Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries"

Transcription

1 Noah Kaufman Working Paper Fall 2008 Bilateral Negotiations on Emissions Abatement among Heterogeneous Countries I. Introduction The successful implementation of international environmental agreements ( IEA ) regarding the abatement of greenhouse gas emissions will require participating countries to overcome a number of obstacles. First, and extensively covered in the literature, is the issue of enforcement. Since there is no world government, IEAs are not binding in any meaningful sense, so an agreement must be selfenforcing. A self-enforcing agreement has two components: a participant cannot be made better off by leaving the agreement, and a non-participant cannot be made better off by joining the agreement. Selfenforcing agreements are very tough to achieve in practice because of the strong incentives to free-ride that result from the non-excludable nature of abatement benefits. Second, and far less frequently covered in the literature, is the reality that the efficacy of an IEA will depend in large part on the participation of a small number of specific and heterogeneous countries. In particular, as of 2004, the U.S., the EU, China and India accounted for over 60% of annual manmade carbon dioxide emissions 1, with this percentage expected to grow only larger in the coming years. Any agreement that is unable to support these specific countries will in all likelihood result in an insignificant improvement over unilateral actions. Eyckmans and Finus (2007) divide the world into six regions and use a revised version of the popular RICE model 2 to simulate the global welfare impacts of coalitions of particular regions to abate greenhouse gas emissions. They conclude that the identity of members may matter more than the number of participants for the success of cooperation. Put differently, the commonly held view that high participation indicates success of an IEA proves to be wrong. In particular, in their simulations of the welfare impacts of potential coalitions, China and the Rest of World region (including primarily India and other developing countries) are included in each of the top 12 welfare increasing coalitions. For these reasons, the inclusion in an IEA of specific, pivotal 1 Data per Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center, 2 Model created by Nordhaus and Yang (1996) 1

2 countries is an additional layer of complexity added to the difficulties of achieving self-enforcing agreements. The Kyoto Protocol is the result of an IEA among many non-pivotal countries. The developing countries are not responsible for any meaningful abatement, and the U.S. has refused to participate as long as developing countries such as China and India are not given abatement responsibilities 3. Kyoto may be a step in the right direction, but it will likely have only a small impact on the global growth of greenhouse gas emissions. Despite the difficulties mentioned above, the economics literature has recently produced a number of papers that predict meaningful international cooperation regarding the abatement of greenhouse gas emissions, in effect overturning Barrett s (1994) result that a high degree of cooperation can be achieved only when the differences between global net benefits under the non-cooperative outcome and the full cooperative outcome are small. Specifically, Barrett (2001), McGinty (2006), and Caplan and Silva (2007) are among the papers with optimistic predictions of international cooperation compared to Barrett s original model. In this paper, I attempt to explain why the predictions of these recent papers have not been mirrored by any real world examples of cooperative success. Barrett (2001) lays the conceptual foundation for the predictions of increased cooperation by demonstrating that certain asymmetries between countries promote greater global cooperation. He finds that if there are countries with differing benefits to an IEA, the countries that benefit the most can pay those that benefit the least in return for their cooperation. This diminishes the problem of freeriding since the differences between countries essentially commit them to particular roles in the process. Barrett assumes rich countries pollute more and benefit more from abatement activities, and should therefore transfer resources to poor countries, whereby efficiency in the model is increased and both countries can potentially realize gains above a non-cooperative outcome. Similarly, McGinty (2006) argues that symmetric models may vastly understate the degree of abatement achievable by a self-enforcing IEA, and, the conventional wisdom that self-enforcing IEAs cannot achieve substantial gains when the gains to cooperation are large does not hold when nations are asymmetric. In the McGinty model, countries differ in benefits and costs of abatement. As in Barrett (2001), McGinty s solution requires international transfers among signatories to increase efficiency and to induce significant cooperation among asymmetric countries. 3 Text of a Letter from the President to Senators Hagel, Helms, Craig, and Roberts, March 13,

3 Caplan and Silva (2007) employ a representative agent model with two regions that are identical with respect to preferences and technologies, but differ in endowments. They describe a three stage process in which regions first choose to participate in an IEA, then select their optimal policies, and finally consent to transfers from an international organization. The paper concludes that as long as the international organization is the Stackleberg follower, it can align the incentives of the regions and induce a scheme that is equitable, efficient and implementable in equilibrium. These results are discussed in more detail in Section V. In the model presented below, I will change the assumptions from the literature in a few key respects. First, as in Caplin and Silva, but unlike much of the literature, I will consider bilateral negotiations between developed and developing regions. This focuses on the specific, pivotal countries mentioned above, and avoids cooperative but ineffective solutions like Kyoto. Next, I will consider a different type of asymmetry among regions. The heterogeneity in the papers mentioned above relates to the costs and benefits of abatement, and in certain cases to the endowments of resources. None of these papers consider any underlying differences in preferences regarding abatement of greenhouse gas emissions. Considering the wide range of actual responses we have seen around the world to the threat of environmental damages, the assumption that the benefits from emissions abatement enter the utility functions of each region identically could be a serious oversimplification of reality. For this reason, I will consider the impact of differing preferences across regions. Finally, the model will use an explicitly specified utility function for each region that emphasizes corner solutions. This has two potential advantages compared with the utility functions seen in Caplan and Silva (2007), among others. The previous literature has assumed that regions have smooth utility functions, which will not lead to corner solutions in general due to Inada conditions. However, in the real world, we have witnessed no meaningful cooperation on greenhouse gas abatement between countries such as the U.S. and China, and many developing countries have stated they cannot afford to slow down the growth of their economies to combat a problem that was largely created by the developed world. It is therefore important to allow for the possibility that these countries can rationally choose not to contribute at all to global abatement. In other words, it is important to consider corner solutions in the model. Another advantage of using specified utility functions is that they permit a more intuitive interpretation of the model s findings compared to the unspecified utility functions seen in the literature. 3

4 I conclude that cooperation between developed regions such as the U.S. and the E.U. and developing regions such as China and India could potentially be impossible to achieve in the near future. In fact, the cooperation of these developing countries may not necessarily lead to increased efficiency as the literature has suggested. The model presented in this paper is primarily intended to point out the uncertainty with which we should view the predictions of recent papers on this topic. The contribution of this uncertainty is the signal it sends to developed countries that have been hesitant to unilaterally tackle the issue of greenhouse gas emissions. Bush administration officials, among others in the developed world, have long held the view that unilateral abatement would in effect surrender their countries bargaining chips, and allow developing countries to continue to free ride. This paper indicates that waiting for the cooperation of developing countries may be a waste of time. Unilateral emissions abatement may be the only option available. The structure of the remainder of this paper is as follows. Sections II presents a model economy. Section III characterizes Pareto efficient solutions to the model. Section IV looks at a decentralized endowment economy with heterogeneous regions, and the potential resulting competitive equilibria. Section V looks at the potential for cooperation from the use of international resource transfers. Section VI expands on the implications of the transfers needed to induce international cooperation. Section VII concludes. II. The Model Following Caplan and Silva, I consider an economy consisting of two regions indexed by j, j=1,2. Region 1 will represent a developed region such as the U.S. or the E.U., and region 2 will represent a developing region such as China or India. Each region is assumed to have a central regulator that chooses its region s policies by maximizing the total utility of the region, which is positively dependent on both consumption and abatement of global greenhouse gas emissions 4. Indifference curves are assumed to be L-shaped in the consumption-global abatement plane: U(a j, c j, x j + x -j ) = min{a j * c j, x j + x -j }, for j= 1,2, 4 The convention in the literature is for utility to be negatively dependant on emissions. I assume positive dependence on emissions abatement because it simplifies the analyses in the following sections. 4

5 y-axis: Total Abatement Contributions (x j + x -j ) where c j 0 is the total consumption of region j, x j 0 are contributions to global abatement (thus x j + x -j = total global abatement), and a j is a parameter for the environmental awareness of region j. Environmental awareness refers in this model to a region s level of concern for the damages that will be inflicted on the environment by greenhouse gas emissions. I assume an endowment economy in which the regulator for region j must adhere to the following budget constraint: c j + x j = w j, for j=1,2, where w j is region j s endowment, representing the region s annual income or a measure of economic growth, which for simplicity is exogenous in this model. The units are adjusted so that each good has a price equal to one. On account of the Leontief utility functions, each region will attempt to equalize global abatement (x j + x -j ) and consumption multiplied by the environmental awareness parameter (a j * c j ). In other words, each region has increasing preferences in both today s consumption and the consumption of future generations (which will be positively impacted by abatement contributions). The parameter a j determines the relative weights placed on the present versus the future by way of the complementarity between the level of environmental awareness and global abatement spending. A high level of environmental awareness will lead to a relatively large portion of the resource endowment used to fund global abatement, while a low level of awareness will lead to larger expenditures on consumption goods. Taking the abatement contribution of the other region as given, each region s maximization of its utility will lead to one of the two following results. The first, displayed as point A in Chart 1 below, Chart 1 Chart 2 Budget Constraint 45 degree line Budget Constraint 45 degree line x -j B Indifference Curves x j A x -j x-axis: Environmental Awareness Parameter (a j ) * Consumption (c j ) 5

6 occurs when region j has the resources required to equalize the two terms of the utility function. The second result, displayed as point B in Chart 2, occurs when region j does not have the resources required to equalize the two terms of the utility function (since x -j > a j * w j ), and therefore contributes only to consumption (c j = w j, x j = 0). The regions preferences differ only in regard to the parameter for environmental awareness. I assume that a 1 > a 2. In other words, holding all else equal, contributions to global abatement are more beneficial to a developed region than to a developing region. This assumption requires that there are fundamental differences between developed and developing regions preferences toward the abatement of emissions. The following are brief justifications of this assumption. Anecdotally, there is plenty of evidence from the real world to suggest that as a region develops economically, it also develops a heightened concern for the long-term future of the environment. To begin with, the countries with binding emissions targets under the Kyoto Agreement are generally the most developed countries in the world, less the U.S. The developing countries have thus far been unwilling to take this step. This is hardly surprising since many developing countries, China and India included, have been somewhat preoccupied with more imminent concerns of widespread poverty. It seems only natural that until the necessities for survival can be provided to citizens, countries will focus more on their current issues and less on those of the future. In this way, abatement of emissions acts as a luxury good. The assumption of a 1 > a 2 requires further that this difference in environmental awareness would remain even if the regions endowments were equal. Caplan and Silva (2007), among other previous papers, implicitly assumes that rich and poor regions become identical when transfers of resources serve to equalize endowments. However, regional preferences have been cultivated over many generations, influenced undoubtedly not only by wealth but also by other cultural factors. Developed and developing regions have differing preferences toward the environment that in all likelihood would not disappear immediately due to a transfer of resources. Consider an example involving two individuals in a comparable situation. One earns $1 million per year and plays tennis twice per week, and the other earns $20 thousand per year and plays no tennis. Would equalizing their incomes immediately cause them to play an equal amount of tennis? Or would the previously poor individual spend his additional resources on more familiar goods? Applying this metaphor to the current situation, developed countries have been able to spend resources in recent decades not only on directly combating environmental damages, but also on educating their citizens on the importance of becoming better stewards of the environment. This education gap has created an 6

7 abundance of environmental advocates in developed regions who will derive a greater benefit from abatement contributions than will less educated citizens. This greater benefit from abatement contributions is represented by the difference between a 1 and a 2 in the model. More formally, the difference between a 1 and a 2 can be justified through the treatment of a j as an endogenous variable in region j s optimization problem. In this case, region j would need to invest resources in a j to raise its level of environmental awareness. This idea of endogenous preference formation follows from Becker and Murphy (1988) and Mulligan (1997), among others. Rapaport and Vidal (2007) use endogenous preference formation to model the intergeneration altruism of parents toward their children. In their model, all parents are affected to some extent by the welfare of their children, but they can also invest their time and other resources in shaping their own preferences toward more concern for their children when they realize that this change will raise their own utility: It is because they rationally anticipate the effects of their actions on their future preferences and life-cycle utility that parents purposefully accumulate intergenerational altruism through the purchase of childoriented goods (e.g. time spent interacting with children). Their model assumes that this intergenerational altruism increases by some function of the investment of resources. Rapaport and Vidal s measure of parent-to-child altruism has a natural analogous interpretation in the setting of preferences toward environmental issues. Investing time and resources in improving the environment provides a benefit to environmentally educated individuals that cannot simply be measured by the direct impact on the environment of global emissions abatement. To include endogenous preference formation in this model, each region would choose levels of consumption, contribution to global abatement and investment in environmental awareness to solve the following utility maximization problem: Max [Min(f(q j ) * c j, x j + x -j )], such that c j + x j + q j = w j, where q j refers to the resources invested in environmental awareness and f(q j ) refers to the level of environmental awareness. I assume f is a strictly positive, strictly increasing and strictly concave function. Rapaport and Vidal establish in their model that parents invest resources to accumulate parentchild altruism if and only if their wealth exceeds a specific endogenously determined threshold, which is interpreted as the minimal level of income beyond which individuals have satisfied their own physiological constraint and can start to shape their preferences by honing their altruistic trait beyond its natural degree. I show a similar result below. If a region s endowment of resources is below a 7

8 certain threshold of economic growth, this region will not invest in the accumulation of environmental awareness. Proposition 1: If w j > w b, there exists a unique q j є (0, w j ) solution to region j s maximization problem. If w j < w b, the solution to region j s maximization problem is q j = 0. The proof is given in Appendix A. It follows that assuming the relative endowment of the developing region is below this threshold, only the developed region will invest in environmental awareness. On account of the assumptions on the function f, f(q 1 ) > f(0). In other words, the environmental awareness of the developed region is strictly greater than that of the developing region, or, a 1 > a 2. III. Pareto Efficiency A Pareto efficient allocation in this model is obtained by selecting {c j, x j } j=1,2 to maximize: U 1 (a 1, c 1, x 1 + x 2 ) subject to: U 2 (a 2, c 2, x 1 + x 2 ) V, and (1) c 1 + c 2 + x 1 + x 2 = w 1 + w 2, where V is a strictly positive constant. First, consider the case of unspecified, smooth utility functions as in Caplan and Silva. It is straightforward to show that equation (1) and the following conditions characterize a Pareto efficient solution: (2) U 1 x 1 / U 1 c 1 = 1 U 2 x 1 / U2c 2 (3) U 2 x 2 / U 2 c 2 = 1 U 1 x 2 / U 1 c 1, where the notation U 1 c 1 refers to the partial derivative of region 1 s utility function with respect to its own consumption. I will return to the interpretation of these conditions when discussing the decentralized scenario in the next section. With the Leontief preferences of this model, a Pareto efficient allocation must satisfy equation (1) and one of the three following sets of conditions: Case 1 High Global Welfare Solutions: (4) a 1 * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 (5) a 2 * c 2 = x 1 + x 2 Case 2 Low Global Welfare Solution A: 8

9 a 1 * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 a 2 * c 2 < x 1 + x 2 Case 3 Low Global Welfare Solution B: a 1 * c 1 < x 1 + x 2 a 2 * c 2 = x 1 + x 2 To see why efficiency requires one of these cases to be satisfied, first note that if neither equation (4) nor (5) holds with equality, taking resources from the larger sides of the equations and distributing them to the smaller sides will be a Pareto improvement. Next, note that neither a 1 * c 1 > x 1 + x 2, nor a 2 * c 2 > x 1 + x 2 can occur in an efficient allocation, because in that case, a region could be made better off and the other region no worse off by shifting resources from consumption to abatement contributions. Thus, only the three cases described above remain. The level the global welfare (U 1 + U 2 ) is necessarily higher in Case 1 than in either Cases 2 or 3. This follows due to the concavity of the minimum function. Since U 1 + U 2 = min{a 1 * c 1, x 1 + x 2 } + min{ a 2 * c 2, x 1 + x 2 } is the sum of two identical and strictly concave functions, its value will be greatest when resources are distributed such that the arguments inside the two functions are equal. This is precisely the situation in which equations (4) and (5) hold. IV. The Decentralized Scenario When there is no cooperation among regions, each region j will solve its own Cournot-style maximization problem subject to its budget constraint, taking the abatement action of the other region as given. I assume the endowment of region 1 is strictly greater than that of region 2, since region 1 represents the developed region. Region j solves: Max [Min(a j * c j, x j + x -j )], such that c j + x j = w j. The positive impacts of each region s abatement spending on the other region s utility are externalities unaccounted for in the utility functions. 9

10 First, let us return to the general case with smooth utility functions. Along with the budget constraint, the following conditions, stating that each region s marginal rate of substitution between abatement contributions and consumption are equal, characterize a competitive equilibrium: (6) U 1 x 1 / U 1 c 1 = 1 (7) U 2 x 2 / U 2 c 2 = 1 It is evident that the externalities lead to an inefficient solution. Comparing equations (6) and (7) to the efficient conditions of equations (2) and (3), the inefficiency results from the terms in (2) and (3) expressing the ratio of the marginal utility to region j of an additional unit of abatement by region -j to the marginal utility of consumption of region j. Caplan and Silva refer to this type of inefficiency as externality distortion 5. The Leontief preferences of this model, however, produce different results. As I will show below, the efficient Cases 1 and 2 will be decentralized equilibrium solutions. To see this, note that with the assumptions of w 1 > w 2 and a 1 > a 2, region 1 will always have the necessary resources to ensure that the following condition holds with equality: (8) a 1 * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 The condition a 2 * c 2 > x 1 + x 2 can clearly never hold in equilibrium. If it did hold, region 2 would shift resources from consumption to abatement spending. A resulting equilibrium must therefore fall into either Case 1 or Case 2 of the efficient allocations described in the previous section. The relative endowments will determine when the best responses of the regions will result in an efficient, High Global Welfare Solution, and when they will result in an efficient, Low Global Welfare Solution. Charts 3 and 4 below display why the utility function specifications are important. Chart 3 displays the resulting equilibria for two choices of x 2. Note that the best response curve for region 1 is the 45 degree line from the origin. At any point along this line, condition (8) will hold with equality. When region 2 selects an abatement contribution of x 2, the efficient allocation A will result. When region 2 selects an abatement contribution of zero (x 2 =0), the allocation that results (point B) will still be efficient (because it is still on the 45 degree line). Therefore, region 1 s utility level will change based on the abatement contribution of region 2, but this change will not impact efficiency. 5 In Caplan and Silva s model, there is a second type of inefficiency, referred to as market distortion, that results from changes in the international terms of trade between a polluting and a non-polluting good. Market distortion will not occur in this paper s model because of the assumption of only one consumption good. 10

11 ` Chart 3 Chart 4 Budget Constraint 45 line / Best Response Curve 45 line C x 1 x 2 x 1 A Indifference Curves x 2 D x 2 x 1 B x 1 x 2 x-axis: Environmental Awareness Parameter (a 1 ) * Consumption (c 1 ) Indifference Curves Chart 4 displays the general case in which region 1 has a smooth utility functions. The same two choices of x 2 are shown. A shift in region 2 s abatement contribution from x 2 to zero (x 2 = 0) will shift the equilibrium from point C to point D. As long as the term for the externality distortion is nonzero ( U 2 x 1 / U 2 c 2 = 0 ), neither of these points will be efficient solutions. Potential equilibrium allocations in the model with Leontief preferences can therefore be grouped into two categories that I will label E1 and E2: E1: a 1 * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 = a 2 * c 2, c 1 < c 2 x 1 > x 2 ; E2: a 1 * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 > a 2 * c 2, x 1 > x 2 = 0. Type E1 equilibria are High Global Welfare Solutions, as described in the previous section. For these allocations, the regions have the same total utility. Since region 1 has a higher level of environmental awareness than does region 2 (a 1 > a 2 ), it prefers to devote a lower portion of its endowment of resources to consumption. Since c 1 < c 2 and w 1 > w 2, it follows from the budget constraints that region 1 s contribution to global abatement is strictly higher than the contribution of region 2 (x 1 > x 2 ). 11

12 Type E2 equilibria are Low Global Welfare Solutions. For these allocations, the utility of region 1 is strictly greater than that of region 2. Region 2 does not contribute at all to global abatement in these equilibria. To see this, note that if x 2 were strictly positive, and (9) a 2 * c 2 < x 1 + x 2, then region 2 would shift resources from abatement contributions to consumption until a 2 * c 2 = x 1 + x 2. It follows that as long as condition (9) is an inequality, x 2 = 0. Type E1 equilibria will result when the difference in initial resource endowments is relatively small. In this situation, the relative benefit that region 1 receives from its greater endowment is counteracted by the relative benefit region 2 receives by contributing less to the public good. But while the difference in endowments can continue to grow unboundedly, region 2 cannot continue to contribute less to the public good (since negative abatement contributions are not feasible in this model). Once region 2 s contribution to global abatement is zero, any additional divergence in endowment will strictly benefit region 1. Type E2 equilibria will result from initial resource endowments for which the difference between w 1 and w 2 is beyond this threshold. Even though efficiency is achieved in equilibrium, total global welfare could be greater if the endowments of resources were closer to each other. This result that global welfare can be increased by transferring resources to the developing region mirrors many of the results in the literature. I will discuss this connection between this paper and the literature further in the next section. Type E2 equilibria are far more justifiable as depictions of reality than type E1 equilibria. In a type E1 equilibrium, the total consumption of the developing region is greater than that of the developed region. In the real world, this is clearly not the case. Data show that developed countries consume more and have far greater endowments of resources as defined in this model. Table 1 below displays GDP values for the relevant regions: Table 1: GDP and Population Statistics GDP Population Country/Region ($Billions) (Millions) European Union 14, United States 13, People's Republic of China 6,991 1,327 India 2,989 1,140 12

13 Moreover, there has been little to no cooperation in regard to greenhouse gas abatement between the heterogeneous regions that are discussed in this paper. Consistent with the characterization of the type E2 equilibria, developing countries such as China and India have been hesitant to risk slowing down the growth of their economies by devoting resources to emissions abatement efforts. On the other hand, the E.U. has already acted virtually unilaterally with a program to decrease global greenhouse gas emissions. And despite the inaction of the U.S. government, there is widespread support in the U.S. for Congress to follow the E.U. s lead in the upcoming years. V. A Three-stage Cooperative Game The recent literature has been optimistic in predicting cooperation among heterogeneous regions regarding the abatement of greenhouse gas emissions. Typically, this cooperation is achieved via the actions of an international organization ( IO ) with the ability to transfer resources among participating countries. Caplan and Silva (2007) describe an economy similar to the model in this paper, with bilateral negotiations between the central regulators of a rich and poor region. In this section, I will briefly explain how the game theoretic process of their model induces cooperation in an efficient and implementable equilibrium, and how this process could be applied to the model I have described above. Caplan and Silva utilize a three-stage game among a rich region, a poor region, and an IO. In the first stage, each region decides whether or not to participate in a coalition with the other. If either region decides not to participate, in the second stage, both regions simply maximize their own utility, as in the decentralized scenario of the previous section. If both regions choose to participate in the coalition, however, then each will choose its policy taking as given not only the action of the other region, but also the anticipated action of the IO in the third stage. In this third stage, with the regions policies already determined, the IO acts as a Stackelberg follower and transfers resources from one region to the other in accordance with a previously agreed upon equity principle. Specifically, the IO retains the relative rankings of international welfare levels of the decentralized case by ensuring that the ratios of each region s utility in the cooperative case to its utility in the decentralized case are equal. With this setup, Caplan and Silva find that efficiency in their model is restored since the anticipation of the transfers serve to align the incentives of the regions by forcing them to account for the impact of their own abatement spending on the other region s utility. The excess burden is therefore removed, and the IO has a larger pool of resources to distribute among the regions. The transfer scheme is implementable (it is a subgame perfect equilibrium) because the equity principle 13

14 ensures that each region is at least as well off as in the decentralized case, so each region will choose to participate. Cooperation among the rich and poor regions in abating global greenhouse gas emissions has thus been achieved. If a similar multi-stage game with international transfers is set up in this paper s model with Leontief preferences, transfers can no longer improve efficiency. As shown above, the equilibria are already efficient. Moreover, it is straightforward to show that any transfer of resources from region 1 to region 2 will make region 1 strictly worse off than had the transfer not occurred 6. Therefore, international transfers cannot be sustained in any subgame perfect equilibrium in this model. VI. Transfer Implications While transfers cannot increase efficiency in this model, it may be useful to determine the necessary transfers to induce the developing region to contribute to abatement, and therefore reach a higher level of total global welfare. Most other papers in the recent literature utilize cooperation on emissions abatement as a vehicle for increasing efficiency and total global welfare. However, these papers do not offer any interpretation of the magnitudes of the required transfers. Given the fairly innocuous assumption that smaller transfers are more politically feasible than larger transfers, the size of transfers could be a factor in explaining why we have not seen the type of cooperation predicted in the literature. The explicit utility functions of this paper yield a straightforward interpretation of the magnitudes of the necessary transfers to induce the developing region to contribute. Since this model is very nearly a special case of the models from the literature, the magnitudes of the necessary transfers will likely be similar. Consider the more realistic case described in Section IV in which the endowments are such that a type E2 equilibrium (a Low Global Welfare Solution) results. In this equilibrium, region 2 will not contribute to global abatement. Assuming for a moment that region 1 would agree to resource transfers to promote cooperation and higher global welfare, what level of transfers to region 2 would be necessary to shift to a High Global Welfare Solution? The transfers would need to be sufficient to reduce to the difference in endowments between the regions within the threshold of endowment divergence described above. Only then would a type E1 equilibrium (a High Global Welfare Solution) result. 6 This is due in part to the implicit assumption that the marginal costs of abatement to the regions are equal. 14

15 Recall that in a type E1 equilibrium, the consumption of region 2 is higher than that of region 1. Simple back-of-the-envelope calculations can roughly display the potential implications of this result. Total 2007 consumption was approximately $9.7 trillion in the U.S., $4.9 trillion in China and $2.1 trillion in India 7. In order to just equalize the consumption of the developed and the developing regions, a $2.4 trillion transfer from the U.S. to China or a $3.8 trillion transfer from the U.S. to India would be required. And since the consumption of region 2 actually needs to be strictly greater than that of region 1, even greater transfers would be necessary for a High Global Welfare Solution to be an equilibrium result. Transfers of this magnitude, even if individually rational, would arguably be politically infeasible regardless of how they were structured. VII. Conclusion This paper asks why previous papers have predicted meaningful international cooperation on the abatement of greenhouse gas emissions, and yet the real world has not produced examples of this success. I have offered a few potential explanations. First, the literature generally has not focused on the importance and unique challenges that come with the inclusion of a developing country such as China or India in the agreement. Additionally, depending of the form of the assumed preferences, an efficient solution may be one in which the developed region unilaterally contributes to abatement spending. With the Leontief preferences in the model I have presented, as long as the difference in resource endowments among the regions is above a certain threshold, efficiency does not involve any cooperation on abatement contributions. Finally, I have given an indication of the magnitude of international resource transfers needed to raise global welfare to its highest possible level. The necessary transfers may be too large to be politically feasible. Even if these transfers were optimal, a second best solution may be needed. Previous papers have not reached these conclusions. They generally have not focused on the importance of the participation of particular developing countries such as China and India, and the unique challenges that inducing their cooperation may present. Additionally, the assumption in previous papers that regions have identical preferences toward global abatement contributions may 7 Using GDP data for the U.S., China and India, and consumption data for the U.S., I assumed the ratio of consumption to GDP is equal across countries. 15

16 disregard underlying cultural differences among regions, and generally does not allow for the corner solutions that have been observed in real world negotiations. Finally, previous papers have not considered the magnitudes of necessary transfers. These results indicate that the recent policies of the U.S. and other developed countries to refrain from abatement spending until developing countries such as China and India agree to cooperate may be misguided. It is often assumed that although the developed countries were responsible for the vast majority of the emissions in the atmosphere, all countries will need to act in concert to respond to the problem. However, if cooperation with developing countries such as China and India cannot be achieved, unilateral action of the developed countries may be the only remaining option. This model in this paper could be improved in a number of ways going forward. First, I have considered only bilateral negotiations. While a small number of autonomous regions do contribute a huge percentage of greenhouse gas emissions, it would be useful to consider negotiations between at least three or four regions as well. Additionally, the assumption that the marginal benefit of abatement contributions is equal across regions for all levels of contributions may need to be revised. Finally, the concept of environmental awareness that I have considered in this paper may be better suited for a dynamic rather than a static model. Along these lines, it may be interesting to examine a model in which the preferences of the developing region can evolve as the region develops. Appendix A: Following Rapaport and Vidal, I will show that there exists an endogenously determined wealth threshold below which region 2 will not contribute to accumulating environmental awareness. First, I assume that the regions are in the efficient equilibrium in which: (10) f(q 1 ) * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 (11) f(q 2 ) * c 2 = x 1 + x 2. I substitute both conditions (10) and (11) into (x j + x -j ) in (1), and solve these two resulting equations simultaneously, yielding: (12) c j = f(q -j ) (w j + w -j - q j - q -j ) / [(1 + f(q j )) (1+f(q -j )) 1], for j=1,2. Then, I solve for the level of global abatement by plugging equations (12) back into (1): x 1 + x 2 = f(q 1 ) f(q 2 ) (w 1 + w 2 q 1 q 2 ) / [f(q 1 ) + f(q 2 ) + f(q 1 ) * f(q 2 )] The maximization problem for the representative agent of region 2 can then be written with an equivalent reduced form utility function in terms of q j : 16

17 Max [H(q 2 )], where H(q 2 ) = f(q 1 ) f(q 2 ) (w 1 + w 2 q 1 q 1 ) / [f(q 1 ) + f(q 2 ) + f(q 1 ) f(q 2 )] Taking a derivative with respect to q 2, H (q 2 ) is the same sign as: (13) G(q 2 ) = f(q 1 )^2 * f (q 2 ) * (w 1 + w 2 - q 1 - q 2 ) - f(q 1 ) * f(q 2 ) * [f(q 2 ) * (1 + f(q 1 )) + f(q 1 )] I then take the derivative of (13) with respect to q 2 : (14) G (q 2 ) = -f(q 1 )^2 * f (q 2 ) + f(q 1 )^2 * f (q 2 ) * (w 1 + w 2 - q 1 - q 2 ) -f(q 1 ) * f(q 2 ) * *f (q 2 ) * (1 + f (q 1 ))] f(q 1 ) * f (q 2 ) * [f(q 2 ) * (1 + f(q 1 )) + f(q 1 )] Condition (14) is strictly negative since the function f( ) is strictly positive, strictly increasing and strictly concave. This has two implications. First, H(q 2 ) is strictly concave, so a solution to H (q 2 ) = 0 will result in a maximum value. Second, G(q 2 ) is strictly decreasing in q 2. Case 1: Assume q 1 = w 1, c 1 = x 1 = 0. Then, G(w 2 ) = - f(q 1 ) * f(q 2 ) * [f(q 2 ) * (1 + f(q 1 )) + f(q 1 )] < 0 An interior solution for q 2 (q 2 > 0) therefore requires G(0) > 0, which implies w 2 > f(q 1 ) * f(0) * [f(q 2 ) * (1 + f(q 1 )) + f(q 1 )] / [f(q 1 ) * f (0)+ = w a > 0, where w a is a minimum wealth threshold below which q 2 = 0. Case 2: Assume q 1 < w 1 G(w 2 ) will be unambiguously larger than it was in Case 1 in which q 1 = w 1, which leads to 2 subcases: Case 2a: G(w 2 ) >= 0 Since G(q 2 ) is strictly decreasing, q 2 = w 2, and therefore c 2 = x 2 = 0 Case 2b: G(w 2 ) < 0 Then, as in Case 1, G(0) > 0 for an interior solution, implying w 2 > w b > 0, where w b is a minimum wealth threshold below which q 2 = 0. In both Cases 1 and 2a, note that one region s consumption is zero, and therefore its utility is zero, which cannot be optimal with strictly positive endowments. Therefore, I exclude these cases from consideration, leaving Case 2b, in which w b is the endogenously determined threshold above which a region will accumulate environmental resources, and below which it will not. I have thus far assumed that equations (10) and (11) bind. This result can also be applied to the equilibria for which: f(q 1 ) * c 1 = x 1 + x 2 f(q 2 ) * c 2 < x 1 + x 2, 17

18 and x 2 = 0. To see this, note that there is an equilibrium of type E1 (see Section IV above) for which x 2 = 0 (this is the exact point at which an additional unit of divergence between the endowments will lead to an equilibrium of type E2). At this equilibrium, there is an efficient solution in which, due to the proof above, q 2 = 0. Region 2 must have been maximizing the product c 2 * f(q 2 ) at this point. If q 2 = 0 maximizes this product in the High Global Welfare equilibrium in which x 2 = 0, it will also maximize this product in the Low Global Welfare equilibrium in which x 2 = 0. Therefore, the endogenously determined minimum wealth threshold described above applies to type E2 equilibria as well. I have therefore shown that as long as region 2 s endowment is below a certain threshold, the decentralized solution will lead to an equilibrium in which the poor region does not invest in accumulating environmental awareness and potentially does not contribute at all to global abatement. References Barrett, S. (1994), Self-enforcing international environmental agreements, Oxford Economic Papers, 46, Barrett, S. (2001), International cooperation for sale, European Economic Review, Volume 45, Issue 10. Becker, Gary S., Murphy, Kevin M. (1988), A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy 96, Botteon, Michele and Carraro, Carlo (1997), Environmental Coalitions With Heterogeneous Countries: Burden- Sharing and Carbon Leakage, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper No Buchner, B. and Carraro, C. (2006), US, China and the Economics of Climate Negotiations, Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics Caplan, Arthur J., Cornes, R. C., & Silva, E. C. D. (2003). An ideal kyoto protocol: Emissions trading, redistributive transfers and global participation, Oxford Economic Papers, 55, Caplan, Arthur J. and Silva, Emilson C. D. (2007), An equitable, efficient and implementable scheme to control global carbon dioxide emissions, International Tax and Public Finance. Chichilnisky, G., Heal, G., and Starrett, D. (2000), Equity and efficiency in environmental markets: global trade in carbon dioxide emissions, In G. Chichilnisky and G. Heal (Eds.), Environmental. Markets: equity and efficiency, New York: Columbia University press. Eyckmans, J., Finus, M. (2007), Measures to enhance the success of global climate change treaties, International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics. Hoel, M., & Schneider, K. (1997). Incentives to participate in an international environmental agreement, Environmental and Resource Economics, 9(2), McGinty, M. (2006), International environmental agreements among asymmetric nations, Oxford Economic Papers. Mulligan, Casey B. (1997). Parental Priorities and Economic Inequality. The University of Chicago Press. Rapaport, H. and Vidal, J.P. (2007), Economic growth and endogenous intergenerational altruism, Journal of Public Economics 91, Silva, E. and Zhu, X. (2008), Global trading of carbon dioxide permits with noncompliant polluters, International Tax and Public Finance. 18

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice Paul A Johnson Economics 304 Advanced Topics in Macroeconomics Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice A: The Two-Period Model Consider an individual who faces the problem of allocating their available

More information

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments Chapter 8: Exchange 8.1: Introduction In many ways this chapter is the most important in the book. If you have time to study just one, this is the one that you should study (even though it might be a bit

More information

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Learning Objectives: Students should learn to:. The student will understand the ideas of strategic interdependence and reasoning strategically and be able

More information

SOCIETAL RISK AVERSION AND THE GOVERNMENT SUPPORT OF GEOENGINEERING. 1. Introduction

SOCIETAL RISK AVERSION AND THE GOVERNMENT SUPPORT OF GEOENGINEERING. 1. Introduction SOCIETAL RISK AVERSION AND THE GOVERNMENT SUPPORT OF GEOENGINEERING Abstract. A fixed R&D budget for climate change prevention spending is allocated by the government between geoengineering and renewable

More information

Bilateral and Multilateral Exchanges for Peer-Assisted Content Distribution

Bilateral and Multilateral Exchanges for Peer-Assisted Content Distribution 1290 IEEE/ACM TRANSACTIONS ON NETWORKING, VOL. 19, NO. 5, OCTOBER 2011 Bilateral and Multilateral Exchanges for Peer-Assisted Content Distribution Christina Aperjis, Ramesh Johari, Member, IEEE, and Michael

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Climate Change Policy

Climate Change Policy Seventh Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis World Bank, June 17-19 Climate Change Policy Carlo Carraro University of Venice, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, CEPR, CEPS, CESifo 1 THE GLOBAL WARMING

More information

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro Microfoundations and General Equilibrium I. Introduction Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro economic theories and the general equilibrium approach to economic

More information

Productivity or Signaling?

Productivity or Signaling? Economics 623 Human Capital 4: Productivity or Signaling? Spring 2012 Productivity or Signaling? Why does education lead to higher earnings? The human capital perspective is that education raises the productivity

More information

Total Factor Productivity and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: A Comment and Some Intuition

Total Factor Productivity and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: A Comment and Some Intuition 1 Total Factor roductivity and the nvironmental Kuznets urve: A omment and Some Intuition eha Khanna* Department of conomics Binghamton niversity,.o. Box 6000 Binghamton, Y 13902-6000 hone: 607-777-2689,

More information

Applied Welfare Economics

Applied Welfare Economics Economics Monika Köppl - Turyna Department of Economics ISCTE-IUL Summer 2014/2015 Introduction We will have lectures and problem solving sessions (usually one per two lectures) Attendance is generally

More information

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent Dhimitri Qirjo Florida International University This Version: March 2010 Abstract This paper proposes a theory of free movement

More information

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models Preface Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics 1.1 Economic Models 1.1.1 Positive and Normative Analysis 1.1.2 The Market Economy Model 1.1.3 Types of Economic Problems 1.2 Mathematics

More information

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand.

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand. Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand May, 2005 Abstract Quality levels have been widely discussed in the

More information

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute WWW.RRI.WVU.EDU Spring 2007 Session One: THEORY Session 1: Theory What are CGE models? A brief review:

More information

1) Your answer to this question is what form of the exam you had. The answer is A if you have form A. The answer is B if you have form B etc.

1) Your answer to this question is what form of the exam you had. The answer is A if you have form A. The answer is B if you have form B etc. This is the guide to Fall 2014, Midterm 1, Form A. If you have another form, the answers will be different, but the solution will be the same. Please consult your TA or instructor if you think there is

More information

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Introduce the government. Construct closed-economy one-period macroeconomic model, which has: (i) representative consumer; (ii) representative

More information

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August IMPORTANT. You are expected to adhere to the following guidelines in completing the exam:

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August IMPORTANT. You are expected to adhere to the following guidelines in completing the exam: Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2009 This exam is designed to test your broad knowledge of microeconomics. There are three sections: one required and two choice sections. You must complete all three

More information

Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and Equity

Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and Equity 20th World Energy Congress, Enel Special Session Architectures for Agreement: Climate change policy post 2012 Rome, November 15, 2007 Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and

More information

Final Exam Study Questions:

Final Exam Study Questions: Final Exam Study Questions: Practice Multiple-Choice Questions 1. If a consumer purchases only two goods (X and Y ) and the demand for X is elastic, then a rise in the price of X a. will cause total spending

More information

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit Modern Economy, 07, 8, 99-0 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 5-76 ISSN Print: 5-745 The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit Feifei Zheng

More information

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy Policy Brief Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research U.S. Climate-Change Policy: The Bush Administration s Plan and Beyond Lawrence H. Goulder In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration

More information

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change Some Simple Economics of Climate Change Kevin M. Murphy The University of Chicago September 7, 2008 Climate Change Climate change has emerged as a significant policy issue. In the U.S. both Presidential

More information

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern:

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern: December 2016 Professors Joseph Stiglitz and Lord Nicholas Stern Co-Chairs of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition and World Bank Group Subject: Commission on

More information

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series ISSN 1791-3144 University of Macedonia Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series International Environmental Agreements: An emission choice model with abatement technology Eftichios Sartzetakis and

More information

A nash equilibrium game and pareto efficient solution to a cooperative advertising

A nash equilibrium game and pareto efficient solution to a cooperative advertising IOSR Journal of Mathematics (IOSR-JM) e-issn: 78-578, p-issn: 319-765X. Volume 11, Issue 1 Ver. V (Jan - Feb. 015), PP 100-104 www.iosrjournals.org A Nash Equilibrium Game and Pareto Efficient Solution

More information

GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: STRATEGIC INTERACTIONS OR UNILATERAL GAINS?

GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: STRATEGIC INTERACTIONS OR UNILATERAL GAINS? 40 TH IAEE INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE SINGAPORE, 18-21 JUNE 2017 GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: STRATEGIC INTERACTIONS OR UNILATERAL GAINS? SIGIT PERDANA Business School, University of Western Australia

More information

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Gerhard Clemenz March 2012 Abstract: According to the Porter Hypothesis (PH) stricter environmental regulations

More information

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth. Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth. Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007 Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine April 4, 2007 The Conventional View innovation along quality ladder, driven by short-term monopoly power fixed costs

More information

VALUE OF SHARING DATA

VALUE OF SHARING DATA VALUE OF SHARING DATA PATRICK HUMMEL* FEBRUARY 12, 2018 Abstract. This paper analyzes whether advertisers would be better off using data that would enable them to target users more accurately if the only

More information

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market Qihong Liu Jie Shuai January 18, 2014 Abstract Advancing in information technology has empowered firms with unprecedented flexibility when interacting

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior

Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior Lancaster, K. J. (1966). A new Approach to Consumer Theory. Journal of Political Economy. 74, 132-157. Traditional theories of consumer behavior do not take into account

More information

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability Oksana Loginova October 27, 2016 Abstract This paper studies the impact of competition on the benefits of advance selling. I construct a two-period

More information

Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs

Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs DET ØKONOMISKE RÅD S E K R E T A R I A T E T Nordic Carbon Dioxide Abatement Costs Jens Hauch Working Paper 1999:6 The Secretariat publishes a series of Working Papers, which primarily contains detailed

More information

Inventory Systems with Transshipments and Quantity Discounts

Inventory Systems with Transshipments and Quantity Discounts Wright State University CORE Scholar Browse all Theses and Dissertations Theses and Dissertations 2012 Inventory Systems with Transshipments and Quantity Discounts Gregory Daniel Noble Wright State University

More information

Externalities and the Environment

Externalities and the Environment Externalities and the Environment What is an Externality? When a person/firm does something that affects the interests of another person or firm without affecting prices. Examples: Traffic/telephone/internet

More information

International Negotiations for Reducing Greenhouse Gases with Emission Permits Trading

International Negotiations for Reducing Greenhouse Gases with Emission Permits Trading International Negotiations for Reducing Greenhouse Gases with Emission Permits Trading Koichi Tadenuma December 2003 Abstract We build a three-stage game model of international negotiations on regulation

More information

How Much Should You Invest In Software Security?

How Much Should You Invest In Software Security? How Much Should You Invest In Software Security? Kelce S. Wilson, PhD, MBA, J.D. Research In Motion 122 West John Carpenter Freeway, Suite 430 Irving, TX 75039 USA Abstract - A Protection Valuation Tool

More information

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Ricardo Cavalcanti Getulio Vargas Foundation Ed Nosal Cleveland Fed November 006 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We describe counterfeiting activity

More information

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Abstract. Revenue management (RM) is the art and science of predicting consumer behavior and optimizing price and product availability to maximize

More information

SUBJ SCORE # Version D: Page 1 of 9. (signature) 2. Please write your name and GU ID carefully and legibly at the top of this page.

SUBJ SCORE # Version D: Page 1 of 9. (signature) 2. Please write your name and GU ID carefully and legibly at the top of this page. SUBJ SCORE # Version D: Page 1 of 9 Economics 001 NAME Professor Levinson GU ID # Midterm #2 November 12, 2012 DO NOT BEGIN WORKING UNTIL THE INSTRUCTOR TELLS YOU TO DO SO. READ THESE INSTRUCTIONS FIRST.

More information

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions Welfare Economics The Edgeworth Box The Basic Theorem The basic theorem in welfare economics: A market, exchange, economy will achieve efficient resource allocation. We intend to show the basics of that

More information

EU Emissions Trading: What is at Stake? Volkswirtschaftliches Kolloquium, Ruhr-Universität Bochum 22. January, 2008

EU Emissions Trading: What is at Stake? Volkswirtschaftliches Kolloquium, Ruhr-Universität Bochum 22. January, 2008 EU Emissions Trading: What is at Stake? Volkswirtschaftliches Kolloquium, Ruhr-Universität Bochum 22. January, 2008 Generic Approach to Environmental Policy Analysis Identification of incentive problems

More information

Economic Concepts. Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change

Economic Concepts. Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change Economic Concepts and Applications to Climate Change Economic Concepts When markets work and when they don t t work Policy Interventions to correct market failures Recent research in climate change 1 Part

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013 Pricing with market power and oligopolistic markets (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Module 4 Sep. 28, 2013

More information

Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets?

Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets? Should Consumers Be Priced Out of Pollution-Permit Markets? Stefani C. Smith and Andrew J. Yates Abstract: The authors present a simple diagrammatic exposition of a pollutionpermit market in which both

More information

Industrial Organization Entry Costs, Market Structure and Welfare

Industrial Organization Entry Costs, Market Structure and Welfare ECON 312: Determinants of irm & Market Size 1 Industrial Organization Entry Costs, Market Structure and Welfare Your economics courses has thus far examined how firms behave under differing market structures,

More information

1.5 Nov 98 a. Explain the term natural monopolies and why are they considered a danger if left unregulated. [10] b. (not in 2013 syllabus)

1.5 Nov 98 a. Explain the term natural monopolies and why are they considered a danger if left unregulated. [10] b. (not in 2013 syllabus) Higher Level Essays Microeconomics only 1.5 (old syllabus specimen) a. Explain the main features of an oligopolistic market. [10] b. Discuss whether oligopolies work in favor of, or against the interest

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly

Volume 30, Issue 3. Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly Volume 30, Issue 3 Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly Luigi Filippini Università Cattolica, Milano Abstract We argue that cross-licensing is a device to establish

More information

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation

Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Climate policy and uncertainty: the roles of adaptation versus mitigation Warwick J. McKibbin and Peter J. Wilcoxen Australian National University Economics and Environment Network Working Paper EEN0306

More information

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling Organized by Economics and Social Commission for Western Asia (September 29, 2017) Beirut Presented by: Yves Surry: Professor at the Swedish

More information

Macroeconomics, 10e (Parkin) Chapter 2 The Economic Problem. 1 Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost

Macroeconomics, 10e (Parkin) Chapter 2 The Economic Problem. 1 Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost Macroeconomics, 10e (Parkin) Chapter 2 The Economic Problem 1 Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost 1) The production possibilities frontier is the boundary between A) those combinations of goods

More information

The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage

The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage Dusan Drabik Graduate student Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, USA dd387@cornell.edu Harry

More information

Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution

Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution Geoffrey Heal a Graduate School of Business Columbia University and Nori Tarui b Department of Economics University of Hawai i at Mānoa

More information

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION 5. Game Theory Mr. Sydney Armstrong Lecturer 1 The University of Guyana 1 Semester 1, 2016 OUR PLAN Analyze Strategic price and Quantity Competition (Noncooperative Oligopolies)

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms Hongru Tan and Julian Wright March, 2018 Abstract We show that in the context of pricing by a multi-sided platform, in addition to the classical market-power

More information

General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition

General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition Chapter 12 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair General Equilibrium and the Efficiency

More information

ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS & MANAGEMENT MEMORANDUM

ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS & MANAGEMENT MEMORANDUM # 123 Efficiency vs. stability of climate coalitions: a conceptual and computational appraisal Thierry Bréchet, François Gérard and Henry Tulkens April 2010 ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS & MANAGEMENT MEMORANDUM

More information

Nash bargaining solutions for international climate agreements under different sets of bargaining weights

Nash bargaining solutions for international climate agreements under different sets of bargaining weights Int Environ Agreements (2017) 17:709 729 DOI 10.1007/s10784-017-9351-3 ORIGINAL PAPER Nash bargaining solutions for international climate agreements under different sets of bargaining weights S. Yu 1 E.

More information

ECON 1100 Global Economics Exam #2 Fall 2010 (Version B) Multiple Choice Questions ( 2. points each):

ECON 1100 Global Economics Exam #2 Fall 2010 (Version B) Multiple Choice Questions ( 2. points each): ECON 11 Global Economics Exam #2 Fall 21 (Version B) 1 Multiple Choice Questions ( 2 2 points each): 1. In a free market economy, households A. sell finished goods and services to firms. B. receive income

More information

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Suman Ghosh Kameshwari Shankar Abstract A common form of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) by firmsistoagreetodonatea fixed portion of private

More information

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University Montreal v. Kyoto Scott Barrett Columbia University Obligations Domestic v. International Title IV Kyoto Caps SO 2 by plant. Caps GHG by states. Trading Yes Yes Monitoring Precise Self-reporting Participation

More information

Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics

Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics (see Chapter 5 of the textbook: erman, Ma, McGilvray, Common) - the starting point of most economic analysis is the neoclassical general equilibrium theory - this

More information

Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets

Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets Robert A. Ritz Faculty of Economics & Energy Policy Research Group (EPRG) University of Cambridge 2014 Toulouse Energy Conference

More information

Introduction Question Bank

Introduction Question Bank Introduction Question Bank 1. Science of wealth is the definition given by 2. Economics is the study of mankind of the ordinary business of life given by 3. Science which tells about what it is & what

More information

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity Countervailing Power and Product Diversity by Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Work in Progress December 6, 2003 Abstract To analyse the effects of countervailing power on product variety, I construct a

More information

ANSWER OUTLINE. DATE: Thursday, March 12, 11:00am Econ 308, Spring 2009

ANSWER OUTLINE. DATE: Thursday, March 12, 11:00am Econ 308, Spring 2009 ANSWER OUTLINE Midterm Exam (80 Points Total) Leigh Tesfatsion DATE: Thursday, March 12, 11:00am Econ 308, Spring 2009 NOTE: Please answer ALL FOUR questions included on this test. In answering these questions,

More information

Professor Jan Hanousek CERGE-EI Charles University Academy of Sciences Politickych veznu 7 P.O.Box Prague Czech Republic

Professor Jan Hanousek CERGE-EI Charles University Academy of Sciences Politickych veznu 7 P.O.Box Prague Czech Republic HU WiWi, Mikroökonomische Theorie 10099 Berlin Professor Jan Hanousek CERGE-EI Charles University Academy of Sciences Politickych veznu 7 P.O.Box 882 111 21 Prague Czech Republic Faculty of Economics Chair

More information

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Kyoto University, Graduate School of Economics Research Project Center Discussion Paper Series Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Hide-Fumi Yokoo and Thomas C. Kinnaman Discussion Paper No. E-09-002

More information

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY 1993, Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics 6(1), 161 64.

More information

An experimental study of competition in two-sided markets

An experimental study of competition in two-sided markets An experimental study of competition in two-sided markets Kenan Kalaycı University of Queensland Kian Nam Loke Queensland Competition Authority Stuart McDonald Hanqing Advanced Institute of Economics and

More information

On mergers in a Stackelberg market with asymmetric convex costs

On mergers in a Stackelberg market with asymmetric convex costs On mergers in a Stackelberg market with asymmetric convex costs Marc Escrihuela-Villar Universitat de les Illes Balears April, 2013 (PRELIMINARY VERSION) Abstract This paper analyzes profitability, the

More information

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives Paolo Fulghieri University of North Carolina Merih Sevilir University of North Carolina Abstract This paper studies mergers between competing firms and shows

More information

Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage"

Web Appendix to Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage" Meredith L. Fowlie Abstract This appendix provides additional details and results to support the main

More information

Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction

Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction David McAdams September 23, 20 Abstract Suppose bidders may publicly choose not to learn their values prior to a second-price auction with costly bidding.

More information

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University Montreal v. Kyoto Scott Barrett Columbia University One World Many Countries Obligations Domestic v. International Title IV Kyoto Caps SO 2 by plant. Caps GHG by states. Trading Yes Yes Monitoring Precise

More information

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria Slide Slide 3 Recall from last time A Nash Equilibrium occurs when: Econ 40: Micro Theory Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria Monday, December 3 rd, 007 Each firm s action is a best

More information

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as Economists typically assume that firms or a firm s owners try to maximize their profit. et R be revenues of the firm, and C be the cost of production, then a firm s profit can be represented as follows,

More information

Output-based rebating of carbon taxes. when playing with others: competitiveness and welfare considerations

Output-based rebating of carbon taxes. when playing with others: competitiveness and welfare considerations 1 Output-based rebating of carbon taxes when playing with others: competitiveness and welfare considerations by Christoph Böhringer, Brita Bye, Taran Fæhn, and Knut Einar Rosendahl 1 Introduction Lack

More information

UWM Digital Commons. University of Wisconsin Milwaukee. Zheng Wang University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee. Theses and Dissertations

UWM Digital Commons. University of Wisconsin Milwaukee. Zheng Wang University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee. Theses and Dissertations University of Wisconsin Milwaukee UWM Digital Commons Theses and Dissertations 5-1-2014 Three Essays on the Economics of Spatial Price Discrimination: Strategic Delegation Under Spatial Price Discrimination

More information

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

1 Preliminaries. 1.1 What is Macroeconomics?

1 Preliminaries. 1.1 What is Macroeconomics? 1 Preliminaries 1.1 What is Macroeconomics? Letusstartfromadefinition of economics. Economics is the science concerned with interpreting and predicting social behavior in terms of the incentives and the

More information

Working papers of the Department of Economics University of Perugia (IT) Favoritism in public procurement auctions: model of endogenous entry

Working papers of the Department of Economics University of Perugia (IT) Favoritism in public procurement auctions: model of endogenous entry ISSN 2385-2275 Working papers of the Department of Economics University of Perugia (IT) Favoritism in public procurement auctions: model of endogenous entry Maria Ostrovnaya Elena Podkolzina Working paper

More information

58.5% 17.3% 17.0% 7.1%

58.5% 17.3% 17.0% 7.1% CHAPTER 7 - INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY In the first chapter of the book, we examined the nature of the global economy. We saw that the nations of the world are becoming more economically interdependent.

More information

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level ECONOMICS 9708/41 Paper 4 Data Response and Essays MARK SCHEME Maximum Mark: 70 Published This

More information

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money Main Aims: 1. Answer following two questions: Why money is used as a medium of exchange? How and why money improves allocations in an economy and

More information

Special Section 1: Carbon Trading: An opportunity for Pakistan

Special Section 1: Carbon Trading: An opportunity for Pakistan First Quarterly Report for FY10 Special Section 1: Carbon Trading: An opportunity for Pakistan SS1.1 Background There is an international consensus that global warming has significantly jeopardized the

More information

Ch. 7 outline. 5 principles that underlie consumer behavior

Ch. 7 outline. 5 principles that underlie consumer behavior Ch. 7 outline The Fundamentals of Consumer Choice The focus of this chapter is on how consumers allocate (distribute) their income. Prices of goods, relative to one another, have an important role in how

More information

The Efficient Allocation of Individuals to Positions

The Efficient Allocation of Individuals to Positions The Efficient Allocation of Individuals to Positions by Aanund Hylland and Richard Zeckhauser Presented by Debreu Team: Justina Adamanti, Liz Malm, Yuqing Hu, Krish Ray Hylland and Zeckhauser consider

More information

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January 2011 Economics Assessment Unit A2 1 Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 28 JANUARY, AFTERNOON MARK SCHEME 6364.01 General Marking Instructions This mark

More information

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework ARNAUD CHÉRON (GAINS-TEPP, UNIVERSITY OF LE MANS) Attribution Non commercial - No Derivative Work : http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.0/fr/

More information

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies 14.03 Spring 2003 1 Externalities: The Coase Theorem and Market Remedies 1.1 Introduction You have seen externalities in 14.01. An externality

More information

Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem

Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem JEL Codes: D0, L0 1. Introduction World Review of Business Research Vol. 2. No. 6. November 2012. Pp. 84 99 Damaged Durable Goods: Mitigating the Time Inconsistency Problem Xiaojing (Joanne) MA * In this

More information

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Pricing Under Homogeneous Oligopoly We will assume that the

More information

Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities

Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities Investment and emission control under technology and pollution externalities (Original title: Technology diffusion, abatement cost, and transboundary pollution) July 2009 Geoffrey Heal a, Nori Tarui b

More information