Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities"

Transcription

1 Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities (Original title: Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution) July 2009 Geoffrey Heal a, Nori Tarui b abstract This paper studies incentives to develop advanced pollution abatement technology when technology may spillover across agents and pollution abatement is a public good. We are motivated by a variety of pollution control issues where solutions require the development and implementation of new pollution abatement technologies. We show that at the Nash equilibrium of a simultaneous-move game with R&D investment and emission abatement, whether the free rider effect prevails and under-investment and excess emissions occur depends on the degree of technology spillovers and the effect of R&D on the marginal abatement costs. There are cases in which, contrary to conventional wisdom, Nash equilibrium investments in emissions reductions exceed the first-best case. Classification: Q50, H87, D70 Keywords: International environmental agreement; pollution abatement costs; endogenous technological change. a Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 616 Uris Hall, New York, NY 10027, USA. gmh1@columbia.edu. b Corresponding author, Department of Economics, University of Hawaii at Manoa, 2424 Maile Way, Honolulu, HI 96822, USA. nori@hawaii.edu, phone: , fax:

2 Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities (Original title: Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution) abstract This paper studies incentives to develop advanced pollution abatement technology when technology may spillover across agents and pollution abatement is a public good. We are motivated by a variety of pollution control issues where solutions require the development and implementation of new pollution abatement technologies. We show that at the Nash equilibrium of a simultaneous-move game with R&D investment and emission abatement, whether the free rider effect prevails and under-investment and excess emissions occur depends on the degree of technology spillovers and the effect of R&D on the marginal abatement costs. There are cases in which, contrary to conventional wisdom, Nash equilibrium investments in emissions reductions exceed the first-best case. Classification: Q50, H87, D70 Keywords: International environmental agreement; pollution abatement costs; endogenous technological change.

3 1 Introduction Controlling pollution is a public good in many cases, within or across countries, where effective control requires the development of a new technology. The control of ozone-depleting chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs) is a notable example where the removal required a novel technological development (i.e. less harmful substitutes for CFCs, Barrett 1992); the control of sulfur dioxide (SO 2 ) emissions that caused acid rain also had these characteristics, and the last two decades have seen many technological changes in the capturing of SO 2 emissions (Popp 2006). A current example is the release of greenhouse gases causing climate change, as is the emission of nitrogen oxides (NO x ), which contribute to acid rain, climate change and acidification of water bodies. Development of new technologies would be necessary for mitigating not only air pollution but water pollution and hazardous waste. Pollution of coastal water, and resulting damages to the coastal ecosystems, caused by runoffs of sediments and fertilizers is an example of non-air pollution where technology innovation for abatement is called for (National Research Council 2000, Chapter 9). It is for this reason the necessity of technology innovation that researchers argue that understanding the interactions between environmental policy and technology may have quantitatively important consequences in the context of cost-benefit or cost-effectiveness analyses of such policies (Popp et al. 2009). In the context of pollution control where pollution generates negative externalities, We examine how the effect of technological innovation on the cost structure of emission abatement influences the agents incentives to reduce emissions and to invest in R&D in new technologies. To analyze these issues, we use a simultaneous-move game of emissions reduction and R&D investments where each agent acts noncooperatively. We hope that the intuitions we develop here can be valuable in managing the R&D process and structuring collective action or international agreements for pollution control. Most studies on emission control and technological innovation predict that scenarios without policy intervention involve excessive emissions and insufficient R&D relative to the first best levels. It is not widely recognized that a crucial assumption behind this prediction is that the marginal abatement cost decreases as technology improves. In fact this need not be the case: we provide examples of technological changes which imply smaller total abatement costs but larger marginal abatement costs. Using a simultaneous-move game of 1

4 emissions reduction and R&D investments, we find that the equilibrium R&D investment can be larger than the first best level in these examples. In the context of transboundary pollution, technological innovation is often induced by an international environmental agreement (IEA). In some cases, IEAs explicitly encourage the signatories to cooperate in R&D. 1 Several studies have examined how technology spillovers influence countries cooperation in providing global public goods. 2 Carraro and Siniscalco (1997) analyze the stability of IEAs assuming that the signatories conduct R&D to develop a cleaner technology which is unavailable to non-signatories. Buchner et al. (2002) study the stability of climate change mitigation cooperation across countries when technology spillovers within cooperating countries are larger than spillovers from cooperating countries to non-cooperating countries. Barrett (2003) raises two questions about their approach (pp ). First, it is often difficult to prevent technology diffusion once new technology is developed. Second, given that a cleaner technology is developed and signatories environmental damage is increasing in non-signatories emissions, the signatories may have an incentive to allow the non-signatories to use the cleaner technology so that the global emissions decline. Barret (2003) also argues that no existing IEAs prevent the non-signatories from using new technology developed by the signatories. For example, the Montreal Protocol requires that parties cooperate in promoting R&D for a technology that reduces controlled substances, where non-parties are allowed easy access to new technologies by the parties (Barret 2003, pp ) Indeed, there is a stronger argument against the idea that new technologies will not spill over: this is that the companies that develop them will want to sell them worldwide as part of a profit-maximization strategy. General Electric is aggressively promoting its carbon capture and storage technologies worldwide, though they were developed in the U.S. To investigate agents incentive for emission control and investments, we consider a simultaneous-move game where the agents choose investments and emissions simultaneously 1 Examples include a six-country pact for developing technology to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. See Vision Statement of Australia, China, India, Japan, the Republic of Korea, and the U.S. for a New Asia-Pacific Partnership on Clean Development and Climate, available at 2 Heal (1993) and Barrett (2003) argue that abatement efforts and technology change in one country may reduce the marginal abatement costs in other countries and the first-best outcome may be supported once a sufficient number of countries adopt higher environmental standards. 2

5 when both technology and pollution spill over across agents. We find the following (see Table 1). 1. If each agent s marginal abatement cost is decreasing in R&D investment, then the Nash equilibrium investments are lower and the equilibrium emissions are larger than the first-best levels. This result holds regardless of the degree of technology spillovers among agents. This is the conventional wisdom case. 2. If the marginal abatement costs are increasing in investment, then the equilibrium results in over-(under-)investment when the degree of spillovers is small (large) enough. With large technology spillovers, emissions may be less than in the first best case. This case is contrary to conventional wisdom. The first point is consistent with Golombek and Hoel (2004), who have the same finding under the assumptions listed above. The second point implies that whether the first claim holds depends on the relationship between R&D and the marginal abatement costs. Section 2 discusses cases in which marginal abatement costs may increase under a new technology. Intuitively we can see why the movement of marginal abatement costs (MACs) is important. Suppose that technological development leads to an abatement technology with lower fixed and higher variable costs, and lower average costs we will suggest below that this accurately describes one of the main technologies now being developed, that of carbon capture and storage. Then the lower fixed costs have an income effect which will typically lead to the choice of more abatement. However, the higher MAC produces a substitution effect that acts in the opposite direction. Higher MAC also implies that the marginal reduction in abatement costs due to investment is larger when emissions are larger. When technology spillovers are small, this fact implies that both the equilibrium investment and the equilibrium emissions are larger than the socially optimal levels. When technology spillovers are large, however, each agent s incentive for investment is smaller. In such a situation it is not clear whether the outcome will be more or less abatement. This is true for both the socially optimal allocation and the Nash equilibrium allocation, but it is stronger for the first best case and so tends to reduce abatement more, reduce emissions less, in this case. This opens up the possibility that the equilibrium emissions may be less than the first best, as 3

6 equilibrium abatement is reduced less. We show below that this can happen when spillovers are large: large spillovers tend of course to counteract the standard arguments about free riders and public goods. Large spillovers provide income effects to all agents, similarly to lower fixed costs. This explains why we find counterintuitive outcomes with small income effects. [Table 1] The next section discusses examples of technologies where the marginal abatement cost may decrease or increase as a result of technology innovation. Section 3 describes the assumption of our analysis, the result, and discussions regarding alternative assumptions. Section 4 concludes the paper with policy implications. 2 Technology innovation and marginal abatement costs The relationship between marginal abatement costs and R&D is central to some of our results. We expect, of course, that abatement costs will fall as a result of successful R&D that is in effect the definition of success in R&D. Presumably we mean the total cost of attaining a given level of abatement falls, but this leaves open the impact of R&D on the fixed and variable costs of reducing emissions. In principle, successful R&D can introduce a new technology whose cost structure is totally different from that of the current technology. The current technology may for example have high fixed and low variable costs, whereas the new one has low fixed costs and high variable costs. In this case the total and average costs would be lower but the marginal abatement cost might be higher with the new technology. These issues are discussed to some degree in Baker et al. (2006, 2008), who consider the effect of uncertainty about the costs of climate change on the optimal spending on R&D: they find that the abatement cost curve can change in many different ways as a result of R&D, depending on the parameters of the model. Bauman (2003) and Brechet and Jouvet (2006) also present theoretical models which demonstrate that the marginal abatement cost may be higher with new technology. The Economics of Climate Change (Stern Review, 2006) also notes that step-change improvements in a technology might accelerate progress [of declining marginal costs], while constraints such as the availability of land or materials could result in increasing marginal costs (Executive Summary, p.xx). 4

7 Researchers are currently investigating many different technologies for CO2 abatement. Integrated combined cycle coal gasification (ICCCG) with carbon capture and storage is one possibility: coal combustion with cryogenic oxygen and carbon capture and storage is another, and the use of renewable energy sources and nuclear power represent yet more alternatives. If we think of renewable energy and nuclear as the current abatement technologies, and ICCCG with C-capture and storage as a possible new technology, then the change in cost structures in going from the old to the new technologies is instructive. Renewable energy sources and nuclear have high fixed costs but almost no variable costs, so that the marginal cost of abatement along this route is close to zero even though the average is high. ICCCG with C-capture and storage, by contrast, would have high marginal costs: each ton of CO2 has to be captured (perhaps $5 per ton) and then transported (perhaps $10 per ton) and stored (perhaps $5 per ton). We would not use this technology unless its average cost were less than renewables, but if we used it we would face a higher marginal cost. 3 3 A game with pollution and technology externalities 3.1 Assumptions, the optimal outcome, and the symmetric Nash equilibrium Suppose N agents choose R&D investments and emissions for developing abatement technology. Let (k i, e i ) 0 be agent i s investment and emissions choice. Agent i s cost of investing k i is given by G(k i ) 0 where G > 0, G 0. 4 When the agents investment profile is k = (k 1,..., k N ), agent i s cost of reducing emissions from its status-quo level ē > 0 to a level e i 0 is given by C(e i, z i (k)) 0 where z i (k) = k i + λ j i k j. The function z i represents the effective amount of abatement capital available to agent i given investment profile k. The exogenous parameter λ [0, 1] represents the extent of innovation spillovers across agents. There is no technology diffusion and R&D is a private good if λ = 0. With complete spillovers, λ is equal to one. The abatement cost function 3 We are grateful to Klaus Lackner for an instructive discussion of these issues. 4 We have G(k) = k provided that pollution control costs, damages, and investment costs are measured with the same metric. We have G > 0 if there is inefficiency in using resources for investment. We thank a referee for clarifying the role of function G. 5

8 C is twice continuously differentiable and convex with C e < 0, C z < 0, C ee > 0, C zz > 0 for all e < ē. (Subscripts stand for partial derivatives.) We assume C ez is positive, zero, or negative. The marginal abatement cost C e is decreasing in investment if C ez > 0. Given total emissions E = j e j, agent i s damage is D(E) 0 where D > 0 and D > 0. We assume that the agents choose investment and emissions simultaneously. The main result of the paper will hold if the agents choose investment and emissions sequentially (i.e. they choose investment simultaneously first, and then emissions simultaneously). The first-best investment emission and allocation {ki, e i } minimizes the social cost of emissions i [G(k i) + C(e i, z i (k)) + D(E)]. The first order condition for an interior solution is G (k i ) + C z(e i, k i + λ j i k j ) + j i λc z(e j, k j + λ l j k l ) = 0, C e (e i, k i + j i k j ) + ND ( j e j ) = 0 for i = 1,...,N. The symmetric solution where (k i, e i ) = (k j, e j ) (k, e ) for all i, j I satisfies G (k ) + f(λ)c z (e, f(λ)k ) = 0, (1) C e (e, f(λ)k ) + ND (Ne ) = 0 (2) where f(λ) 1 + (N 1)λ. Similarly, an interior Nash equilibrium { k i, ê i } satisfies G ( k i ) + C z (ê i, k i + λ j i k j ) = 0, C e (ê i, k i + λ j i k j ) + D ( j êj) = 0 for all i. The symmetric Nash equilibrium (ê, k) where ( k i, ê i ) = ( k, ê) for all i satisfies G ( k) + C z (ê, f(λ) k) = 0, (3) C e (ê, f(λ) k) + D (Nê) = 0. (4) Under the assumptions on C and D, we can solve conditions (2) and (4) for emissions as a function of investment in the first best allocation and in the Nash equilibrium. Call these functions e f and e n. (Superscript f stands for the first best and n for Nash equilibrium. Note that e f (k ) = e and e n ( k) = ê.) Similarly, define k f (e) and k n (e) to be the investment solutions to conditions (1) and (3) as functions of emissions under the first best solution and the Nash equilibrium, respectively. These functions will prove useful when comparing the optimal and the equilibrium quantities of investments and emissions. They satisfy the following property. (See the appendix for the proofs.) 6

9 Lemma 1 The functions defined above satisfy e n (k) > e f (k) for all k > 0 and k n (e) < k f (e) for all e > 0. Lemma 2 The derivatives def dk, den dk, dkf de, dkn de are all negative if C ez > 0, all positive if C ez < 0, and are all zero if C ez = 0. Lemma 3 The equilibrium investment by each agent is decreasing in the degree of technology spillovers λ (i.e. k λ < 0). The first-best investment by each agent may be decreasing or increasing in technology spillovers. The equilibrium and the first best emissions are nonincreasing (increasing) in λ if C ez > (<)0. The equilibrium emissions are independent of λ if G = 0. Lemma 1 states that, given the same investment level, the Nash equilibrium emission is larger than the first best level. Similarly, the equilibrium investment is lower than the first best level given the same emission level. These results hold regardless of whether marginal abatement costs are decreasing in investment. Both the equilibrium and the first best emissions are decreasing (increasing) in investment if the marginal abatement cost is decreasing (increasing) in investment (Lemma 2). The last part of lemma 3 indicates that k/ λ < 0 while ê/ λ = 0 (i.e. the equilibrium emissions are independent of λ) when G = 0. This can be explained in two ways. First, taking λ as a parameter, we can take the total derivative of e n ( k(λ); λ) with respect to λ to identify the effect of changes in λ on ê: de n ( k(λ); λ) dλ = en ( k(λ); λ) λ + en ( k(λ); λ) d k(λ) k dλ = A C ez B C ez d k(λ) dλ, where A, B are positive. 5 The first term on the right-hand side represents the direct effect of changes in λ on e n while the second term represents the indirect effect of λ through its effect on k. Both effects depend on the sign of C ez. If C ez > 0, then the direct effect implies that, holding k constant, an increase in λ increases the effective capital z = (1+λ(N 1))k available to each agent. Then the marginal abatement costs decrease and hence the equilibrium emissions decrease. The indirect effect works in the opposite direction: an increase in λ 5 Total differentiation of condition (4) with respect to e, k, and λ yields the above expression for den ( k(λ);λ) dλ where A (N 1) k/(c ee + ND ) and B f(λ)/(c ee + ND ). 7

10 reduces the equilibrium investment (the first part of lemma 3), which increases the marginal abatement costs given C ez > 0 and hence the equilibrium emissions. The directions of the direct and indirect effects are oppositive if C ez < 0. Regardless of the sign of C ez, it turns out that these effects cancel each other exactly and hence ê/ λ = 0. The second way to verify ê/ λ = 0 given G = 0 is to look at the conditions for the symmetric Nash equilibrium (3) and (4) given G = 0: r + C z (ê, ẑ) = 0, C e (ê, ẑ) + D (Nê) = 0, where r G > 0 and ẑ f(λ) k. The solutions to these conditions ê and ẑ are independent of λ: That is, the equilibrium quantity of effective capital and emissions are independent of the degree of technology spillovers. Hence, we observe that ê and ẑ stay constant as λ changes while each agent s equilibrium investment k = ẑ 1+λ(N 1) falls as λ increases. See section 3.3 for an example where the first-best investment may decrease when the degree of technology spillovers increases. 3.2 Main results The following proposition is based on the three lemmas and compares the first best solution and the Nash equilibrium outcome of the game where agents choose investment and emissions simultaneously. Proposition 1 Let {k, e } be the first best investment and emission of each agent and { k, ê} be the symmetric Nash equilibrium. (i) If C ez > 0, then ê > e and k < k for all λ [0, 1]. (ii) If C ez = 0 and λ = 0, then ê > e and k = k. If C ez = 0 and λ > 0, then ê > e and k < k. (iii) If C ez < 0 and if the following inequality holds: 0 λ < 1 N 1 [ C z (e n ( k), f(λ) k) C z (e f ( k), f(λ) k) 1 ], (5) then k > k and ê > e. If (5) does not hold, then k k (but ê may or may not exceed e ). If C ez > 0, then ê < e if and only if C e (ê, f(λ)k n (ê)) C e (ê, f(λ)k f (ê)) > (N 1)D (Nê). (6) 8

11 The proposition states that the equilibrium emission is larger than the first best level if the marginal abatement cost is nonincreasing in investment (C ez 0) or if the spillover effect is small. If the marginal abatement cost is decreasing in investment (C ez > 0), then the equilibrium investment is smaller than the first best level regardless of the spillover effect λ. If C ez = 0, then the equilibrium investment is the same as the first best level under no spillover while under-investment occurs under spillovers. If the marginal abatement cost is increasing in investment (C ez < 0), then over-investment occurs when spillovers and the number of agents are small while under-investment occurs when spillovers or the number of agents are large. Larger marginal abatement costs imply larger ex-post optimal emissions and hence larger damages to each agent. With the marginal abatement costs increasing in investments, each agent s equilibrium investment exceeds the socially optimal level when technology spillovers are small (i.e. when condition 5 holds). Part (i) has been demonstrated in literature (e.g. Golombek and Hoel 2004) and perhaps not surprising. We explain part (iii) graphically by assuming C ez < 0 (Figures 1 and 2). Figure 1 contrasts a representative agent s optimal and equilibrium emission and investment choice. The figure also assumes λ = 0, and hence the only source of externality is emissions. While the marginal abatement cost of each agent equals the social (aggregate) marginal damages of all agents under the optimal outcome, the equilibrium emission equates the marginal abatement cost and the private marginal damages for each agent (panel b). The assumption C ze C ez < 0 implies that the marginal benefit of investment (i.e. the marginal reduction in abatement cost due to investment) is smaller under smaller emissions (see panel a), and hence the equilibrium investment exceeds the first best level. Lemma 3 implies that de /dλ > 0 and dê/dλ = 0 given C ez < 0 and G = 0. These facts open up the possibility that ê becomes lower than e for λ sufficiently large. Figure 2 illustrates a case where condition (6) holds and hence the equilibrium emission is lower than the first best level. Given λ > 0, technology spillover is an additional source of externality. The spillovers tend to lower the equilibrium investment relative to the first best level. With λ sufficiently large, the equilibrium investment ˆk is lower than the first best level k and hence the marginal abatement cost curve given ˆk lies to the left of the marginal abatement cost curve given k. Therefore, as in Figure 2(b), the equilibrium emission (given by the intersection of the marginal abatement cost given ˆk and the private marginal damage) can 9

12 fall below the first best emission (given by the intersection of the marginal abatement cost given k and the social marginal damage). 6 A remark regarding part (iii) is that condition (5) holds (and hence k > k ) if λ = 0 or if λ is small. In contrast, condition (6) (and hence ê < e ) may not hold even if λ is large. The following example illustrates that the conditions under which (6) may in fact be limited. [Figure 1] 3.3 Example [Figure 2] The following example illustrates the result of Proposition 1: G(k) = k, C(e, z) = f(z) + a(z)(ē e) + b(z) 2 (ē e)2, D(E) = d 2 E2, (7) where the quantity ē > 0 represents the emission level in the absence of abatement, and ē e the abatement level. The linear-quadratic cost specification has been used in many studies including Karp (2006). The function f represents the fixed cost of emission abatement. As explained in the previous section, f may be decreasing or increasing in the effective capital z. We assume f is strictly convex. At an emission level e [0, ē], the marginal abatement cost is given by a(z)+b(z)(ē e) and its derivative with respect to investment is a (z)+b (z)(ē e). For simplicity, assume f(z) = f 0 f 1 z + f 2 2 z2, a(z) = az, b(z) b, (8) for all z 0 where f 2 and b are positive while f 1 and a may be positive or negative. New technology results in either lower marginal abatement cost, lower fixed cost of abatement, or both. If a < 0, then investment results in smaller marginal abatement cost. If f 1 > 0 and a > 0, then investment results in technologies with lower fixed costs and larger marginal abatement cost. Convexity of C requires bf 2 a 2 0. Provided bf 2 a 2 = 0, condition (6) for under-emissions for this example is given by f 1 < N 1 f(λ) N 1. (9) 6 Though the figure assumes that G = 0, the argument is also valid when G > 0. 10

13 The necessary and sufficient condition for the equilibrium emission to be interior is 1 < f 1. The right-hand side of condition (9) decreases monotonically as N increases, and converges to 1. Therefore, condition (9) does not hold if f 1 is large or if N is large. [Figure 3] Figure 3 illustrates part (iii) of Proposition 1 using the above example with N = 2, a = 1, b = 1, d =.75, f 1 = 2, f 2 = 1, ē =.5. These parameter values satisfy C ez < 0 and bf 2 a 2 = 0, but do not satisfy condition (9). With small technology spillovers, the equilibrium investment level is larger than the optimal level while the equilibrium emissions are always larger than the optimal level. Figure 4 assumes the same parameter values as Figure 3 except for a smaller value of f 1 such that condition (9) (for ê > e ) holds. With large technology spillovers, the equilibrium emissions, as well as the equilibrium investment levels, are smaller than the optimal levels. As Proposition 1 indicates, the equilibrium emission exceeds the optimal level whenever the equilibrium investment is larger than the optimal level. [Figure 4] 3.4 Investment and emissions under alternative assumptions We discuss the results under alternative assumptions. We assumed that the agents choose investment and emissions simultaneously. It might be more natural to assume that the agents choose investment first and then emissions. The result about over-investment under increasing marginal abatement cost holds under the alternative assumption of sequential move. Though we present our result in the context of transboundary pollution with countries as players, our analysis has an implication to domestic environmental regulation with a regulator and regulated firms as players. A large number of studies have compared regulated firms incentive for technology innovation and adoption under alternative emission regulation (such as emissions quantity standards, emissions taxes, and emissions trading, see Milliman and Prince 1989, Requate et al. 2003, Jaffe et al. 2003). A number of studies have found that, when the regulator sets emissions standards or emissions taxes after the firms conduct 11

14 investment, the regulated firms have an incentive to over-invest (relative to the optimal level) under taxes and under-invest under standards (Malik 1991, Kennedy and Laplante 1999, Karp and Zhang 2002, Moledina et al. 2003, Tarui and Polasky 2006). These studies assume that the marginal abatement costs are decreasing in investment. If the marginal abatement costs are increasing investment, then the opposite incentive will work under taxes and standards. Baker et al. (2008) present a thorough summary of the implications of the increasing marginal abatement costs and provide a raking of alternative emission policy instruments under the assumption. The analysis in this section assumed that the agents are identical. A more realistic model would assume that agents differ in abatement costs and pollution damage functions. With heterogeneity, the equilibrium investment (emission) of some agents may be larger (lower) than the first best level even if the marginal abatement cost is decreasing in investment. This possibility is analogous to the free-rider problem associated with the private provision of public goods: with heterogenous players, those who would benefit most (less) from public goods may contribute more (less) to the supply of public goods. 7 4 Discussion This paper studied agents incentives to reduce emissions of pollutants and develop a new emission abatement technology when technology diffusion across agents may occur and emission reduction is a public good. If the marginal abatement cost of each agent is decreasing in investment, then the Nash equilibrium results in excessive emissions and under-investment in innovation relative to the first-best under any degree of technology spillovers. The equilibrium results in over-investment when spillovers are small enough and if the marginal abatement cost is increasing in investment. Our study is motivated by a variety of pollution issues where a comprehensive solution needs new technologies, solving the problem is providing a global public good, and the tradeoffs we model here are central to policy choices about funding R&D and, in the context of transboundary pollution, about treaty formats regarding coordination on emission control 7 For example, let N = 2 and consider a simple emission game (without investment decisions): C i (e i ) = (1 e i) 2 2, D i (E) = di 2 E2 for i = 1, 2. With parameter values (d 1, d 2 ) = (0.25, 1), the equilibrium emissions are Ê 0.89, ê , ê while the efficient quantities are E 0.58, e 1 = e We have ê 2 < e 2 : player 2 s equilibrium emission is smaller than the optimal level. 12

15 and technology innovation. Our finding implies that the direction to which the incentives for investments and emission reduction are biased depends on the types of technologies involved and the degree of technology spillovers. In particular, the transitions from one pollution abatement technology to another do not necessarily justify subsidizing it even if the emission causes a negative externality. Though the model applies to transboundary pollution and technology spillovers across countries, the implication extends to environmental regulation on industries in a domestic context as well (see section 3.4). We did not consider several important aspects of investments and emission reduction in international and national contexts such as government-industry interactions (firms incentive to innovate given costly R&D and/or patenting or licensing opportunities given imperfect appropriability of innovation), heterogeneity among agents, and dynamics (changes in technology, pollution stock, and in the context of transboundary pollution, treaty participation over time). We assumed deterministic innovation. 8 Though some of these issues are discussed in the previous section, further analysis is left for future research. Appendix Proof of Lemma 1 We have C e (e n (k), f(λ)k)+nd (Ne n (k)) = C e (e n (k), f(λ)k)+d (Ne n (k))+(n 1)D (Ne n (k)) > 0 for all k > 0 by condition (4). Because C e + ND is increasing in emissions, it follows that e n (k) > e f (k) for all k > 0. Similarly, for all e > 0 we have G (k n (e))+f(λ)c z (e, f(λ)k n (e)) = G (k n (e))+c z (e, f(λ)k n (e))+λ(n 1)C z (e, f(λ)k n (e)) < 0 because the sum of the first two terms is zero (condition 3) while the last term is negative. Because G (k) + f(λ)c z (e, f(λ)k) is increasing in investment, the above inequality implies k n (e) < k f (e) for all e > 0. 8 For the analysis of IEAs with stochastic technological change, see Kolstad (2007). 13

16 Proof of Lemma 2 Totally differentiate condition (2) with respect to e and k to obtain C ee de + f(λ)c ez dk + N 2 D de = 0, i.e. de f dk = f(λ)c ez C ee + N 2 D which is positive if C ez < 0 and negative if C ez > 0. Similarly, total differentiation of condition (4) yields C ee dê + f(λ)c ez dk + ND dê = 0, i.e. de n dk = f(λ)c ez C ee + ND which is positive if C ez < 0 and negative if C ez > 0. Totally differentiate condition (1) with respect to e and k to obtain G dk + f(λ)c ze de + f(λ) 2 C zz dk = 0, i.e. dk f de = f(λ)c ze G + f(λ) 2 C zz which is positive if C ez < 0 and negative if C ez > 0. Similarly, total differentiation of condition (3) yields G dk + C ze de + f(λ)c zz dk = 0, i.e. dk n de = C ze G + f(λ)c zz, which is positive if C ez < 0 and negative if C ez > 0. Proof of Lemma 3 Differentiate the equations (3) and (4) with respect to λ and obtain G + f(λ)c zz C ze ) ( f(λ)c ez C ee + ND = ( k λ ê λ f (λ) kc zz f (λ) kc ez ). Applying Cramer s Rule, we have ê λ = f (λ) kg C ez, A k λ = f (λ) k [{C ee C zz Cez 2 } + NC zzd ] A where A G (C ee + ND ) + f(λ){c ee C zz C 2 ez} + Nf(λ)C zz D > 0. 14

17 Therefore, ê λ ( )0 if C ez ( )0. The equilibrium investment is decreasing in λ ( k λ < 0) regardless of the sign of C ez. Similarly, differentiate the equations (1) and (2) with respect to λ and obtain G + f 2 C zz fc ze ( k ) ( ) fc ez C ee + N 2 D f = C z ff k C zz f k. C ez Solving for k λ e and, we have λ e λ = f C ez [G k fc z ], B where λ e λ k λ = f C z (C ee + N 2 D ) ff k [{C ee C zz Cez 2 } + N2 C zz D ] B B G (C ee + N 2 D ) + f 2 {C ee C zz C 2 ez} + f 2 N 2 C zz D > 0. Therefore, e < (>)0 if C λ ez > (<)0. The sign of k λ is indeterminate. Proof of Proposition 1 To show (i), suppose C ez > 0. As in the proof of lemma 3, the first best investment k satisfies F (k ) G (k ) + f(λ)c z (e f (k ), f(λ)k ) = 0. Similarly, the equilibrium investment k satisfies F( k) G ( k) + C z (e n ( k), f(λ) k) = 0. Note that def dk < 0 and den dk < 0 by lemma 2 and C ez > 0. For any k 0 we have F (k) F(k) = f(λ)c z (e f (k), f(λ)k) C z (e n (k), f(λ)k) C z (e f (k), f(λ)k) C z (e n (k), f(λ)k) where the last inequality follows from C z < 0 and f(λ) 1 for all λ [0, 1]. Because C ze > 0 by assumption and e f (k) < e n (k) by lemma 1, we have C z (e f (k), f(λ)k) C z (e n (k), f(λ)k) < 0. Hence, k (that satisfies F( k) = 0) must be smaller than k (that satisfies F (k ) = 0) regardless of the value of λ. Finally, k < k implies ê = e n ( k) > e n (k ) > e f (k ) = e. To show (ii), suppose C ez = 0. Then conditions (1) and (2) are equivalent to G (k ) + f(λ)φ k (f(λ)k ) = 0, (10) 15

18 φ e (e ) + ND (Ne ) = 0 where φ k (z) C z (e, z) for all e, z and φ e (e) C e (e, z) for all e, z. These two conditions determine the first best invest and emission independently. Similarly, conditions (3) and (4) for the Nash equilibrium are equivalent to G ( k) + φ k (f(λ) k) = 0, (11) φ e (ê) + D (Nê) = 0. Lemma 1 implies ê > e for any λ. If λ = 0, then conditions (10) and (11) are identical and hence k = k. If λ > 0, then G (k) + φ k (f(λ)k) = G (k) + f(λ)φ k (f(λ)k) (f(λ) 1)φ k (f(λ)k) > G (k) + f(λ)φ k (f(λ)k) for all k because φ k < 0. If follows from G + φ k > 0 that k < k. To show (iii), suppose C ez < 0. If λ = 0, then F (k) F(k) = C z (e f (k), k) C z (e n (k), k) where e f (k) < e n (k) for all k by lemma 1. Because C ze < 0, we have C z (e f (k), k) > C z (e n (k), k) for all k. Hence, F (k) F(k) > 0 for all k. This implies that k > k. Emissions satisfy ê = e n ( k) > e f ( k) > e f (k ) = e where the last inequality follows from lemma 2 and the assumption C ez < 0. For λ > 0, we have F (k) = G + f(λ)c ze de f dk + (f(λ))2 C zz = G + (f(λ))2 [C ee C zz C 2 ze + N2 C zz D ] C ee + N 2 D > 0, for all k > 0. Hence, k > k if and only if F ( k) > 0. Because F( k) = 0, F ( k) = F ( k) F( k) > 0 holds if and only if f(λ)c z (e f ( k), f(λ) k) C z (e n ( k), f(λ) k) > 0. Given C z < 0 and f(λ) = 1 + (N 1)λ, this inequality is equivalent to (N 1)λ < C z(e n ( k), f(λ) k) 1. (12) C z (e f ( k), f(λ) k) 16

19 Inequality k > k also implies ê = e n ( k) > e f ( k) > e f (k ) = e. If (12) does not hold, then we have k k but ê may or may not exceed e. In what follows we describe the conditions under which ê < e occurs. The first best emission e and the equilibrium emission ê satisfy It follows from C ee C zz C 2 ez 0 that H (e) C ee + f(λ)c ez dk f H (e ) C e (e, f(λ)k ) + ND (Ne ) = 0, Ĥ(ê) = C e (ê, f(λ) k) + D (Nê) = 0. de + N2 D = C eeg + (f(λ)) 2 [C ee C zz C 2 ze] G + C zz f(λ) 2 + N 2 D > 0. Thus ê < e H (ê) < 0 H (ê) Ĥ(ê) = C e(ê, f(λ)k f (ê)) C e (ê, f(λ)k n (ê)) + (N 1)D (Nê) < 0 C e (ê, f(λ)k n (ê)) C e (ê, f(λ)k f (ê)) > (N 1)D (Nê). (Because k f (ê) > k n (ê), the left-hand side of the last inequality is nonpositive if C ez 0. Therefore, the above inequality holds only if C ez < 0.) References [1] Baker, E., Clarke, L., Weyant, J., Optimal Technology R&D in the Face of Climate Uncertainty. Climatic Change 75, [2] Baker, E., Clarke, L., Shittu, E., Technical Change and the Marginal Cost of Abatement. Energy Economics, forthcoming. [3] Barrett, S., Strategy and the environment. Columbia Journal of World Business 27, [4] Barrett, S., Environment and Statecraft. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK. [5] Bauman, Y. K The Effects of Environmental Policy on Technological Change in Pollution Control. PhD Dissertation, University of Washington. 17

20 [6] Brechet, T., Jouvet, P.-A Environmental Innovation and the Cost of Pollution Abatement. Presented at the Third World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, July [7] Buchner, B., Carraro, C. Cersosimo, I., Marchiori, C Back to Kyoto? US Participation and the Linkage between R&D and Climate Cooperation. FEEM Working Paper , Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei. [8] Carraro, C., Siniscalco, D R&D Cooperation and the Stability of International Environmental Agreements. In C. Carraro ed. International Environmental Negotiations, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham. [9] Golombek, R., Hoel, M The Kyoto Agreement and Technology Spillovers. University of Oslo, Working paper. [10] Heal, G Formation of International Environmental Agreements, in C. Carraro ed. Trade, Innovation, Environment, Kluwer, Dordrecht. [11] Jaffe, A.B., Newell, R. G., Stavins, R. N., Technology change and the environment, in K.G. Mäler, J. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of Environmental Economics, North Holland/Elsevier Science, Amsterdam. [12] Karp, L Multiplicity of investment equilibria when pollution permits are not tradable. Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA. [13] Karp, L., Zhang, J., Controlling a stock pollutant with endogenous investment and asymmetric information, Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA [14] Kennedy, P. W., Laplante, B., Environmental policy and time consistency: emission taxes and emissions trading, in Petrakis, E., Sartzetakis, E. S., Xepapadeas, A. (Eds.), Environmental Regulation and Market Power, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp [15] Kolstad, C., Systematic uncertainty in self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 53, 1,

21 [16] Malik, A.S., Permanent versus interim regulations: A game-theoretic analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 21, 2, [17] Milliman,S.R., Prince, R., Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 17, [18] Moledina, A. A., Coggins, J. S., Polasky, S., Costello, C., Dynamic environmental policy with strategic firms: prices versus quantities, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, [19] National Research Council Clean Coastal Waters: Understanding and Reducing the Effects of Nutrient Pollution. National Academy Press, Washington, DC. [20] Popp, D., International innovation and diffusion of air pollution control technologies: the effects of NOX and SO2 regulation in the US, Japan, and Germany. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 51, [21] Popp, D., Newell, R. G., Jaffe, A. B., Energy, the Environment, and Technological Change. NBER Working Paper No [22] Requate, T., Unold, W., Environmental policy incentives to adopt advanced abatement technology: Will the true ranking please stand up? European Economic Review, 47, [23] Stern, N., The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. H.M. Treasury, U.K. 19

22 Table 1: Equilibrium outcome of simultaneous-move games Technology Marginal abatement costs spillovers Decreasing in R&D Increasing in R&D Emissions Investment Emissions Investment Small Too large Too small Too large Too large Large Too large Too small? Too small 20

23 MB, MC Panel (a) Investment Panel (b) Emissions * MB of investment given MAC, MD e MAC given k * Social MD MB of investment given ê MC of investment Private MD MAC given kˆ 0 * k kˆ Investment MB of investment is the negative of the partial derivative of abatement cost with respect to investment. MC of investment is the derivative of investment cost. MAC is the negative of the partial derivative of abatement codst with respect to emissions. Private and social MD refer to the marginal damage at a country level and at the aggregate, global level. 0 * e ê Emission Figure 1: The equilibrium and the first best when C ez < 0 and λ = 0. 21

24 MB, MC Panel (a) Investment MB of investment given ê MB of investment given * e MAC, MD Panel (b) Emissions * MAC given k Social MD MC of investment Private MD MAC given kˆ 0 * kˆ k Investment MB of investment is the negative of the partial derivative of abatement cost with respect to investment. MC of investment is the derivative of investment cost. MAC is the negative of the partial derivative of abatement codst with respect to emissions. Private and social MD refer to the marginal damage at a country level and at the aggregate, global level. 0 ê * e Emission Figure 2: The equilibrium and the first best when C ez < 0 and a large λ. 22

25 1.3 Panel (a) Investment 0.7 Panel (b) Emissions 1.2 First Best Nash Eqm First Best Nash Eqm The figure is based on a linear quadratic example (equations 7, 8) with N=2, a = 1, b = 1, d =.75, f 1 = 2, f 2 = 1, e =.5. In the two panels, the horizontal axes measure the degree of spillovers (0: no spillovers, 1: highest degree of spillovers). Figure 3: The equilibrium and the first best when C ez < 0. 23

26 0.35 Panel (a) Investment 0.3 Panel (b) Emissions First Best Nash Eqm First Best Nash Eqm The figure is based on a linear quadratic example (equations 7, 8) with the same parameter values as for Figure 3 except f 1 = 1.4 (lower than in Figure 3). In the two panels, the horizontal axes measure the degree of spillovers (0: no spillovers, 1: highest degree of spillovers). Figure 4: The equilibrium and the first best when C ez < 0 (2). 24

Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution

Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution Geoffrey Heal a Graduate School of Business Columbia University and Nori Tarui b Department of Economics University of Hawai i at Mānoa

More information

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis Indrani Roy Chowdhury* and Sandwip K. Das** Abstract We provide a new formulation of the Porter hypothesis that we feel is in the spirit of the hypothesis. Under this

More information

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series ISSN 1791-3144 University of Macedonia Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series International Environmental Agreements: An emission choice model with abatement technology Eftichios Sartzetakis and

More information

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ 009/55 Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ CORE DISCUSSION PAPER 009/9 Clean technology adoption and its influence on tradeable

More information

Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms?

Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms? Kyushu University Global COE Program Journal of Novel Carbon Resource Sciences, Vol. 7, pp. 26-32, Feb. 2013 Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms? Tadahisa Ohno Research and Education Center

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand

Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand WP-2009-001 Technology Adoption in a Differentiated Duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand Rupayan Pal Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai January 2009 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2009-001.pdf

More information

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract

Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty. Abstract Strategic R and D investments with uncertainty Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo Abstract I introduce uncertainty into the model of strategic cost reducing R and D investments

More information

Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms?

Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms? Should the Government Privatize Polluting Firms? Tadahisa Ohno Research and Education Center of Carbon Resources, Kyushu University Abstract This paper presents an analysis of whether the government should

More information

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy Emmanuel Petrakis and Anastasios Xepapadeas University of Crete This paper analyzes and compares delocation decisions

More information

Anti-Sharing as a Theory of Partnerships and Firms

Anti-Sharing as a Theory of Partnerships and Firms Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Robert Cooter December, 2006 Anti-Sharing as a Theory of Partnerships and Firms Robert D Cooter, University of California, Berkeley Roland Kirstein Available at:

More information

Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets?

Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets? Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets? Stefani C. Smith and Andrew J. Yates Abstract: The authors present a simple diagrammatic exposition of a pollutionpermit market in which both

More information

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit

The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit The Efficiency of Voluntary Pollution Abatement when Countries can Commit by Robin Boadway, Queen s University, Canada Zhen Song, Central University of Finance and Economics, China Jean-François Tremblay,

More information

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Learning Objectives: Students should learn to:. The student will understand the ideas of strategic interdependence and reasoning strategically and be able

More information

Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs

Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs DET ØKONOMISKE RÅD S E K R E T A R I A T E T Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs Jens Hauch Working Paper 1999:6 The Secretariat publishes a series of Working Papers, which primarily contains detailed

More information

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Abstract. Revenue management (RM) is the art and science of predicting consumer behavior and optimizing price and product availability to maximize

More information

Ec 11 Caltech Lecture 1 Notes (revised: version 2.0)

Ec 11 Caltech Lecture 1 Notes (revised: version 2.0) Ec 11 Caltech Lecture 1 Notes (revised: version 2.) Prof. Antonio Rangel Spring 212 Contact rangel@hss.caltech.edu with corrections, comments, and suggestions. Lecture notes are organized around the following

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1 Review of Economics & Finance Submitted on 30/03/2015 Article ID: 1923-7529-2015-04-78-14 Fang Wei Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1 Dr. Fang Wei

More information

Tipping Climate Negotiations. Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School. January

Tipping Climate Negotiations. Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School. January Tipping Climate Negotiations Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School Howard Kunreuther, The Wharton School 1 January 10 2011 Abstract. We investigate whether progress towards an international treaty on

More information

Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and Equity

Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and Equity 20th World Energy Congress, Enel Special Session Architectures for Agreement: Climate change policy post 2012 Rome, November 15, 2007 Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information

Pollution-Reducing and Resource-Saving Technological Progress

Pollution-Reducing and Resource-Saving Technological Progress Pollution-Reducing and Resource-Saving Technological Progress by Dagmar Nelissen and Till Requate Economics Working Paper No 2004-07 Pollution-Reducing and Resource-Saving Technological Progress * by Dagmar

More information

Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure

Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure Maryam Khajeh Afzali, Poh Kim Leng, Jeff Obbard Abstract The issue of channel power in supply chain has recently received considerable attention in literature.

More information

Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion

Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion Emission Tax or Standard? TheRoleofProductivityDispersion Zhe Li Shanghai University of Finance and Economics (li.zhe@mail.shufe.edu.cn) Shouyong Shi Department of Economics University of Toronto (shouyong@chass.utoronto.ca)

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries

Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries Noah Kaufman Working Paper Fall 2008 Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries I. Introduction The successful implementation of international environmental agreements

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction and maximization Introduction Maximization. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6. General results on maximizing with two variables 3. Non-negativity constraints

More information

Incentives in Supply Function Equilibrium

Incentives in Supply Function Equilibrium Discussion Paper No. 2014-38 September 29, 2014 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2014-38 Please cite the corresponding Journal Article at http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2015-5

More information

Environmental Policy and Time Consistency

Environmental Policy and Time Consistency Public Disclosure Authorized POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 23 51 L,)PS - a 361 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Environmental Policy and Time Consistency Emissions Taxes and Emissions

More information

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence Learning Objectives: Students should learn to: 1. Define and give examples of predatory conduct. 2. Explain stylized facts about the entry of firms into industries.

More information

Environmental Protection and Economic Growth: An Optimal Pollution Controlling Model

Environmental Protection and Economic Growth: An Optimal Pollution Controlling Model MPRA Munich Personal RePc Archive nvironmental Protection and conomic Growth: An Optimal Pollution ontrolling Model Liyuan Liu and Fei Peng December 5 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/766/ MPRA

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF ALLOWING POLLUTION OFFSETS WITH IMPERFECT ENFORCEMENT. Hilary Sigman Howard F. Chang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF ALLOWING POLLUTION OFFSETS WITH IMPERFECT ENFORCEMENT. Hilary Sigman Howard F. Chang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF ALLOWING POLLUTION OFFSETS WITH IMPERFECT ENFORCEMENT Hilary Sigman Howard F. Chang Working Paper 16860 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16860 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

OPTIMAL ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION, R&D SUBSIDIZATION AND THE ROLE OF MARKET CONDUCT* JOANNA A. POYAGO-THEOTOKY

OPTIMAL ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION, R&D SUBSIDIZATION AND THE ROLE OF MARKET CONDUCT* JOANNA A. POYAGO-THEOTOKY Finnish Economic Papers Volume 16 Number 1 Spring 2003 OPTIMAL ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION, R&D SUBSIDIZATION AND THE ROLE OF MARKET CONDUCT* JOANNA A. POYAGO-THEOTOKY Department of Economics, University of

More information

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Kyoto University, Graduate School of Economics Research Project Center Discussion Paper Series Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Hide-Fumi Yokoo and Thomas C. Kinnaman Discussion Paper No. E-09-002

More information

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 30, 2005 Answer four of the six

More information

Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation

Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation Energy Security and Global Climate Change Mitigation OP 55 October 2003 Hillard G. Huntington and Stephen P.A. Brown Forthcoming in Hillard G. Huntington Energy Modeling Forum 448 Terman Center Stanford

More information

Literature Review of Emissions Control and Research and Development Externalities

Literature Review of Emissions Control and Research and Development Externalities Grand Valley State University ScholarWorks@GVSU Honors Projects Undergraduate Research and Creative Practice 2015 Literature Review of Emissions Control and Research and Development Externalities Luke

More information

Peter J. Wood. Resource Management in Asia Pacific Program Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies The Australian National University

Peter J. Wood. Resource Management in Asia Pacific Program Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies The Australian National University Global climate change architecture: comparing blueprints from Australia and China, from a game theory perspective Peter J. Wood Resource Management in Asia Pacific Program Research School of Pacific and

More information

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE MS # 1949 OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE Tsuyoshi TOSHIMITSU * Kwansei Gakuin University Final version March 2003 Abstract In a quality-differentiated duopoly where (i) quality is endogenously

More information

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia IMPACTS OF ENERGY TAXES AND SUBSIDIES B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia Keywords: energy taxes, energy subsidies, price gap approach

More information

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account Index: 8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account... 8. Introduction... 8. The deterministic case...3 8.3 Optimal consumption under uncertainty...4

More information

Manufacturer s pricing strategy for mixed retail and e-tail channels

Manufacturer s pricing strategy for mixed retail and e-tail channels 2013 46th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences Manufacturer s pricing strategy for mixed retail and e-tail channels Xu Chen University of Electronic Science and Technology of China xchenxchen@263.net

More information

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang *

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang * Forthcoming in Economics Letters Leading Merger in a Stackelberg Oligopoly: Profitability and Consumer Welfare Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang * Department of Applied Economics, National University

More information

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Warwick J. McKibbin and Peter J. Wilcoxen Australian National University Economics and Environment Network Working Paper EEN0306

More information

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3 Economics 2 Spring 2018 rofessor Christina Romer rofessor David Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO ROBLEM SET 3 1.a. A monopolist is the only seller of a good. As a result, it faces the downward-sloping market

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 2 44706 (1394-95 2 nd term) - Group 2 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 11: Externalities & Public

More information

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game Hassan Benchekroun a Amrita Ray Chaudhuri b January 2009 a Department of Economics, McGill University, 855 Sherbrooke Ouest, Montreal, QC, Canada,

More information

Instrument Choice for Environmental Protection When Technological Innovation is Endogenous

Instrument Choice for Environmental Protection When Technological Innovation is Endogenous Instrument Choice for Environmental Protection When Technological Innovation is Endogenous Carolyn Fischer Ian W. H. Parry William A. Pizer Discussion Paper 99-04 October 1998 1616 P Street, NW Washington,

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results *

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results * Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results * Xavier Cuadras-Morató Department of Economics Universitat Pompeu Fabra Ramon Trias Fargas, 25-27 08005 BRCELON e-mail: xavier.cuadras@econ.upf.es

More information

Taxes and Caps as Climate Policy Instruments with Domestic and Imported Fuels

Taxes and Caps as Climate Policy Instruments with Domestic and Imported Fuels Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 57 Taxes and Caps as Climate Policy Instruments with Domestic

More information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information

Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Matching Markets with Endogenous Information Tracy Lewis Duke University Li, Hao University of British Columbia Matching Problems in Chicago 2012 Lewis and Li Endogenous Matching 1 Introduction: Motivation

More information

Journal of Industrial Organization Education

Journal of Industrial Organization Education Journal of Industrial Organization Education Volume 3, Issue 1 2008 Article 1 Capacity-Constrained Monopoly Kathy Baylis, University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign Jeffrey M. Perloff, University of California,

More information

Lecture 2 Pollution control

Lecture 2 Pollution control Lecture 2 Pollution control Ingrid Hjort Econ 4910 - Environmental Economics - UiO January 25, 2017 1 / 36 Review Last lecture: Market failures Characterizing the pollution problem Determining the pollution

More information

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Gerhard Clemenz March 2012 Abstract: According to the Porter Hypothesis (PH) stricter environmental regulations

More information

Innovation benefits from nuclear phase-out: Can they compensate the costs?

Innovation benefits from nuclear phase-out: Can they compensate the costs? 2013 International Energy Workshop Paris, 19 th -21 st June 2013 Innovation benefits from nuclear phase-out: Can they compensate the costs? Enrica De Cian, Samuel Carrara, Massimo Tavoni FEEM (Fondazione

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Essi Eerola RUESG, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland Niku Määttänen Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain and The Research Institute

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions

Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions Masahiko Hattori and Yasuhito Tanaka. June 2015 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/65008/

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I)

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I) The 2x2 Exchange Economy Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/2 (Lecture 8, Micro Theory I) Road Map for Chapter 3 Pareto Efficiency Allocation (PEA) Cannot make one better off without hurting others Walrasian (Price-taking)

More information

A Note on The Simple Analytics of the Environmental Kuznets Curve

A Note on The Simple Analytics of the Environmental Kuznets Curve A Note on The Simple Analytics of the Environmental Kuznets Curve Florenz Plassmann Department of Economics State University of New York at Binghamton P.O. Box 6000, Binghamton, N.Y. 1390-6000 Phone: 607-777-4304;

More information

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I)

The 2x2 Exchange Economy. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I) The 2x2 Exchange Economy Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2012/11/21 (Lecture 2, Micro Theory I) Road Map for Chapter 3 Pareto Efficiency Cannot make one better off without hurting others Walrasian (Price-taking) Equilibrium

More information

Competition with Licensed Shared Spectrum

Competition with Licensed Shared Spectrum ompetition with Licensed Shared Spectrum hang Liu EES Department Northwestern University, Evanston, IL 628 Email: changliu212@u.northwestern.edu Randall A. Berry EES Department Northwestern University,

More information

Existence of Nash equilibria in sporting contests with capacity constraints

Existence of Nash equilibria in sporting contests with capacity constraints Existence of Nash equilibria in sporting contests with capacity constraints Shumei Hirai This article considers a contest model of an n-team professional sports league. The market areas in which teams

More information

Selling methods by a monopolist

Selling methods by a monopolist Selling methods by a monopolist Lluís Bru y Ramon Faulí-Oller z and Joel Sandonís x February 18, 005 Abstract In an industry with an upstream monopolist and a continuum of heterogeneous downstream rms,

More information

Summary of the DICE model

Summary of the DICE model Summary of the DICE model Stephen C. Newbold U.S. EPA, National Center for Environmental Economics 1 This report gives a brief summary of the DICE (Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy) model, developed

More information

Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS. Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh

Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS. Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh Explore Financial Innovation for Linkage China ETS and EU ETS Lan Wang, Dr Xi Liang University of Edinburgh Background Seven Pilots Trading Systems National ETS in 2017 European Emission Trading System

More information

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) Public Economics by Luca Spataro Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded) 1 Introduction Connection between agents outside the price system The level of externality

More information

Overcoming the Limitations of Utility Design for Multiagent Systems

Overcoming the Limitations of Utility Design for Multiagent Systems 1402 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON AUTOMATIC CONTROL, VOL. 58, NO. 6, JUNE 2013 Overcoming the Limitations of Utility Design for Multiagent Systems Jason R. Marden and Adam Wierman Abstract Cooperative control

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

The Price of Anarchy in an Exponential Multi-Server

The Price of Anarchy in an Exponential Multi-Server The Price of Anarchy in an Exponential Multi-Server Moshe Haviv Tim Roughgarden Abstract We consider a single multi-server memoryless service station. Servers have heterogeneous service rates. Arrivals

More information

CREATING ENVIRONMENTAL MARKETS. Modeling Solutions to Environmental Problems

CREATING ENVIRONMENTAL MARKETS. Modeling Solutions to Environmental Problems 1 CREATING ENVIRONMENTAL MARKETS Modeling Solutions to Environmental Problems 2 Creating Environmental Markets Conventional Solutions Market Solutions Assign property rights Pigouvian and emission taxes

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012. 1 A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET April 2012 Bralind Kiri bralind.kiri@gmail.com PhD Student, Department of Economic Theory and

More information

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry Aviv Nevo* 549 Evans Hall [3880, Department of Economics, UC Berkeley, Berkeley,

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing TI 2004-068/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing Maarten C.W. Janssen José Luis Moraga-González* Matthijs R. Wildenbeest Faculty of Economics,

More information

Energy and Climate Change in China

Energy and Climate Change in China Energy and Climate Change in China Carlo Carraro, University of Venice and Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Emanuele Massetti, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei and CMCC Workshop on the Chinese Economy Bank of

More information

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Thomas D. Jeitschko and Mark J. Tremblay Prepared for IIOC 2014: Not Intended for Circulation March 27, 2014 Abstract In this paper we investigate

More information

Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard

Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard This version 24 th January 2011 Lecture Notes on Pure and Impure Public Goods by Dale Squires and Niels Vestergaard 1. General Points About Public Goods Goods that are non rival and non excludable in consumption

More information

China s New National Carbon Market

China s New National Carbon Market AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 463 467 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181029 China s New National Carbon Market By William A. Pizer and Xiliang Zhang* On December 19, 2017, China announced the

More information

Harvard University Department of Economics

Harvard University Department of Economics Harvard University Department of Economics General Examination in Microeconomic Theory Spring 00. You have FOUR hours. Part A: 55 minutes Part B: 55 minutes Part C: 60 minutes Part D: 70 minutes. Answer

More information

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition by Joshua S. Gans and Stephen P. King University of Melbourne 0 th March, 000 This paper demonstrates that low (below marginal

More information

R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization

R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization Discussion Paper No. 2013-41 August 12, 2013 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2013-41 R&D Cooperation and Industry Cartelization Jacek Prokop and Adam Karbowski Abstract The

More information

The Coalition of the Willing: Effect of Country Diversity in an Environmental Treaty Game

The Coalition of the Willing: Effect of Country Diversity in an Environmental Treaty Game The Coalition of the Willing: Effect of Country Diversity in an Environmental Treaty Game Rögnvaldur Hannesson The Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration Helleveien 30 N-5045 Bergen

More information

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe Ryosuke Okazawa April 21, 2012 A. Multiple Pooling Equilibria In Section 3, although

More information

Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market

Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market Coase vs. Pigou in the Petroleum Market Ju Vinn Chai, Cen Chen, Fabienne Giauque & Wei Zhu Overview Non-renewable resources such as fossil fuels are used extensively in industrial activities and transportation.

More information

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes. These notes provided by Laura Lamb are intended to complement class lectures. The notes are based on chapter 12 of Microeconomics and Behaviour 2 nd Canadian Edition by Frank and Parker (2004). Chapter

More information

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. Understanding UPP Roy J. Epstein and Daniel L. Rubinfeld Published Version, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Policies and Perspectives, Volume 10, Issue 1, 2010 Introduction The standard economic

More information

Chapter 7 Energy-Related Carbon Dioxide Emissions

Chapter 7 Energy-Related Carbon Dioxide Emissions Chapter 7 Energy-Related Carbon Dioxide Emissions In the coming decades, actions to limit greenhouse gas emissions could affect patterns of energy use around the world and alter the level and composition

More information

Technical Change and the Marginal Cost of Abatement

Technical Change and the Marginal Cost of Abatement Technical Change and the Marginal Cost of Abatement Erin Baker and Ekundayo Shittu University of Massachusetts, Amherst Leon Clarke Joint Global Change Research Institute University of Maryland, College

More information

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 2 Wednesday June16th 2004

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 2 Wednesday June16th 2004 1 Behind the demand and supply curves 2 Monopoly Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 2 Wednesday June16th 2004 Main ideas so far: Supply and Demand Model Analyzing the model - positive - e.g. equilibrium,

More information

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge by Luis Garicano and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Since the seminal work of Katz and Murphy (1992), the study of wage inequality has taken as its starting point a

More information

Climate Policy. Michael Springborn. Department of Environmental Science & Policy. springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu.

Climate Policy. Michael Springborn. Department of Environmental Science & Policy. springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu. Climate Policy Michael Springborn Department of Environmental Science & Policy springborn.faculty.ucdavis.edu mspringborn@ucdavis.edu [image: USGCRP, 2010] The intensity of CO2/GDP is falling but not fast

More information