreign Trade New Delhi biswajit@iift.ac.in biswajit.nag@gmail.com Content Theoretical Models to asses International Competitiveness Empirical

More information

Misallocation Measures: Glowing Like the Metal on the Edge of a Knife

Misallocation Measures: Glowing Like the Metal on the Edge of a Knife Misallocation Measures: Glowing Like the Metal on the Edge of a Knife John Haltiwanger, University of Maryland and NBER Robert Kulick, University of Maryland Chad Syverson, U. of Chicago Booth School of

More information

Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection of 25 Percent on US Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities

Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection of 25 Percent on US Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection of 25 Percent on US Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities By Farzad Taheripour Wallace E. Tyner Update to GTAP Working Paper No. 83 April 2018 This research

More information

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms

Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Determinants and Evidence of Export Patterns by Belgian Firms Jan Van Hove, Sophie Soete and Zuzanna Studnicka University of Leuven Document Identifier D5.10 Case Study on Belgian business succession practices

More information

Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture. Ian Sheldon AED Economics Agricultural Outlook. Wooster, OH January 31, 2018

Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture. Ian Sheldon AED Economics Agricultural Outlook. Wooster, OH January 31, 2018 Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture Ian Sheldon AED Economics 2018 Agricultural Outlook Wooster, OH January 31, 2018 U.S. Free Trade Agreements: Current Status Free trade agreements

More information

A Note on the Impact of Economic Reforms on the Performance of the Agriculture Sector in Latin America Daniel Lederman * Rodrigo Reis Soares **

A Note on the Impact of Economic Reforms on the Performance of the Agriculture Sector in Latin America Daniel Lederman * Rodrigo Reis Soares ** A Note on the Impact of Economic Reforms on the Performance of the Agriculture Sector in Latin America Daniel Lederman * Rodrigo Reis Soares ** Introduction Economic reforms in Latin America have been

More information

Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture. Ian Sheldon AED Economics Agricultural Outlook

Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture. Ian Sheldon AED Economics Agricultural Outlook Free Trade Agreements: Why They Matter to U.S. Agriculture Ian Sheldon AED Economics 2018 Agricultural Outlook Wakeman and Defiance, OH January 29, 2018 U.S. Free Trade Agreements: Current Status Free

More information

CHINA-US BORDER EFFECT OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE USING GRAVITY MODEL

CHINA-US BORDER EFFECT OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE USING GRAVITY MODEL CHINA-US BORDER EFFECT OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE USING GRAVITY MODEL Haixia Zhu 1,2,*, Haiying Gu 1 1 Antai School of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong Universy, Shanghai, P. R. China 200052 2 School

More information

FAO RICE CONFERENCE. Rome, Italy, February 2004 IMPLICATIONS OF THE WTO DOHA ROUND FOR THE RICE SECTOR

FAO RICE CONFERENCE. Rome, Italy, February 2004 IMPLICATIONS OF THE WTO DOHA ROUND FOR THE RICE SECTOR February 2004 FAO RICE CONFERENCE 04/CRS.4 E FAO RICE CONFERENCE Rome, Italy, 12-13 February 2004 IMPLICATIONS OF THE WTO DOHA ROUND FOR THE RICE SECTOR By: Eric J. Wailes L.C. Carter Professor, Department

More information

Rice Tariffication in Japan : A General Equilibrium Analysis

Rice Tariffication in Japan : A General Equilibrium Analysis Rice Tariffication in Japan : A General Equilibrium Analysis Masaru Kagatsume Ching-Cheng Cheng Chang Chia-Hsun Wu 1 Outline Introduction Overview the rice market in the world Japan s s Rice Import Policy

More information

ExportVersusFDI with Heterogeneous Firms

ExportVersusFDI with Heterogeneous Firms ExportVersusFDI with Heterogeneous Firms By ELHANAN HELPMAN, MARC J. MELITZ, AND STEPHEN R. YEAPLE Empirical Topics in the Economics of Location and Trade Prof.Brülhart Seminar Presentation Matthias Rieger

More information

Test Codes: QEA and QEB (Both are of 'Descriptive' type) (Junior Research Fellowship in Quantitative Economics)

Test Codes: QEA and QEB (Both are of 'Descriptive' type) (Junior Research Fellowship in Quantitative Economics) Test Codes: QEA and QEB (Both are of 'Descriptive' type) (Junior Research Fellowship in Quantitative Economics) The candidates for Junior Research Fellowship in Quantitative Economics are required to take

More information

Project on Organic Agriculture

Project on Organic Agriculture Department of Agricultural Economics Project on Organic Agriculture Number 7 January 2005 By Shon Ferguson and Simon Weseen The Economic Effect of Canada Making or Missing the EU 3 rd Country List: The

More information

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing Summary Freeing up resources so that they can be used more productively in other industries is the logic behind international

More information

Multilateral Trade Reforms Under Doha and Income Distribution in South Asia

Multilateral Trade Reforms Under Doha and Income Distribution in South Asia Multilateral Trade Reforms Under Doha and Income Distribution in South Asia Paper Presented to the Asia-Pacific Trade Economists Conference, Bangkok Associate Professor Department of Economics and Finance

More information

Trade Costs and Regional Productivity in Indian Manufacturing. Hanpil Moon

Trade Costs and Regional Productivity in Indian Manufacturing. Hanpil Moon Trade Costs and Regional Productivity in Indian Manufacturing Hanpil Moon Munisamy Gopinath Oregon State University Overview Motivation for spatial and firmheterogeneity in responses to trade cost changes

More information

Estimation of Aggregate Demand and Supply Shocks Using Commodity Transaction Data

Estimation of Aggregate Demand and Supply Shocks Using Commodity Transaction Data October 13, 2016 Estimation of Aggregate Demand and Supply Shocks Using Commodity Transaction Data Naohito Abe, Noriko Inakura, Akiyuki Tonogi 1 Consumer Price Index in Japan Revision of tax rate 27 22

More information

EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California

EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California Bradley J. Rickard, Assistant Professor, Agribusiness Department California Polytechnic State University, San

More information

Problem Set 1 (Gains From Trade and the Ricardian Model)

Problem Set 1 (Gains From Trade and the Ricardian Model) 14.581 Problem Set 1 (Gains From Trade and the Ricardian Model) Dave Donaldson February 16, 2011 Complete all questions (100 total marks). Due by Wednesday, March 9 to Sahar or Dave. 1. (10 marks) Consider

More information

Innovation and the Elasticity of Trade Volumes to Tariff Reductions

Innovation and the Elasticity of Trade Volumes to Tariff Reductions Innovation and the Elasticity of Trade Volumes to Tariff Reductions Loris Rubini Arizona State University May 11, 2010 Motivation What are the effects of tariff reductions on trade volumes and productivity?

More information

Agriculture & Agri Food. A Bright Future. Vincent Cloutier, agr. Chief Economist La Coop fédérée

Agriculture & Agri Food. A Bright Future. Vincent Cloutier, agr. Chief Economist La Coop fédérée Agriculture & Agri Food A Bright Future Vincent Cloutier, agr. Chief Economist La Coop fédérée Twitter: @vincentcloutie2 Drop in food prices really? FAO Food Price Index Source: FAO Megatrends World population

More information

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, 10 12 September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne Institutional quality and contract complexity: the effects on the intensive and extensive margins of trade

More information

Inattentive Importers

Inattentive Importers Inattentive Importers Kunal Dasgupta University of Toronto Jordi Mondria University of Toronto August 2014 Abstract Importers rarely observe the price of every good in every market because of information

More information

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017 Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017 This exam is designed to test your broad knowledge of microeconomics. There are three sections: one required and two choice sections. You must complete both problems

More information

2010 JOURNAL OF THE ASFMRA

2010 JOURNAL OF THE ASFMRA Impact of Hired Foreign Labor on Milk Production and Herd Size in the United States By Dwi Susanto, C. Parr Rosson, Flynn J. Adcock, and David P. Anderson Abstract Foreign labor has become increasingly

More information

FIRM PERFORMANCE AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE

FIRM PERFORMANCE AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 99 FIRM PERFORMANCE AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE - evidence from a small open economy Martin Andersson, Sara Johansson and Hans Lööf (CESIS) October 2007 Firm

More information

Costs of Foreign Currency Invoicing

Costs of Foreign Currency Invoicing Costs of Foreign Currency Invoicing Kazunobu Hayakawa (Institute of Developing Economies) Nuttawut Laksanapanyakul (Thailand Development Research Institute) Taiyo Yoshimi (Nanzan University) 2015/12/14

More information

CHAPTER 2. Demand and Supply

CHAPTER 2. Demand and Supply CHAPTER 2 Demand and Supply The Supply_and_demand model A model for understanding the determination of the price of quantity of a good sold on the market Two groups: buyers and sellers Types of Competition

More information

The impact of trade shocks on collective wage bargaining agreements 1

The impact of trade shocks on collective wage bargaining agreements 1 Powered by The final version of this paper was published by the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), Discussion Paper 11289, May 2016. http://cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=11289

More information

Why has US sorghum lost the market share in the Japanese market? Kazuyoshi Ishida and Jaime Malaga. Abstract

Why has US sorghum lost the market share in the Japanese market? Kazuyoshi Ishida and Jaime Malaga. Abstract 1 Why has US sorghum lost the market share in the Japanese market? Kazuyoshi Ishida and Jaime Malaga Abstract About 20 years ago, the United States had the largest market share of sorghum in the Japanese

More information

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Yizao Liu Assistant Professor Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Connecticut yizao.liu@uconn.edu Adam N. Rabinowitz Assistant

More information

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy. Final Exam Section 2 May 11 th 7:30 am-10:00 am HH 076

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy. Final Exam Section 2 May 11 th 7:30 am-10:00 am HH 076 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Final Exam Section 2 May 11 th 7:30 am-10:00 am HH 076 Grading Scale 5% - Attendance 8% - Homework (Drop the lowest grade) 7% - Quizzes (Drop the lowest grade)

More information

International trade and the division of labour

International trade and the division of labour Economics Working Paper Series 2015/028 International trade and the division of labour Kwok Tong Soo The Department of Economics Lancaster University Management School Lancaster LA1 4YX UK Authors All

More information

Firms, Quality Upgrading and Trade. Ian Sheldon The Ohio State University

Firms, Quality Upgrading and Trade. Ian Sheldon The Ohio State University Firms, Quality Upgrading and Trade Ian Sheldon The Ohio State University Presentation delivered at the 2013 Annual Meeting of the International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium (IATRC) Clearwater

More information

Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection on US Soybeans

Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection on US Soybeans Impacts of Possible Chinese Protection on US Soybeans By Farzad Taheripour Wallace E. Tyner GTAP Working Paper No. 83 February 2018 This research was funded by the U. Soybean Export Council. Impacts of

More information

Effects of Shifts in Industrial Compositions on Wages in Developing Countries: The Case of Mexican Cities and NAFTA *

Effects of Shifts in Industrial Compositions on Wages in Developing Countries: The Case of Mexican Cities and NAFTA * Effects of Shifts in Industrial Compositions on Wages in Developing Countries: The Case of Mexican Cities and NAFTA * Jian Mardukhi Job Market Paper (November 2009) Abstract Industrial or trade policy

More information

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3 More Tutorial at www.dumblittledoctor.com Microeconomics 1. To an economist, a good is scarce when: *a. the amount of the good available is less than the amount that people want when the good's price equals

More information

Impacts of Possible Chinese 25% Tariff on U.S. Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities

Impacts of Possible Chinese 25% Tariff on U.S. Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities 2nd Quarter 2018 33(2) Impacts of Possible Chinese 25% Tariff on U.S. Soybeans and Other Agricultural Commodities Farzad Taheripour and Wallace E. Tyner JEL Classifications: F13, F167, Q17 Keywords: International

More information

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 24: U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 24: U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 24: U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY AGEC 429 Lecture #24 U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY Free Trade: Long-time stated goal of U.S. agricultural policy - World trade

More information

Impact of Sino-Australia free trade Agreement s talks on China's dairy industry

Impact of Sino-Australia free trade Agreement s talks on China's dairy industry Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Agriculture and Agricultural Science Procedia 1 (2010) 469 476 International Conference on Agricultural Risk and Food Security 2010 Impact of Sino-Australia free

More information

Final Exam - Answers

Final Exam - Answers Page 1 of 8 December 20, 2000 Answer all questions. Write your answers in a blue book. Be sure to look ahead and budget your time. Don t waste time on parts of questions that you can t answer. Leave space

More information

A Note on Trade Costs and Distance

A Note on Trade Costs and Distance MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive A Note on Trade Costs and Distance Martina Lawless and Karl Whelan Central Bank of Ireland, University College Dublin August 2007 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5804/

More information

Chapter 8.B. Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications. Robert A. McDougall

Chapter 8.B. Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications. Robert A. McDougall Chapter 8.B Food and Agricultural Data Base: Local Modifications Robert A. McDougall 8.B.1 Overview Some local modifications were made to the agricultural and food products (AFP) dataset described in chapter

More information

Different Models in International Trade

Different Models in International Trade Master s Degree programme in Economics - Models and methods in economics and management Final Thesis Different Models in International Trade From the Krugman-Melitz framework to the new Addilog Theory

More information

THE AMBITIOUS U.S. TRADE AGENDA

THE AMBITIOUS U.S. TRADE AGENDA THE AMBITIOUS U.S. TRADE AGENDA Laurie Hueneke Director of International Trade Policy, Sanitary & Technical Issues USAHA Committee on Import Export San Diego, CA October 20, 2013 General Trade Overview

More information

Heterogeneous Multinational Firms and Productivity Gains from Falling FDI Barriers

Heterogeneous Multinational Firms and Productivity Gains from Falling FDI Barriers RIETI Discussion Paper Series 12-E-010 Heterogeneous Multinational Firms and Productivity Gains from Falling FDI Barriers Shawn ARITA University of Hawaii at Manoa TANAKA Kiyoyasu Institute of Developing

More information

TPP, TTIP & YOU: Good Things on the Horizon

TPP, TTIP & YOU: Good Things on the Horizon TPP, TTIP & YOU: Good Things on the Horizon American Farm Bureau Federation Veronica Nigh, Economist Iowa Economic Summit Monday, June 27, 2016 Agenda Making the Case for Trade TPP TTIP Lets get political,

More information

Latent Semantic Analysis. Hongning Wang

Latent Semantic Analysis. Hongning Wang Latent Semantic Analysis Hongning Wang CS@UVa VS model in practice Document and query are represented by term vectors Terms are not necessarily orthogonal to each other Synonymy: car v.s. automobile Polysemy:

More information

Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand. Data

Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand. Data Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Demand Aggregate (market) aggregate (market-level) quantity prices + characteristics (+advertising) distribution of demographics (optional) sample from distribution

More information

Understanding the impact of barriers to digital trade: Leveraging theories of factor mobility

Understanding the impact of barriers to digital trade: Leveraging theories of factor mobility 1) Overview Understanding the impact of barriers to digital trade: Leveraging theories of factor mobility A backlash against the globalization of Internet-based information industries by national governments

More information

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Cardiff Economics Working Papers Cardiff Economics Working Papers Working Paper No. E016/3 Gains from Variety? Product Differentiation and the Possibility of Losses from rade under Cournot Oligopoly with Free Entry David R. Collie pril

More information

Envy-free Pricing for Collaborative Consumption in Transportation Systems

Envy-free Pricing for Collaborative Consumption in Transportation Systems Envy-free Pricing for Collaborative Consumption in Transportation Systems Roger Lloret-Batlle, PhD Candidate. R. Jayakrishnan, Professor. Institute of Transportation Studies, Irvine. July 6 th 2017 SoCal

More information

Inattentive Importers

Inattentive Importers Kunal Dasgupta University of Toronto Jordi Mondria University of Toronto OCTOBER 2017 Abstract Information frictions prevent importers from observing the price of a good in every market. In this paper,

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Theory. Chapter 8: Game Theory and Imperfect Competition

Advanced Microeconomics Theory. Chapter 8: Game Theory and Imperfect Competition Advanced Microeconomics Theory Chapter 8: Game Theory and Imperfect Competition Outline Game Theory Tools Bertrand Model of Price Competition Cournot Model of Quantity Competition Product Differentiation

More information

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models 1 Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models This chapter introduces students to computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, a class of economic model that describes an economy as a whole and

More information

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models 1 Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models This chapter introduces students to computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, a class of economic model that describes an economy as a whole and

More information

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011 Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring 2011 Honors General Exam April 6, 2011 The exam has three sections: microeconomics (Questions 1 3), macroeconomics (Questions 4 6), and econometrics

More information

Analyzing the Impact of Chinese Wheat Support Policies on U.S. and Global Wheat Production, Trade and Prices

Analyzing the Impact of Chinese Wheat Support Policies on U.S. and Global Wheat Production, Trade and Prices Analyzing the Impact of Chinese Wheat Support Policies on U.S. and Global Wheat Production, Trade and Prices A Study Prepared for the U.S. Wheat Associates Miguel Carriquiry and Amani Elobeid Global Agricultural

More information

Volume 35, Issue 2. Loris Rubini Universidad Catolica de Chile and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Volume 35, Issue 2. Loris Rubini Universidad Catolica de Chile and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Volume 35, Issue 2 Productivity and Trade Liberalizations in Canada Loris Rubini Universidad Catolica de Chile and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Abstract I study the evolution of productivity in Canada

More information

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Journal of Logistics Management 017, 6(): 35-40 DOI: 10.593/j.logistics.017060.01 Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Aika Monden Graduate School of

More information

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation

Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Effects of Openness and Trade in Pollutive Industries on Stringency of Environmental Regulation Matthias Busse and Magdalene Silberberger* Ruhr-University of Bochum Preliminary version Abstract This paper

More information

Selection, Agriculture, and the Gains from Trade

Selection, Agriculture, and the Gains from Trade Selection, Agriculture, and the Gains from Trade Douglas Gollin David Lagakos Michael E. Waugh Williams College Arizona State University New York University July 7, 2011 1/25 Y/N Differences Large in Agriculture,

More information

Trade Impacts of Common Agricultural Policy

Trade Impacts of Common Agricultural Policy Trade Impacts of Common Agricultural Policy Alan Matthews, Luca Salvatici, and Margherita Scoppola Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium s

More information

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods Mark R. Jacobsen, 1,5 Christopher R. Knittel, 2,5 James M. Sallee, 3,5 Arthur A. van Benthem 4,5 December 8, 2014

More information

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe Fall 2010 Contents 1 Motivation 2 2 The Krugman and Venables (1995) model 2 2.1 Key assumptions...................................

More information

Econometric Models of Car Market Entry Games

Econometric Models of Car Market Entry Games Econometric Models of Car Market Entry Games Bulat Sultanov 1[0000 0002 8657 6793], Railya Bahitova [0000 0002 7237 4306], and Elvira Shakirova [0000 0002 8711 4048] Bashkir State University, Ufa, Russia,

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Demand for U.S. Soybeans in the Philippines

An Empirical Analysis of Demand for U.S. Soybeans in the Philippines An Empirical Analysis of Demand for U.S. Soybeans in the Philippines Jewelwayne S. Cain Graduate Research Assistant Department of Agricultural & Applied Economics University of Missouri 143-C Mumford Hall

More information

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK. University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics Field Exam January 2017 Labor Economics There are three parts of the exam. Please answer all three parts. You should plan to spend about one hour

More information

Output Cost of Gender Discrimination in the Korean Labour Market *

Output Cost of Gender Discrimination in the Korean Labour Market * Output Cost of Gender Discrimination in the Korean Labour Market * Hanol Lee # Korea University Latest update: May 2017 Abstract This study constructs and calibrates a macroeconomic model that explains

More information

Trade Liberalization, Technology and Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from India. Rana Hasan 1. Devashish Mitra 2. Asha Sundaram 3

Trade Liberalization, Technology and Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from India. Rana Hasan 1. Devashish Mitra 2. Asha Sundaram 3 Trade Liberalization, Technology and Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from India Rana Hasan 1 Devashish Mitra 2 Asha Sundaram 3 Preliminary Draft December 2016 ABSTRACT. This paper looks at the impact of

More information

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. Understanding UPP Roy J. Epstein and Daniel L. Rubinfeld Published Version, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Policies and Perspectives, Volume 10, Issue 1, 2010 Introduction The standard economic

More information

THE ROLE OF INCOME GROWTH IN EMERGING MARKETS AND THE BRICS IN AGRIFOOD TRADE

THE ROLE OF INCOME GROWTH IN EMERGING MARKETS AND THE BRICS IN AGRIFOOD TRADE THE ROLE OF INCOME GROWTH IN EMERGING MARKETS AND THE BRICS IN AGRIFOOD TRADE CATPRN Working Paper 2009-02 February 2009 Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow Karl Meilke Professor Department of Food, Agricultural

More information

2010 Merger Guidelines: Empirical Analysis. Jerry Hausman, MIT 1

2010 Merger Guidelines: Empirical Analysis. Jerry Hausman, MIT 1 2010 Merger Guidelines: Empirical Analysis Jerry Hausman, MIT 1 Empirical analysis of mergers has advanced significantly since the 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines were issued. 2 In particular, direct

More information

Individual and Market Demand

Individual and Market Demand C H A P T E R 4 Individual and Market Demand Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano CHAPTER 4 OUTLINE 4.1 Individual Demand 4.2 Income and Substitution Effects 4.3 Market Demand 4.4 Consumer Surplus 4.5

More information