The Economics of the Long Tail

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Economics of the Long Tail"

Transcription

1 The Economics of the Long Tail Todd D. Kendall and Kevin K. Tsui Compass Lexecon and Clemson University October 20, 2008 Abstract Anderson (2006) argues that e-commerce and other new technologies improve e ciency by encouraging the entry of new producers and innovations, creating a long tail of niche products while reducing the market share of previously popular products. We study the strategic interaction between hits and niches in their pricing, entry, and innovation decisions using a model of product di erentiation with generalized cost structure. In contrast to the popular view, we show that improvements in information and communication technology can lead to either the long tail e ect or an opposite superstar e ect (Rosen, 1981), depending on (a) how the structure (not simply the level) of producer costs changes, and (b) how disparate are consumer preferences. These two factors also determine whether there is excessive or insu cient product diversity. Post-entry product and technology innovation incentives are ine cient in the long tail market structure because producers can soften price competition by engaging in excessive product di erentiation and adopting technologies with high variable costs. These results have implications on competitive policy, the paradox of choice, social fragmentation, and network neutrality. JEL Classi cations: L11, L86, M13, O31, K21 We acknowledge helpful comments and suggestions from Bill Dougan, Tim Perri, Ivan Png, Chad Syverson, Irina Suleymanova, Chuck Thomas, Bob Tollison, Julian Wright, and seminar participants at Clemson, National University of Singapore, the North American Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society 2007, and the Intertic Conference on Endogenous Market Structure and Industrial Policy. All remaining errors are our own. Correspondence may be addressed to Kevin K. Tsui, John E. Walker Department of Economics, Clemson University, ( ktsui@clemson.edu).

2 What changes in the future will be wrought by cable, video cassettes, and home computers? Sherwin Rosen I. Introduction The e ects of the internet on price levels and dispersion in various industries have been explored extensively. 1 Of equal interest, however, is the role of internet technology in changing the number and market shares of producers in these industries. An in uential trade book by Anderson (2006) considers this question and contends that e-commerce is creating a long tail of entry by individually-minor (through collectively important) niche suppliers in many industries, while reducing the relative importance of mainstream products. He argues for important normative e ects from increased entry, and in particular, the shift from the production of a few, monolithic hit products to the production of many separate niche products, both because it implies greater variety and satisfaction of niche preferences, and because it increases the likelihood that unknown, but talented individuals will enter markets where they can generate valuable innovations. 2 The long tail e ect is also related to important welfare debates on competition policy, cultural fragmentation, and network neutrality regulation. Theoretical and empirical research on the long tail e ect has reached con icting conclusions. Brynjolfsson, et al. (2007) and Emre, et al. (2007) both consider a decline in consumer search costs due to the introduction of e-commerce; however, the former authors argue for a long tail e ect, 3 while the latter argue that these cost reductions have actually had the opposite e ect, creating a superstar e ect in the sense of Rosen (1981), who argued that earlier communications technologies such as radio and television primarily served to increase the extent of scale economies among high quality suppliers. In this paper, we provide a uni ed theoretical framework to consider the e ects of the internet on industrial structure, e ciency, and innovation incentives. Our model is able to show how progress in information and communication technology may create long tails in some cases, and superstars in others, depending on how the structure (not simply the level) of producer costs changes with the introduction of the new technology, and how disparate are consumer preferences. In particular, we show that technological innovations that reduce xed costs relative to variable costs encourage entry by marginal producers, and thus generate long tail e ects in industries with plentiful horizontal di erentiation. By contrast, technologies that reduce variable costs relative to xed costs in highly vertically-di erentiated industries lead to strategic exclusion of marginal entrants, and thus, superstar e ects. Intuitively, high variable costs serve as a mechanism to soften price 1 See Ellison and Ellison (2005) for a review of the literature. 2 Today, millions of ordinary people have the tools and the role models to become amateur producers. Some of them will also have talent and vision. Because the means of production have spread so widely and to so many people, the talented and visionary ones, even if they re just a small fraction of the total, are becoming a force to be reckoned with (Anderson 2006, p. 65). 3 Technically, Brynjolfsson, et al. (2007) only argue for a short-run long tail e ect. They show that this e ect may be diminished in the long run as rms adjust their investments in the development of di erent products. 1

3 competition and customer-stealing among competing suppliers, while high xed costs reduce contestability by potential entrants. Therefore, it is unsurprising that the internet may have had di erent e ects in di erent industries, and the future direction of internet innovation may be to lengthen or shorten the tail in any given industry. With a better understanding of the long tail e ect, we can address several related welfare and regulatory issues. First, it is sometimes claimed that the internet has reduced the necessity for enforcement of competition laws in some industries, such as cross-ownership restrictions in radio and television (McKenzie and Lee, 2001, Crampton and Boudreaux, 2004). Our model implies conditions under which long tails and superstar e ects are e cient, and hence, when the internet may be a substitute (or complement) for antitrust enforcement. In particular, it is possible for technological change to generate excessive entry in some cases and insu cient entry in others. Second, Anderson (2006) argues that the increased variety of products available due to the internet has increased consumer welfare; however, Sunstein (2001) points out a darker side to the long tail social and cultural fragmentation. By providing a simple framework for distinguishing where internet technology creates long tails and generates excessive product di erentiation, our model can be a guide to where concern over fragmentation should rest. Finally, an important aspect of the debate over network neutrality legislation is the concern that broadband providers may raise costs to marginal entrants in internet application markets, and so reduce entry and innovation. Our model shows that the ability of network neutrality legislation to solve this problem depends on just how broadband providers would, in actuality, change the structure of costs, and how consumer preferences for internet applications are distributed. More generally, we demonstrate how niche product suppliers may innovate in order to gain access to an industry, and how incumbent producers may innovate in order to strategically exclude niche products. In many cases, we show that neutrality regulation would be counterproductive. Section II exposits our model and considers the e ects of exogenous technological change in generating long tail and superstar e ects. Section III shows how the model uni es previous theoretical and empirical ndings on the long tail e ect. Section IV considers the e ciency of market equilibria, and so addresses the general issue of how the internet a ects the value of competition laws, as well as addressing the paradox of choice and the problem of excessive social fragmentation. Section V studies producer incentives to innovate and the model s implications for network neutrality regulation, while Section VI concludes. II. A Model of Di erentiated Products with Fixed and Variable Costs of Production According to Anderson (2006), the internet reduces the cost of reaching niche pockets of consumers, and thus, the long tail is created as product selection switches from a few hit products to a multitude of varied niche products. To capture this idea, we present a model, the formal structure of which is an adaptation 2

4 of the duopoly model used in Davis, Murphy, and Topel (2004) (hereafter, DMT ). This duopoly setting is very simple, but it highlights the strategic interaction between incumbents and new niches in particular, their pricing, entry, and innovation decisions. The solution concept developed by DMT also enables us to focus on unique pure-strategy equilibria, which are useful for comparative analysis. We shall argue, however, that our key intuitions can be generalized to some standard oligopoly models with free entry, which suggests the robustness of these assumptions and our solution concept. Consumer demand in our model is more exible than in some other models, allowing for both vertical and horizontal product di erentiation, although this demand characteristic is not emphasized in DMT. More importantly, the major novelty here is to introduce a generalized cost structure in this framework, which highlights how a reduction in the costs of reaching niche consumers can have ambiguous e ects on entry, pricing, and innovation decisions, and how declines in cost interact with both vertical and horizontal di erentiation in consumer preferences, which we argue is crucial in understanding the nature and implications of the long tail. Moreover, introducing this generalized cost structure also allows us to study incentives for cost-saving technology innovation which are not considered in DMT. Subsection A exposits notation and describes the equilibrium concept we employ, while subsections B and C depict the properties of two possible types of equilibrium in the model. Subsection D supplies existence conditions for each type of equilibrium and illustrates how technological change can a ect these conditions. Subsection E illustrates the robustness of our major ndings in other theoretical frameworks. II.A. Theoretical Framework and Equilibrium Concept Consider a market with two single-product producers, each of whom sets a single price and maximizes pro ts. We will refer to them as the hit producer (h) and the niche producer (n), indicating their relative popularity in a market when both supply positive output, as discussed below. The production technology is de ned by xed costs F F; paid if a producer enters the market, and variable costs, V C(); where F and V are parameters which shift the cost structure. 4 We also assume that C() is increasing and convex, and thus, average variable cost, denoted C(), is increasing. To focus on the e ects of changes in the cost structure, we also assume for now that both producers have access to the same technology; however, our results are robust to this assumption, which will be relaxed in Section V when we study strategic technology innovation. There are N consumers, of which N f have fringe tastes, and N p = N N f have popular tastes. Denote the relative number of fringe customers by = N f =N p < 1. Consumers have unit demand, so that each of them will purchase at most one unit of either the hit or the niche product. 5 Let V p and V f be 4 For simplicity, we parameterize only the level of variable cost, but see note 16 below where we brie y consider shifts in the shape of the variable cost function. 5 Individual unit demand and constant population implies aggregate demand is inelastic when all consumers purchase from 3

5 the valuations of the hit product by popular- and fringe-taste consumers, respectively. Similarly, denote consumers valuations of the niche product by W p and W f. To distinguish consumers, assume that popular-taste consumers value the hit product more highly than fringe consumers, i.e., V p > V f : Thus, the majority of consumers (popular-taste) prefer the hit product. It is also natural to interpret these demand parameters in terms of the degree of vertical and horizontal di erentiation. An increase in (V p W p ) or (V f W f ) represents an increase in the hit s vertical di erentiation over the niche. Similarly, an increase in (V p V f ) or (W f W p ) represents an increase in horizontal di erentiation between the two products. Denote the producers chosen prices by P h and P n : Participation by popular-taste consumers requires V p P h or W p P n ; similarly, fringe consumer participation requires V f P h or W f P n : We will assume throughout that these constraints do not bind. We will also assume that each producer could feasibly sell to either consumer type and cover its costs: N i V i F F + V C(N i ) and N i W i F F + V C(N i ) for i = p; f. These assumptions make the problem non-trivial. The hit and the niche play a simultaneous price-setting game. After prices are selected, each consumer chooses to buy either the hit s product or the niche s. In the model, a supplier can choose not to enter the market by setting a su ciently high price that neither consumer type chooses to buy its product. We will focus throughout on potential entry by the niche, while assuming the hit always enters (the set of primitives for which this is true is broad: see DMT for a fuller analysis of entry incentives for incumbent suppliers). When producers compete in price under this exible demand speci cation and general cost structure, our model has no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium in general. Thus, we borrow a solution concept from DMT, price-cut immune (PCI) equilibrium, which assumes buyers always have the right to purchase at a previously announced price and hence producers are only ready to reduce their prices whenever undercutting and grabbing their rivals customers is pro table (see also Morgan and Shy (2000) and Shy (1996, 2001)). 6 In equilibrium, no seller has an incentive to lower its price in order to steal the rival rm s customers, although they may wish to raise prices. This equilibrium concept delivers unique pure-strategy equilibria. Pure strategy solutions may be preferred here, both because they are simpler and because traditional Bertrand solution concepts in such games are often subject to severe multiple equilibria issues (Baye and Morgan 1999) and are infeasible for many of the important applications to which the model may be applied. 7 DMT show that this equilibrium concept is a natural extension of the more standard Nash-Bertrand pricing equilibrium, some producers in equilibrium, but see section II.E for discussion related to relaxation of this assumption. 6 This solution concept is also known as undercut-proof equilibrium, which speci es a speci c type of conjectural variation behavior in which each rm assumes that the rival rm will alter its price only if such an action satis es two properties: (a) the undercutting rm will enlarge its market share by appropriating the customers of the rms it undercuts, and (b) such undercutting is pro table. 7 In addition, there are the usual concerns regarding the application of mixed strategy solutions (e.g., see Radner and Rosenthal, 1982, or Rubinstein, 1991). 4

6 and implies outcomes identical to those of Nash-Bertrand in many simple frameworks. 8 Formally, De nition 1 (Price-Cut Immune Prices). A set of prices P h ; P n is price-cut immune (PCI) if h (P h ; P n) h (P h ; P n) for all P h < P h and n (P h ; P n ) n (P h ; P n) for all P n < P n; where h and n represent the hit and the niche s pro ts, respectively. In other words, a set of prices is price-cut immune when, given all competitors prices, no individual producer wishes to cut its own price (although it may, however, wish to raise its price). If no producer wished to either cut or raise its price, these prices would correspond to the traditional Nash-Bertrand outcome. De ne i(p i ) as the set of all price-cut immune prices for producer i = h; n, given the price set by its competitor ( i ). Then De nition 2 (Price-Cut Immune Equilibrium). A PCI equilibrium is de ned as a set of prices P h ; P n such that and h (P h ; P n) = n (P h ; P n) = max h(p h ; Pn) P h 2 h(pn ) max P n2 n(p h ) h(p h ; P n ): One intuitive way of justifying this form of equilibrium is by assuming producers make binding price announcements (for example, through advertising), after which consumers perceive further price increases as reneging on a deal, although price reductions are, naturally, acceptable to consumers. When producers face di culty raising prices above previously announced levels, PCI equilibrium is a natural solution concept and forms an extension to ordinary Bertrand competition. 9 8 For example, in a standard model of Bertrand competition between two producers with di erentiated products, the unique PCI equilibrium is also the Nash equilibrium. For price competition between rms producing di erentiated brands, Morgan and Shy (2000) show that whereas a Nash- Bertrand equilibrium in pure actions never exists, a unique undercut-proof equilibrium always exists and has the following properties: (a) brands prices monotonically diverge when the brands become more di erentiated, and are identical when the brands become homogeneous; (b) the rm with the larger market share charges a lower price than the rm with the smaller market share but earns a larger pro t. The undercut-proof equilibrium also supports an upper bound on colluding prices in a dynamic meeting-the-competition price game. 9 Alternatively, Morgan and Shy (2000) argue that in an undercut-proof equilibrium environment, rms assume that rival rms are more sophisticated in that they are ready to reduce their prices whenever undercutting and grabbing their rivals customers is pro table. 5

7 In subsections B and C, we describe the properties of two possible types of PCI equilibria in our game. Subsection D supplies existence conditions for each, and illustrates comparative statics in the model. II.B. Equilibrium Type 1: The Long Tail Consider rst an equilibrium in which both the hit and the niche products are produced and sold in the market what we will refer to as a long tail equilibrium. In a stylized manner, this outcome corresponds to Anderson s (2006) notion that internet technology has introduced many new niche products into music, book, lm, and other industries, while reducing the market share of the incumbent products. More speci cally, we will focus on a sorting equilibrium in which popular-taste consumers purchase the hit product and fringe-taste consumers purchase the niche product. 10 A necessary condition for this equilibrium is that V p W p > V f W f, which we will assume for the rest of the analysis. In order for popular-taste consumers to buy the hit product, they must receive higher consumer surplus than they would receive by purchasing the niche product: P h P n + (V p W p ): (1) Similarly, for fringe-taste consumers to buy the niche product, it must be the case that P h P n + (V f W f ): (2) Also, in equilibrium, the hit must receive higher pro ts selling to popular-taste consumers exclusively, compared with cutting its price to P n + (V f W f ) in order to attract the fringe-taste consumers as well. This implies P h N p C(N p ) F F [P n + (V f W f )]N V C(N) F F; which can be rearranged as P h 1 N p f[p n + (V f W f )]N V [C(N) C(N p )]g : (3) Similarly, the niche producer prefers selling only to fringe consumers: P h (W p V p ) + 1 N f[p nn f + V [C(N) C(N f )]g : (4) Any pair of prices satisfying equations (3) and (4) is price-cut immune because neither supplier wishes 10 It is also possible under some parameterizations for the hit supplier to sell to fringe-taste consumers only and the niche supplier to sell to popular-taste consumers only (see DMT), but we ignore this possibility for simplicity here. 6

8 to cut its price to attract additional customers, given the other s price. Moreover, note that since V p W p > V f W f ; equations (1) and (2) cannot simultaneously bind. As an example, consider the case illustrated in Figure 1, Panel A, where we plot all four equations in P h -P n space. If there is a long tail equilibrium, it must lie strictly within the corridor formed by equations (1) and (2), since otherwise, all consumers would buy from only one of the two suppliers (or neither). Restricting ourselves to this space, we proceed to show that if an equilibrium exists in this region, it is at point e. Since equations (3) and (4) bind at point e, it is necessarily PCI. Then consider any niche producer price below Pn L. If this price were consistent with a long tail equilibrium, the hit s pro t-maximizing PCI response would be to set its price according to the minimum of lines (1) and (4), evaluated at the candidate niche price. But then the niche could do better and still be PCI by raising its price in order to make equation (3) bind. Similarly, consider a niche price above Pn L. Again, if this price were consistent with a long tail equilibrium, the hit must set its price in order to make equation (4) bind. But then the niche s price is no longer PCI. This argument illustrates that if there is a long tail equilibrium, point e, i.e., (Ph L; P n L ), is the only such equilibrium. Panel A represents a particular case in which when equations (3) and (4) bind, equations (1) and (2) automatically hold. This does not necessarily have to be so, and panels B and C illustrate cases in which it is not (and show the unique long tail candidate PCI equilibrium in each case as well). Essentially, cases like that in Panel A involve a su cient degree of horizontal di erentiation. 11 For simplicity, we will maintain this assumption throughout the rest of the paper, and leave the analysis of cases like those in Panels B and C to the Appendix, though as the Appendix shows, very little depends upon this assumption. Lemma 1 (Comparative Statics within a Long Tail Equilibrium). In any long tail equilibrium, (a) an increase in horizontal di erentiation between the two products raises the prices and pro ts of both producers, and (b) a uniform increase in variable costs raises the prices and pro ts of both producers. However, (c) an increase in xed costs has no e ect on prices, but reduces both producers pro ts. To prove this lemma, note that equations (3) and (4) form a system of two equations that imply prices in a long tail equilibrium given by Ph L = (1 + )(V p W p ) (V f W f ) + V [(1 + 2) C(N) C(N 1 + p ) C(N f )] 11 Equations (3) and (4) cross within the corridor formed by equations (1) and (2) when 2 1+ (V f W f ) (V p W p) V [C(N) 1+ C(N 1 f )] V [C(N) 1+ C(Np)] 1 1+ (Vp Wp) (V f W f ). Note that the term on the far left is decreasing, and the term on the far right is increasing, in the degree of horizontal di erentiation. 7

9 and P L n = (V p W p ) (1 + )(V f W f ) + V [(2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) C(N 1 + f )] : The hit producer s pro t can then be written as L h = Ph L N p V C(N p ) F F (1 + )(Vp W p ) (V f W f ) + V [(1 + 2) C(N) = (1 + ) C(N p ) C(N f )] N F F; and the niche producer s pro t is L n = P L n N f V C(N f ) F F = (V p W p ) (1 + )(V f W f ) + V [(2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) (1 + ) C(N f )] N F F: Lemma 1 follows from the expressions derived above. 12 It may seem surprising that rm pro ts are increasing in variable cost. What drives this result is the fact that, due to the assumed convexity of the cost function, price competition among producers is softened when variable costs are high because it becomes increasingly costly for each supplier to expand output to the other supplier s customers. 13 This implies that an improvement in technology that reduces total costs has ambiguous e ects on producer pro tability depending on how the cost structure is changed. For instance, a relative decline in variable costs makes xed costs more salient, reducing diseconomies of scale in production and creating greater competition to increase output and lower prices, and consequently lower pro ts. A relative decline in xed costs does the opposite, tending towards higher pro ts. Nothing in this subsection has shown that a long tail equilibrium must exist; we have only analyzed the uniqueness and properties of a long tail equilibrium if one exists. In the subsection D, we provide existence conditions, but rst, we consider a di erent equilibrium type altogether. II.C. Equilibrium Type 2: Superstars Now consider an equilibrium in which the hit producer sells to all consumers and the niche producer does not enter what we will refer to as a superstar equilibrium. 14 Though stylized, this equilibrium displays 12 In particular, part (b) is proved using the fact that C() is convex: since C(N) > C(N p) and C(N) > C(N f ), an increase in V raises Ph L, P n L, L h, and L n; similarly, an increase in F reduces L h and L n, but as no e ect on Ph L and P n L. 13 See Shaked and Sutton (1982) and Economides (1984) for instances of price competition softening through product di erentiation. 14 It is also possible for the niche producer to monopolize the market, and one could more generally endogenize the identity 8

10 the essential phenomena of Rosen (1981), in which market share and pro ts are concentrated among a small number of suppliers. In order for the hit to exclude the niche from entering the market, it must set P h such that the niche producer cannot pro tably sell to either type of consumer alone, nor to both. In order to sell to fringe-taste consumers, equation (2) implies that P n must be no higher than P h (V f W f ); in which case the niche producer would make pro t no greater than [P h (V f W f )]N f V C(N f ) F F: Thus, in a superstar equilibrium, this expression must be non-positive, i.e., the hit producer must set its price such that P h (V f W f ) + V C(Nf ) F F N : Similarly, to prevent the niche producer from pro tably selling to popular-taste consumers (and hence fringetaste consumers as well), the hit product cannot be sold at a price higher than P h (V p W p ) + V C(N) + F F N : If a superstar equilibrium exists, then the equilibrium price for the hit, Ph S, is the minimum of the above two values. 15 The pro t for the hit supplier in such an equilibrium is, therefore, 8 >< S h = >: (Vf W f ) V [ C(N) C(Nf )] N + F F (V p W p )N if (V f W f ) + V C(Nf ) + 1+ F F N (V p otherwise. W p ) + V C(N) + F F N Lemma 2 (Comparative Statics within a Superstar Equilibrium). In a superstar equilibrium, (a) an increase in the hit s vertical di erentiation over the niche raises its price and pro t, and (b) a uniform increase in either variable or xed costs raises the hit s price, but (c) pro ts are weakly decreasing in variable costs and weakly increasing in xed costs. Intuitively, pro ts are increasing in xed costs because xed costs reduce the entry threat from the marginal supplier, the niche (similarly, see Baumol, et al. 1982). Thus, just as in a long tail equilibrium, the e ect on pro ts from a decline in total costs depends on the relative decline in variable costs in comparison of the producer who becomes the superstar. Given our assumptions on the demand structure, however, it will always be the hit producer who monopolizes the market in any superstar equilibrium. 15 Thus, the niche s price in a superstar equilibrium is Ph S (V f W f ) = V C(Nf ) + 1+ F F, although at this price the N niche does not sell to any customers (recall our de nition of entry involved setting a price such that some customers buy the product). It can be checked that these prices do indeed form a PCI equilibrium: since the hit monopolizes the market at price Ph S, it has no incentive to lower prices below this level, and cannot increase pro ts while maintaining its superstar status above this price. Similarly, by construction, the niche would receive non-positive pro ts by lowering its price to attract either group of customers, so its maximum pro t level is zero, which it attains in the equilibrium. 9

11 with xed costs. However, the e ect is reversed from the long tail equilibrium: if variable costs decline relative to xed costs, the superstar producer becomes more pro table, not less. As an example, suppose V f W f and V p W p are positive, and for simplicity, let V = 0. This example is similar to Rosen s (1981) environment, in which vertical di erentiation is crucial. Then it can be seen from the above expression that even small di erences in supplier quality become magni ed into large di erences in pro ts, with the magni cation factor being the market size, N. Thus, Rosen s superstar income distribution also follows from our model. II.D. The Rise and Fall of Superstars In the previous two subsections, we have analyzed properties of each equilibrium type, but have not established the existence of either. In this section, we consider existence issues and illustrate how changes in technology, as well as demand characteristics, can lead to transitions between equilibrium types. In particular, we assume that new technology, de ned by changes in the parameters ( V ; F ), is exogenous. An alternative interpretation of this assumption is to view the e ects we observe here as long-run comparative statics, assuming that over a su ciently long time frame, lowest total cost technologies are always adopted; however, in Section V, we will explicitly study producers incentives to innovate (or adopt) new technology, and show that the results derived here remain valid. The main result of this section is summarized as follows: Proposition 1 (Determinants of Superstar and Long Tail E ects). Exogenous technological improvements that reduce variable costs relative to xed costs support superstar e ects, while those that reduce xed costs relative to variable costs support long tail e ects. Moreover, the tendency to shift towards a long tail equilibrium is greater when (a) the product is relatively horizontally di erentiated, (b) the size of the fringe customer group is relatively small, and (c) the initial xed costs are relatively large and the initial degree of diseconomies in production is relatively small. We will rst establish the existence and uniqueness of equilibria. Suppose that the niche producer chooses a price of Pn L ; as de ned by the long tail equilibrium in subsection B. If the hit producer then chooses the long tail equilibrium price Ph L ; equation (3) (which binds in a long tail equilibrium) implies that its pro t would be L h = [Pn L + (V f W f ) V C(N)]N F F: Alternatively, the hit producer could choose a price just low enough to exclude the niche producer and 10

12 move into a superstar equilibrium, receiving pro t S h = [P S h V C(N)]N F F [(V f W f ) + V C(Nf ) F F V C(N)]N N = [(V f W f ) + V C(Nf ) V C(N)]N F F + : F F Comparing these two expressions, it is straightforward to show that a necessary and su cient condition for the hit to have higher pro t under the long tail price response than the superstar price response is actually L n 0: In other words, when the niche producer makes pro ts in a long tail equilibrium, the hit prefers to price so as not to exclude the niche, and the long tail equilibrium exists (and is unique, as shown in subsection B). On the other hand, when the niche producer can make only negative pro ts under long tail pricing, the unique equilibrium is for the hit to become a superstar. Thus, the critical condition determining which type of equilibrium exists for any particular technology is the pro tability of the niche producer under long tail pricing. This analysis shows that movements between long tail and superstar equilibria can happen due to technological improvements that a ect the niche s pro tability. Recall that the niche producer s pro t in a long tail equilibrium, for a given technology, is L n = N (Vp W p ) (1 + )(V f W f ) + V [(2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) (1 + ) C(N f )] F F; This expression can be rearranged in the following linear form: V = m n F + b n where m n = ( )F [(2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) (1 + ) C(N f )]N and b n = (1 + )(V f W f ) (V p W p ) (2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) (1 + ) C(N f ) + ( ) L n [(2 + ) C(N) C(Np ) (1 + ) C(N f )]N : This expression de nes linear iso-pro t curves for the niche in V - F space, where the V -intercept is increasing in the niche s pro t level. In particular, by the analysis above, the iso-pro t curve de ned by L n = 0 divides the space between technologies that generate long tail and superstar equilibria, as in Figure 2. Above this zero-pro t line, the niche producer makes positive pro t in a long tail equilibrium, so any 11

13 technology in this region yields a long tail equilibrium. Below the zero-pro t line, the niche producer makes negative pro t if it enters, so any technology in this region yields a superstar equilibrium. The crucial aspect of the niche s zero-pro t line is that it is positively sloped. This is because the niche producer s pro t is increasing in variable costs and decreasing in xed costs, as shown in subsection B. Thus, suppose initially that the available technology generated cost structure a in Figure 2. This lies above the zero-pro t line, so the industry would initially be in a long tail equilibrium. Now consider a change in technology that lowers total costs, but reduces variable costs relative to xed costs, moving the cost structure from point a to point b. Under the new technology, the niche producer can no longer make pro t in any long tail equilibrium; thus, the industry evolves to a superstar equilibrium. Now suppose that total costs further decline through technological innovation to point c. In this case, xed costs have fallen relative to variable costs, and the industry moves back to a long tail equilibrium. Such dynamics can operate repeatedly as technology progresses, so that the industry moves back and forth between long tail and superstar e ects, even as total costs are declining throughout. What is relevant for the market structure is how each new technological innovation changes the mixture of variable and xed costs. Generally speaking, the niche producer s pro t can switch from negative to positive when technological improvement reduces xed costs relative to variable costs, and can switch from positive to negative when technological improvement reduces variable costs relative to xed costs. 16 This completes the rst half of the proof. To show the remaining equilibrium determinants mentioned in Proposition 1, note that from the demand side, the intercept, b n, shifts down when (V p V f ) or (W f W p ) increases. Therefore, an industry with more horizontal di erentiation will have a lower zero-pro t line, and hence a long tail equilibrium is more likely to prevail. Moreover, it is straightforward to show that the slope m n approaches in nity when becomes arbitrarily small. Hence, a larger market size for the fringe-taste consumers increases the incentives for the marginal rm to enter in order to serve that market. Finally, note that the slope of any iso-pro t curve, m n, is increasing in F and decreasing in the convexity of variable costs ( C(N) relative to C(N p ) and C(N f )). Hence, technological improvement is more likely to create superstars when initial xed costs are low or the initial degree of diseconomies is signi cant Throughout this discussion, we have considered uniform changes in variable costs. It is straightforward to generalize the analysis to allow for non-uniform changes. More generally, we can parametrize the variable cost function at di erent output level by 1 C(N), 2 C(N p), and 3 C(N f ). Then, the niche s long tail pro t is L n = (V p W p) (1 + )(V f W f ) + (2 + ) 1 C(N) 2 C(Np) (1 + ) 3 C(Nf )] N F F: Technological progress can reduce 1 ; 2 ; and 3 di erently. When the decline in 1 is small relative to the decrease in 2, 3 ; and F ; L n is likely to increase Therefore, a small (large) reduction in 1 relative to 2 ; 3 and F ; and hence an increase (decrease) in cost elasticity of output, tends to generate a long tail (superstar) e ect. 17 These two supply-side e ects are also consistent with Rosen s predictions. 12

14 II.E. Robustness Checks The model we have used to derive our central ndings is admittedly very simple, with only two competitors and two consumer types, and it employs a relatively non-standard solution concept. These features have allowed us to isolate the impacts of changes in the cost structure on the entry or exit of niche producers when both vertical and horizontal di erentiation are important, and will allow a clearer focus on the e ciency and endogenous technology innovation questions we address later. However, one may be concerned that these aspects of the model make our ndings ungeneralizable. To address this concern, consider the rst part of Proposition 1, which states that relative declines in xed costs lead to entry while relative declines in variable costs lead to exclusion. First, it is straightforward to see how changes in the cost structure are associated with entry or exit in a homogenous-good, free-entry Cournot model. 18 Therefore, our result is likely to hold even when consumers have elastic demands, because the key variable is the relative importance of xed versus variable costs rather than the level of total cost. As an alternative to Cournot, consider the e ect of changes in xed search costs in a hedonic competitive framework (Rosen, 1981). In the hedonic model, goods are vertically di erentiated, and the price of quality for a good with quality z can be written as p(z)+s z ; where p(z) is the market price of the good and s is a xed cost which does not depend on z. While Rosen pointed out that xed time and e ort costs in consumption are important components of s; and that these have increased with consumer earnings over time; we argue that xed time and e ort costs in acquiring information can be equally important and that the internet often reduce these costs signi cantly. Because consumers substitute imperfectly between quality and quantity, a decline in s in this model leads to a atter distribution of sales across producers of di erent qualities essentially, a long tail e ect. 19 Intuitively, a decline in indirect cost s leads consumers to switch towards lower quality products because they have less incentive to economize on the now lower xed costs. 20 Therefore, it is also true in a hedonic model that declines in xed information costs lead to long tails. Finally, we consider two models of horizontal product di erentiation, which explicitly model either consumer search or producer advertising. Anderson and Renault (1999) nd that product diversity rises with 18 Q For simplicity, assume linear demand (i.e., P = a Q) and quadratic variable costs (i.e., C(Q i ) = F + 2 i V ). When 2 the number of producers is xed at n; Cournot competition on quantities implies a unique Nash equilibrium in which each a producer sets Q i =. Under free entry, the number of producers is determined by the zero pro t condition. It is then 1+n+ V straightforward to show that n = 4 F 4 V F + 2a p (4 F + 2 V F ) 4 F which is decreasing in the xed cost F ; but increasing in the variable costs V provided the demand is su ciently high (in particular, a 2 > 8 F (2 + V )): In other words, a reduction in xed costs induces entry and hence reduces market concentration, whereas a reduction in variable costs discourages entry, leading to higher market concentration. 19 Empirically, Crain and Tollison (2002) nd evidence for this theory. They show that artist concentration in the music industry is positively correlated with earnings (and hence value of time). 20 This is similar to the famous Alchian-Allen theorem, although a decrease in s sh ts the supply of, but not the demand for, the good. 13

15 search costs, because market prices and hence pro tability are higher when it is more costly for consumers to search. Higher search costs therefore encourages product entry. This result seems to refute Anderson s (2006) thesis that one of the forces of the long tail is to connect supply and demand through lower search costs. However, it is important to note that the search costs in Anderson and Renault (1999) are best interpreted as variable costs, because each consumer has to incur that in order to learn the price as well as her match value for the product. In another paper, Grossman and Shapiro (1984) show that decreased advertising costs may reduce pro ts by increasing the severity of price competition. In a long run equilibrium, this implies exit for some products, and hence, a reduction in product diversity in the market. Grossman and Shapiro refer to this as an example of a potential cost-based facilitating practice, because it may be in the incumbent producers interests to raise advertising costs. Similarly, note the fact that the advertising cost in their model is essentially a variable cost in the sense that it costs more to expose the message to a larger fraction of the target population. Therefore, their result is also consistent with our implication that a reduction in variable costs can reduce pro ts and produce a superstar e ect through the exit of niche producers. Moreover, it can be shown that, if their model is revised to make the advertising cost xed instead of variable, decreased advertising costs create a long tail e ect in the sense that product diversity increases. 21 III. Unifying the Long Tail Literature According to Anderson (2006), the long tail e ect unleashed by the internet is composed of three forces: (1) a democratization of the tools of production (i.e., user-created content like homemade videos or blogs), (2) reductions in the costs of consumption due to this democratization (e.g., reading blogs is cheaper than reading a newspaper), and (3) closer connections between supply and demand from lower search costs. Previous literature, which we discuss below, has focused on (3) whether internet-related declines in the cost of information have created greater diversity in product o erings. In this section, we show that the literature s divergent views on this question can be reconciled by specifying how the structure of these costs has changed with the internet, and how horizontally or vertically di erentiated consumer preferences are in a given market. In our model, producers incur costs of production. In reality, because knowledge about potential demanders and suppliers, and characteristics of the goods are not perfect, various market institutions arise to facilitate and economize on the spread and acquisition of market information (Alchian, 1969). These institutions lead some information costs to be borne by consumers as explicit search costs, while others 21 In addition, our model may be usefully compared with those of Shaked and Sutton (1987) and Sutton (1991), who study the relationship between market concentration and cost structure in a class of models of vertical product di erentiation. They show that when sunk cost (a xed cost in their models) is endogenous, the market will remain concentrated regardless of market size. This result does not, however, hold when products are purely horizontally di erentiated. In our model, the long tail (superstar) e ect reduces (increases) market concentration. Although our focus is not on the e ects of changes in market size, we show that the long tail (superstar) e ect is more important for products which are horizontally (vertically) di erentiated when xed (variable) costs decline relative to variable ( xed) costs. 14

16 are internalized by rms (Robert and Stahl, 1993). 22 Because both types of information costs serve the same purpose (Janssena and Non, 2008), as well as because the internet may reduce costs in other aspects of production (such as Anderson s points (1) and (2) above), we lump all information costs together and assume their accounting incidence falls primarily on producers, either as xed or variable costs. 23 In particular, the classical reduced-form cost function speci cation in our model makes our results general and robust to the details of the production process, but more importantly, easy to apply in practice. In other words, our approach is not inconsistent with imperfect information. To the extent that private information can be made available at some reasonable cost (which is, in fact, paid in equilibrium), this cost may be treated as part of the production cost. 24 From a qualitative point of view, therefore, this version of imperfect information is a special case of our model. Quantitatively, the question is whether these costs of information are xed or variable. Recall that our model may be summarized as follows: declines in xed costs, especially in industries characterized by high degrees of horizontal di erentiation, are associated with long tail e ects, while declines in variable costs, especially in industries characterized by high degrees of vertical di erentiation, are associated with superstar e ects. Our model therefore provides a uni ed theoretical framework to consider the e ects of the internet on industrial structure, e ciency, and innovation incentives by identifying conditions under which a reduction in the cost of information through internet technology will lead to a long tail or a superstar e ect. We show that two factors generate the apparently contradictory ndings in previous literature: ambiguity about whether the cost reductions from new technologies are xed or variable, and incomplete accounting of the relative degree of vertical and horizontal di erentiation present in various industries. In particular, a close reading of the model in Brynolfsson, et al. (2007) reveals that search costs are xed therein. Thus, our ndings agree with theirs, which show that an internet-induced fall in search costs leads to a long tail e ect. Similarly, a close reading of Emre, et al. (2007) reveals that, in their model, search costs operate as a form of horizontal di erentiation. Thus, our ndings generalize the notion that a decline in search costs may also be associated with a superstar e ect. The empirical ndings of these papers and others in the long tail literature can also be reconciled with our model by noting that the structure of information costs depends on the nature of demand and the durability of information. Acquisition of information regarding the quality of a particular brand, for instance, is essentially a xed cost because customers only need to learn the information once, and can then buy many units of products with that 22 For instance, rms spend substantial resources on advertisements, window displays, sales clerks, specialist agents, brokers, in-store inventories, catalogues, correspondence, phone calls, market research, and so on, to provide useful product information to consumers. 23 While the accounting incidence is assumed to fall on producers, the economic incidence of these cost will, in general, be shared among producers and consumers in equilibrium. 24 The cost of making private information public is known as costly state veri cation (Townsend, 1979). 15

17 brand without having to learn much more about the brand s quality. On the other hand, acquisition of information about relative and absolute price levels is often a variable cost, especially if a product s price uctuates rapidly over time. These examples show that a new technology like e-commerce may reduce variable costs relatively to xed costs or vice-versa. Empirical examples from Brynjolfsson et al. (2007) (women s clothing) and Emre et. al. (2007) (travel agencies) can illustrate this point. Tastes in fashion tend to be idiosyncratic, and once a customer learns about a favorable brand or designer, she may become a repeat customer in the next season. Therefore, marketing costs in the case of women s clothing likely include an important xed component, which e-commerce can plausibly reduce. Knowledge about air travel prices, however, has a very high depreciation rate because of price discrimination, peak-load pricing, and frequent changes in prices and ight schedules. It is not di cult to imagine that online travel sites like Expedia.com and Travelocity.com have reduced the variable costs of airline ticket information in important ways. 25 Thus, our model shows that it is unsurprising that the internet has generated long tail e ects in women s clothing, but superstar e ects in travel agent services. Even within a single market, di erences in consumer preferences can create di erent e ects from the internet. In lm, Elberse and Oberholzer-Gee (2006) nd that the long tail e ect is more important in the Foreign and Adult movie genres, whereas the superstar e ect is more prominent for Children/Family titles. This is unsurprising if horizontal di erentiation is more important among the former groups than the latter, as seems plausible. Similarly, Crain and Tollison (2002) show that in the music industry, more diversity in consumer preferences is associated with a long tail e ect. Our model also provides a quali cation of Rosen s (1981) predictions regarding the e ects of information and communication technology, which supplies the quote that headlines this paper. Radio, television, and recording media technology improvements over the rst half of the 20th century emphasized relative declines in variable costs in comparison to xed costs. For instance, the invention of television lowered substantially per-consumer variable costs in the production of comedic and dramatic performances, relative to pre-existing stage and auditorium technology. However, the xed costs of performance did not decline much, and may have increased, since television studios, microphones, and broadcasting equipment represent substantial capital outlays. Thus, Rosen s model and ours predict that such technological innovation tends to create superstars. IV. Market E ciency: Competition Policy and Social Implications As in other models of entry under strategic competition, the number of rms in equilibrium may be ine cient (Mankiw and Whinston, 1986). Our model supplies conditions under which product entry is 25 Moreover, online travel sites may involve higher capital investment upfront than local bricks-and-mortar travel agencies, but at the same time can serve the entire national market; thus, the overall cost structure of the industry may have changed. 16

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1

Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1 Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1 Yongmin Chen 2 University of Colorado Boulder and Zhejiang University Xinyu Hua 3 Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Abstract. A rm s incentive

More information

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Essi Eerola RUESG, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland Niku Määttänen Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain and The Research Institute

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Bundling and Foreclosure Tina Kao Australian National University Flavio Menezes University of Queensland September 29, 2006

More information

EconS Bertrand Competition

EconS Bertrand Competition EconS 425 - Bertrand Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction Today, we

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Discussion paper No. 113 Cannibalization may Allow a Cost-inefficient Firm to Earn more than a Cost-effcient Firm in a Duopoly with Two Vertically Differentiated Goods Ryoma Kitamura

More information

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association

More information

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Pricing Under Homogeneous Oligopoly We will assume that the

More information

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Universidade de veiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Área Científica de Economia E/nº 41/007 Entry Decision and

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors. Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors. Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin 0 TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors 0 RSMG Working Paper Series Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin Schools of Economics and Political Science The University of Queensland

More information

A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically differentiated market

A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically differentiated market A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically differentiated market Ornella Tarola Cecilia Vergari Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 832 A note on acquisition of complements in a vertically di erentiated

More information

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game Hassan Benchekroun a Amrita Ray Chaudhuri b January 2009 a Department of Economics, McGill University, 855 Sherbrooke Ouest, Montreal, QC, Canada,

More information

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 812 The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies.

More information

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory Econ 500 - Microeconomic Analysis and Policy Monopoly Monopoly A monopoly is a single firm that serves an entire market and faces the market demand curve for its output. Unlike

More information

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models Munich Discussion Paper No. 2010-25 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 School of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 1. Strategic Interaction and Oligopoly

More information

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (Ph.D.) Introduction In this class, we will see two papers that will be used as building blocks of most of this

More information

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Ricardo Cavalcanti Getulio Vargas Foundation Ed Nosal Cleveland Fed November 006 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We describe counterfeiting activity

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Entry and Merger Policy

Entry and Merger Policy 7 85 October 07 Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux, Yassine Lefouili and Wilfried Sand Zantman Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux y Yassine Lefouili z Wilfried Sand-Zantman x August 07 Abstract This

More information

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 30, 2005 Answer four of the six

More information

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm.

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm. Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm. Ricardo Alonso Univeristy of Southern California Wouter Dessein University of Chicago and Toulouse School

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis Department of Economics Queen s University ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis Assignment #4 Answer Key Monday December 6, 2010 Section A (40 percent): Brie y discuss the validity

More information

Search and Categorization

Search and Categorization MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Search and Categorization Chaim Fershtman and Arthur Fishman and Jidong Zhou Tel Aviv University, Bar-Ilan University, NYU Stern December 03 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5366/

More information

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy Arastou KHATIBI and Wouter VERGOTE y August 009 Abstract When selling their products domestically or internationally rms rely on more than just the price as a strategic

More information

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley 1 Overview of the Course This is a readings course. The lectures

More information

SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY. Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita

SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY. Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita WP-AD 008-01 Corresponding author: N. Georgantzís: LEE/LINEEX and Economics Dept., Universitat

More information

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - First-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41 Introduction

More information

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment

Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Exclusive Dealing and Entry, when Buyers Compete: Comment Julian Wright Abstract In a recent paper, Chiara Fumagalli and Massimo Motta (2006) challenge the idea that an incumbent can foreclose efficient

More information

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - Second-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 46 Introduction

More information

Department of Economics Working Paper

Department of Economics Working Paper Department of Economics Working Paper Number 11-14 September 2011 Substitution and Superstars Timothy Perri Appalachian State University Department of Economics Appalachian State University Boone, NC 28608

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market Richard J. Gilbert University of California Michael H. Riordan Columbia University CPDP-17-E October 2005 This article is written

More information

URL:

URL: Behaviour-Based Price Discrimination under Advertising and Imperfectly Informed Consumers Rosa-Branca Esteves Sofia Cerqueira 08/ 014 Behaviour-Based Price Discrimination under Advertising and Imperfectly

More information

Two Lectures on Information Design

Two Lectures on Information Design Two Lectures on nformation Design 10th DSE Winter School Stephen Morris December 2015 nformation Design Usually in information economics, we ask what can happen for a xed information structure... nformation

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors gratefully acknowledge

More information

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Yongmin Chen Department of Economics University of Colorado Boulder, CO 80309 September 2006 Abstract. This paper considers variants of a dynamic duopoly

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text. 1 Monopoly A monopolist is de ned as a single seller of a well-de ned product for which there are no close substitutes. In reality, there are

More information

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers EC 36 - Lecture 11&1 Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers What are vertical restraints? In most markets producers do not sell directly to consumers but to retailers who then sell to consumers. Some

More information

UC Berkeley Recent Work

UC Berkeley Recent Work UC Berkeley Recent Work Title Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/3v04b2rx Authors Gilbert, Richard J Riordan, Michael H Publication

More information

Consumer Search with Price Sorting

Consumer Search with Price Sorting Consumer Search with Price Sorting Jun Yu September 29, 2013 Abstract This paper introduces price sorting into a consumer search model. Either ascending or descending price sorting can be applied before

More information

Industrial Organization 04

Industrial Organization 04 Industrial Organization 04 Product differentiation Marc Bourreau Telecom ParisTech Marc Bourreau (TPT) Lecture 04: Product differentiation 1 / 43 Outline 1 Introduction: forms of product differentiation

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors acknowledge nancial support

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth David Gill Division of Economics University of Southampton John Thanassoulis Dept. of Economics & Christ Church

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Área Científica de Economia E/nº 4/007 Discriminatory Limit

More information

P rofit t (1 + i) t. V alue = t=0

P rofit t (1 + i) t. V alue = t=0 These notes correspond to Chapter 2 of the text. 1 Optimization A key concept in economics is that of optimization. It s a tool that can be used for many applications, but for now we will use it for pro

More information

Home Market E ects with Endogenous Costs of Production

Home Market E ects with Endogenous Costs of Production Home Market E ects with Endogenous Costs of Production Armando J. Garcia Pires Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration June 14, 2011 Abstract Home Market E ects (HMEs) are a central mechanism

More information

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text. 1 Applying the Competitive Model The focus of this chapter is welfare economics. Note that "welfare" has a much di erent meaning in economics

More information

Superstars and the Long Tail: The impact of technology on market structure in media industries

Superstars and the Long Tail: The impact of technology on market structure in media industries Superstars and the Long Tail: The impact of technology on market structure in media industries Helen Weeds University of Essex 25 January 2012 Abstract Technological change has transformed creative media

More information

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

Competition in Two-Sided Markets Competition in Two-Sided Markets Mark Armstrong Department of Economics University College London August 2002: revised May 2005 Abstract There are many examples of markets involving two groups of agents

More information

Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage"

Web Appendix to Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage" Meredith L. Fowlie Abstract This appendix provides additional details and results to support the main

More information

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers Thomas D. Jeitschko and Mark J. Tremblay Prepared for IIOC 2014: Not Intended for Circulation March 27, 2014 Abstract In this paper we investigate

More information

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. Understanding UPP Roy J. Epstein and Daniel L. Rubinfeld Published Version, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Policies and Perspectives, Volume 10, Issue 1, 2010 Introduction The standard economic

More information

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly Takanori Adachi School of Economics Nagoya University Noriaki Matsushima ISER Osaka University November 17, 2010 2 1.

More information

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup Theory Appendix In this appendix, we provide a stylized model based on our empirical setting to analyze the effect of competition on author behavior. The general idea is that in a market with imperfect

More information

ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER

ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER E-Series No.E14-1 Log-Linear Demand Systems with Differentiated Products Are Inconsistent with the Representative Consumer Approach by Takanori Adachi Takeshi

More information

Solutions to Final Exam

Solutions to Final Exam Solutions to Final Exam AEC 504 - Summer 2007 Fundamentals of Economics c 2007 Alexander Barinov 1 Veni, vidi, vici (30 points) Two firms with constant marginal costs serve two markets for two different

More information

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS*

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 0022-1821 Volume XLVIII December 2000 No. 4 INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* Joseph Farrell{ and Michael L. Katz{ We consider innovation

More information

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange fee Hans Zenger a; a European Commission, DG Competition, Chief Economist Team, 1049 Brussels, Belgium February 14, 2011 Abstract Two widely discussed

More information

Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers

Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers David Gill University of Oxford John Thanassoulis University of Oxford April 2007 Abstract In this paper we study

More information

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets S O L U T I O N S 26 Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets Solutions for Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach with Calculus (International Ed.) Apart from end-of-chapter exercises provided

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22 Monopoly. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen November, Lecture Monopoly Outline. Chap : Monopoly. Chap : Shift in Demand and Effect of Tax Monopoly The monopolist is the single supply-side

More information

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013 The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution Ofer Cornfeld Tel-Aviv University (TAU) June 2013 The empirical attributes of the earnings distribution, Neal and Rosen (2000): "Earnings distributions...

More information

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1 EconS 305 - Competitive Markets Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu October 11, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 19 October 11, 2015 1 / 48 Introduction Today,

More information

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION THE JOURNAL O INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 00-181 Volume LVII June 009 No. Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/ PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION LEVENT KUTLU

More information

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Hend Ghazzai Assistant Professor College of Business and Economics Qatar University P.O. Box 2713 Doha, Qatar. Abstract Consumers' choice

More information

E ciency Wages. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

E ciency Wages. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 E ciency Wages Lecture notes Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 1 Introduction Question: Why is there unemployment? Question: How come wages do not fall? ² Union power? (Next lecture) ²

More information

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ 009/55 Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ CORE DISCUSSION PAPER 009/9 Clean technology adoption and its influence on tradeable

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

Reciprocal dumping with Bertrand competition

Reciprocal dumping with Bertrand competition Reciprocal dumping with Bertrand competition Richard Friberg y, Stockholm School of Economics and CEPR Mattias Ganslandt z, The Research Institute of Industrial Economics SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in

More information

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

EconS Monopoly - Part 1 EconS 305 - Monopoly - Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu October 23, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 23 October 23, 2015 1 / 50 Introduction For the rest

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2 Questions of this SAMPLE exam were randomly chosen and may NOT be representative of the difficulty or focus of the actual examination. The professor did NOT review these questions. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose

More information

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition Besanko, Dranove, Shanley, and Schaefer Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition Slides by: Richard Ponarul, California State University, Chico Copyright 2010 John Wiley

More information

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly EconS 425 - Perfect Competition and Monopoly Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing

Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing James D. Reitzes y Glenn A. Woroch z October 2006 Abstract This paper compares one-part pricing

More information

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Market Structure ECON6021 Oligopoly Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island Oligopoly a few major players The top 4 cereal manufacturers sell 90% of all

More information

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly Minas Vlassis * Maria Varvataki Department of Economics, University of Crete, Gallos University Campus, Rethymnon 74100, Greece

More information

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure Employer Discrimination and Market Structure Josh Ederington Jenny Minier Jeremy Sandford Kenneth R. Troske August 29 Abstract We extend Gary Becker s theory, that competitive forces will drive discriminating

More information

Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition

Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition Prof. Jepsen ECO 610 Lecture 4 December 6, 2012 John Wiley and Sons Competition If one firm s strategic choice adversely affects the performance of another, they are

More information

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities

Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Durable Goods, Innovation and Network Externalities Daniel CERQUERA March 15, 2005 Abstract We present a model of R&D competition between an incumbent and a potential entrant with network externalities

More information

Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1

Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1 Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1 Philippe De Donder Toulouse School of Economics (IDEI and GREMAQ-CNRS) John E. Roemer Yale University First version: September 2006 This

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET Chapter 6 We recall that perfect competition was theorised as a market structure where both consumers and firms were price takers. The behaviour of the firm in such circumstances was described in the Chapter

More information

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture nformation Design: Murat Sertel Lecture stanbul Bilgi University: Conference on Economic Design Stephen Morris July 2015 Mechanism Design and nformation Design Mechanism Design: Fix an economic environment

More information

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes. These notes provided by Laura Lamb are intended to complement class lectures. The notes are based on chapter 12 of Microeconomics and Behaviour 2 nd Canadian Edition by Frank and Parker (2004). Chapter

More information

EconS Endogenous Market Size

EconS Endogenous Market Size EconS 425 - Endogenous Market Size Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 35 Introduction Let s contrinue

More information

EconS Bundling and Tying

EconS Bundling and Tying EconS 425 - Bundling and Tying Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 39 Introduction Let s talk

More information

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Principles of Economics. January 2018 Principles of Economics January 2018 Monopoly Contents Market structures 14 Monopoly 15 Monopolistic competition 16 Oligopoly Principles of Economics January 2018 2 / 39 Monopoly Market power In a competitive

More information

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Problem 1. Shorter problems. (35 points) Solve the following shorter problems. 1. Consider the following (simultaneous) game of chicken. This is a game in

More information

Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition

Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition Nicolas Boccard & Xavier Wauthy April 2003 Abstract A regulator imposing sales restrictions on firms competing in oligopolistic markets

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS. Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS IN DURABLE-GOODS MARKETS Dennis W. Carlton Michael Waldman Working Paper 11407 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11407 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Hitotsubashi University August 2009 Abstract We capture the differences between patent and copyright by considering the optimal

More information

Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques

Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques 1.1 Services, Booking Systems, and Consumer Value 2 1.1.1 Service definitions 1.1.2 Dynamic reservation systems 1.1.3 Consumer value 1.2 Overview of Pricing

More information

Product versus Process: Innovation Strategies of Multi-Product Firms

Product versus Process: Innovation Strategies of Multi-Product Firms Product versus Process: Innovation Strategies of Multi-Product Firms Lisandra Flach University of Munich y Michael Irlacher University of Munich z February 11, 2015 Abstract This paper studies innovation

More information