Rockets and Feathers. Understanding Asymmetric Pricing. (Job Market paper)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Rockets and Feathers. Understanding Asymmetric Pricing. (Job Market paper)"

Transcription

1 Rockets and Feathers. Understanding Asymmetric Pricing. (Job Market paper) Mariano Tappata UCLA October 005 [incomplete and preliminar] Abstract Prices rise like rockets but fall like feathers. This stylized fact of most markets has been con rmed by many empirical studies in the past. However, the advance on theoretical work trying to explain it has been rather low. I present a simple model of competitive rms and rational partially-informed consumers where the asymmetric response to costs by rms emerges naturally. In contrast to public opinion and past work, collusion is not needed for such result. JEL Codes: D, D40, L3. Keywords: Asymmetric Pricing, Rockets and Feathers, Consumer Search, Oligopoly.

2 Introduction Output prices do not react symmetrically to changes in input prices. This stylized fact has been getting the attention of both academics and the general public for a long time. As a result, an extensive empirical literature has developed to test for the existence of asymmetric pricing in speci c markets. Peltzman s comprehensive study of 65 producer goods and 77 consumer goods summarizes the results of this literature: "In two out of three markets, output prices rise faster than they fall" (Peltzman, 000; p. 480). This pattern is also known as rockets and feathers and has sometimes been used interchangeably with the term asymmetric pricing. But surprisingly, the research in the area has not developed symmetrically. Despite the abundance of empirical work available, there has not been much progress on theoretical models that support this common phenomenon. The rst thing that comes to mind when talking about the rockets and feathers pattern is gas prices and collusion. Input and output prices are easily observable by everyone and the market is composed by only a handful of players. When gas prices behave asymmetrically, the layperson (and the media) immediately associates it with collusion. This perception has in uenced the focus of economic research; most of the empirical work has concentrated around the retail markets for gasoline (Bacon, 99; Karrenbrock, 99; Borenstein, Cameron, and Gilbert, 997; Lewis, 003; Deltas, 004; and Verlinda, 005 among others). 3;4 However, Peltzman nds that the rockets and feathers pattern is equally likely to be found in both concentrated and atomistics markets. In this paper, I develop a consumer-search model that parses out the conditions under which asymmetric responses of prices to costs arise in non-collusive markets. According to traditional economic theory, homogeneous rms that compete in prices have zero pro ts and cost shocks are completely transferred to nal prices. 5 The nature of this equilibrium changes if consumers have imperfect information about market prices and a fraction of them has positive search costs. Firms now obtain positive pro ts (information rents) and the equilibrium is characterized by price dispersion -instead of a single price. Yet, for a given level of cost, the price margin is the same regardless of whether the cost shock was positive or negative. In order to account for asymmetric pricing, I introduce consumer uncertainty over production costs in a search model from Varian (980). Intuitively, when To the best of my knowledge, Bacon (99) was the rst one to use the term rockets and feathers to describe the pattern of retail gasoline prices in the U.K. See Karrenbrock (99, p. 0) for media and government representative quotations about gasoline price gouging. 3 The properties of the production process of retail gasoline -lack of input substitution and its main input representing 8% of the nal price net of taxes- make it also an attractive market for empirical tests. 4 Papers investigating asymmetric pricing in other markets include Neumark and Sharpe, 99 [Hannan and Berger, 99, [Pick et al, 99] in the banking sector and Ward, 98] Boyd and Brorsen., 988, Goodwin and Holt, 999 and Goodwin and Harper (000) in the food sector. 5 Firms with market power (product di erentiation or monopoly) don t transfer all the cost shocks to price, but still do it symmetrically.

3 input cost shocks are not independent over time, consumers expectations di er depending on whether costs were falling or rising in the previous periods. Asymmetric pricing then arises naturally as a consequence of changes in the perceived demand by rms; and the rockets and feathers pattern is supported under persistence in production cost realizations. Existing theories on asymmetric pricing are fully represented by the works of Borenstein et al. (997), Benabou and Gertner (993), and Lewis (003). The former tests the rockets and feathers pattern for the retailing gasoline market and suggests a model of collusion with imperfect monitoring to explain it (as in Tirole, 988; p. 64). With multiple equilibria, the focal point changes after a positive cost shock and it doesn t if the same shock is negative. The other two papers generate pricing asymmetries in duopoly markets without assuming collusive behavior. Benabou and Gertner analyze the e ect on e ciency of higher in ation uncertainty. In their model, each rm s production cost is composed of both an idiosyncratic (real) and a general (in ation) shock. Consumers update their beliefs about the general shock after observing the rst price and then decide whether to pay a cost to observe the price of the remaining rm. More in ation uncertainty can lead to lower or higher markups. Finally, Lewis develops a reference price search model with homogeneous rms and consumers that form expectations based on past-period prices. Therefore, consumers search strategy is optimal only with respect to the prior distribution of prices but not necessarily to the actual equilibrium prices adopted by the rms. 6 The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section I describe the model and the static duopoly equilibrium. Next, I analyze the dynamic setting and show the rockets and feathers result. In section IV, I extend the result for markets with more than two rms. In section V, I show that rockets and feathers is not supported by models where search is done sequentially. Section VI concludes. The model Consider a duopoly where rms sell homogenous goods. Both rms have the same marginal and average production cost, and compete through prices. Consumers (normalized to the unit measure) have unit demands with a choke price v and obtain information about market prices by searching. A portion (0; ) has zero or negative search cost and they are referred to as shoppers (Stahl, 996). Shoppers can be interpreted as consumers who enjoy searching for prices or who obtained price information unintentionally through advertising or while shopping for other goods. The remaining ( ) consumers have positive search costs s i S = [0; s], s > drawn from a continuous and di erentiable cdf g (s i ). Firms decide their prices simultaneously with consumer s search strategies. The production cost can be high or low c C = fc L ; c H g and is only observed by the rms. Consumers search nonsequentially. That is, each consumer decides -before observing any 6 The work by Eckert (00) and Noel (00) use a model of Edgeworth Cycles to explain asymmetric gasoline prices not related to cost shocks that was observed in some canadian cities. 3

4 price- between becoming informed about all the prices in the market (and buying from the store with the lowest price) or remaining uninformed, in which case they buy costlessly from a random store. If a consumer were to search sequentially, after visiting a store (observe its price) she would decide whether to sample for another price or shop at the lowest price observed at that moment. 7 I will postpone the analysis of sequential search protocol to section V. The early literature on consumer-search models focused on nonsequential search protocols (Salop and Stiglitz, 977; Braverman, 980; and Varian, 980) while more recently sequential search models dominated the scene (Stahl, 989 and 996; and Benabou and Gertner, 993). Both sequential and nonsequential search protocols can be optimal depending on the context of the decision problem (Morgan and Manning, 985). When price quotes are not obtained instantaneously (insurance quotes, repair estimates, etc.) and the opportunity cost of time is important, nonsequential search dominates sequential search protocols. Also, the advance of technology might make nonsequential search optimal. For example, consider online shopping. Consumers have the alternative to sample prices sequentially by visiting each store s websites, or conduct a one-time search in an independent website that compares prices across online stores. 8;9 Nonsequential search dominates sequential search not only because it saves time, but also because it makes the comparison easier by organizing the relevant information (quality, seller s reputation, shipping cost, taxes, etc.) from each seller. In cases where price quotes are obtained easily and there are no economies of scale in the size of the price sample, sequential search dominates nonsequential search protocols since it allows consumers to stop searching as soon as they nd a good bargain. Summarizing, rms and consumers play a simultaneous-move Bayesian game. There are N = N F [ N D players, where j N F = fi; IIg represents a rm and i N D = [0; ]. Producers can be of type c j = c C for all j N F and nature (player 0) moves with probability = P r (c = c H ) : Consumer types (search cost) s i S are common knowledge. Firms choose prices p j P = [c L ; ] and consumers choose actions a i A = f0; g = R fdon t search, searchg : 0 Letting = + ( ) a i di represent the number of informed consumers, the pro ts of a rm j that charges price p j and has production cost c are: + j (p j ; p j ; a; c) = (p j c) fp j < p j g + fp j = p j g + fp j > p j g () 7 This is the case of sequential search with perfect recall. In the case of no recall, if the consumer stops searching, she has to shop at the last price observed. 8 This is also true for the case of o ine shopping where prices are posted online by the stores. 9 Some popular portals that compare online prices are pricegrabber.com, pricescan.com, pricingcentral.com, kelkoo.com and bizrate.com. 0 I ignore the decision between buying or not for the consumer by setting as the upper bound for p j: This simpli es notation and does not a ect any result. 0 4

5 R where = + ( ) 0 a i di represents the number of informed consumers. The expected utility of a consumer i with search cost s i is given by: u i (a i ; a i ; p) = a i (Min [p] s i ) ( a i ) P p j () Firm j 0 s strategy pro les are represented by all possible price distributions for a given cost realization: f j (; c) = (f j (p j ; c)) pj P with f j (p j ; c) 0 for all p j P and R P f j (p; c) dp = : Consumers on the other hand have strategy pro les q i (; s i ) (A). The interaction between consumers and rms is summarized by the number of informed consumers : Any pro le D = fq i (; s i )g in D implies a value of [; ]: De ne a Nash best response N (; c) as a symmetric Nash Equilibrium strategy of the game = [N J ; P; jnj ] where j is de ned in (): A Symmetric Bayesian Nash Equilibrium (SBNE) or market equilibrium from now on is a strategy pro le = D ; F such that, i) D is a best response to F = (f (p; c; )) pp and ii) F is a NR D. Let s start analyzing the supply side of the model. Given the number of informed consumers, a rm with cost c that sets a price p can either fail or succeed in capturing the informed consumers. Its pro ts are: f (p; c) = ( ) j (p c) (3) s ( + ) (p; c) = (p c) (4) The assumption of an atom of shoppers ( > 0) rules out the monopoly price as a Single Price Equilibrium (SPE). Otherwise, a store would capture the informed consumers by undercutting slightly. On the other hand, = implies perfect information and p = c is the unique SPE. As it will be shown below, the assumption of s > is su cient for < in equilibrium: In what follows, consider to be less than. By charging the highest possible price a rm obtains half of the uninformed consumers. The expected pro t is ( ) (; c) = ( c) > 0 De ne p as the minimum price a rm is willing to charge, p = s ( ) ((; c)) = c + ( c) (5) ( + ) Even capturing all the informed consumers, at prices below p ; pro ts are lower than charging the monopoly price. For any potential SPE bp (p ; ]; the presence of shoppers This is consistent with the de nition of shoppers given above. If shoppers are thought of as consumers with zero search cost, I break the indi erence in () by assuming they always search. 5

6 allows for a positive gain to deviators if they set p = bp " (by de nition, bp = p cannot be a SPE). Thus, a rm NR consists of mixing strategies over [p ; ] : By the same argument, all mixing strategies that involve a positive mass over any price is ruled out. Denote the cumulative distribution implied by a particular F with F (; c; ). A rm is indi erent between charging any price that generates an expected pro t () : s (p)( F ()) + f (p)f () = () (6) High prices increase mark-ups per unit sold but decrease the expected market share by reducing the likelihood of being the lowest price in the market. This trade-o (surplusappropiation vs. business-stealing) faced by rms induces price dispersion. Proposition There is a unique Nash Response F. Given and c the cumulative distribution of market prices is pr ( )( p) F (p; c; ) = f (x; c; ) dx = (7) p (p c) for all p h ( ) c + (+) ( c); i As the number of informed consumers increases, the pricing distribution expands its support while it rst-order stochastically dominates distributions for lower values. Firms place more density on low prices than high prices since the size of the captive market decreases and the gains from being the lowest price in the market increase. In the limit (! ) ; expected pro ts and prices approach the competitive outcome. On the demand side, consumers decide between becoming informed about the market prices (and pay cost s i ) or buy from a random store. The demand in the market is composed by many consumers and their individual choices i cannot in uence the total number of informed consumers in the pool. The expected bene t of being informed -taking as given the rm Nash Response F is measured by the di erence between the expected price and the expected minimum price in the market. The expected gains from search for consumers are: Z v E [p p min j] = E c 4 p [ [ F (p; c; )]] df (; c; ) 5 = (8) p ( ) + = ( E [c]) log where the last equation is obtained using (7) and integrating by parts. 3 6

7 Figure : Nonsequential search equilibrium with uniformly distributed search costs Price dispersion in the market is drives consumer to search. As! 0 and! the gains from search disappear. Since there is an atom of shoppers, E [p p min j = ] > 0 and as increases, E [p] and E [p min ] decrease. They do it at di erent rates and eventually the maximum gains from searching are achieved at b. For > b, adding informed consumers reduces the gains from search since the rms are placing too much probability in low prices. The following lemma characterizes (8). Lemma The expected gain from search is a strictly concave function of the number of informed consumers. Furthermore, it has a maximum at = < b < : Shoppers always choose to know the actual prices while consumers with search cost higher than their valuation of the good will never search. 3 In equilibrium, rms face at ( g())( ) least informed and captive consumers. The rest of the consumers optimal search strategies are q i (s i < es) = and q i (s i > es) = 0 where es is the search cost of the indi erent consumer: E[p p min j = + ( ) g (es)]] es = 0 (9) Figure represents the unique market equilibrium when search costs are uniformly distributed. This result holds for any search cost distribution as long as the number of shoppers is bigger than b. In that case, g crosses E [] only once. When the number of shoppers is low, a su cient condition for a unique equilibrium is that the slope of g is steeper than the slope of E [] : Proposition There is a unique market equilibrium if: a) > b, or h i b) 0 < < b and g > E[p p min] over ; b : E [p] decreases at an increasing rate for any while E [p min] decreases at an increasing rate for < 0:7834 and then at a decreasing rate. 3 See footnote 9. 7

8 As long as the demand is composed by informed and uninformed consumers, a market equilibrium implies price dispersion. This is not the consequence of heterogeneous search costs. Consider the case of a degenerate g () with S = f0; sg ; 0 < s <. Intuitively, when search cost is su ciently high, nonshoppers don t search and = : This always happens if s > E [p p min j = b] : For very low search costs, gains from search are higher than its cost and everyone would search. But the negative externality generated by > b on the gains from search imply that = cannot be an equilibrium. Imagine =. Firms NR implies p = c and no price dispersion. But then q = is not optimal for nonshoppers. The number of shoppers relative to the search cost of the nonshoppers can be thought of as a measure of competition in the market. Expected prices decrease with. As mentioned before, when search cost is high, only shoppers search and determines the spread between expected prices and marginal cost. If s < E [p p min j = b] ; there is a such that gains from search are higher than its cost (E [p p min j = ] > s). The nal equilibrium could exhibit more informed consumers than shoppers ( > ) and lower mark-ups. In order to analyze the equilibrium properties better, let the number of shoppers be high or low; and the search costs level be high, moderate or low: De nition The number of shoppers are low (high) if is (>) than b. Given ; search costs are de ned to be low, moderate, or high if: s < E [p p min j = ] ; E [p p min j = ] s E [p p min j = b] ; or s > E [p p min j = b] respectively. Figure shows all possible equilibria. 4 There is always a market equilibrium with = if E [p p min j = ] < s: The rest of the equilibria imply > and is de ned jointly by the roots q (if they exist) of E [p p min j = + ( )q] = s (0) There is a unique equilibrium when the number of shoppers is high, or if the search cost is either low or high. But there are three possible equilibria if there is a low number of shoppers and the search cost is moderate. One in which only shoppers search, and two where > : Note that in this latter case, the equilibrium with the smaller root q is unstable, while the other is locally stable (as well as the one with q = 0). Corollary and Table summarize the equilibrium results. Corollary There can be one, two or three possible market equilibria when there are shoppers and ( ) consumers have positive search cost (s > 0) If search cost is high: equilibrium is unique and = If search cost is low: equilibrium is unique and > If search cost is moderate and the number of shoppers is high: equilibrium is unique and = and the number of shoppers is low, there are three equilibria: i) =, ii) > and iii) 3 > > : 4 Exept for the case where is such that E [p p minj = ] = s or s = E [p p minj = b]. 8

9 (a) High search cost (b) Low search cost (c) Moderate search cost Figure : Nonsequential search equilibria with constant search cost Shoppers () Search Cost (s) low high low > > moderate = ; > ; 3 > > = high = = Table : Nonsequential search equilibria with constant search cost 9

10 3 Dynamics and asymmetric pricing Asymmetric pricing refers to the case where output prices react di erently to positive and negative changes in input prices There is an abundant empirical literature that suggests asymmetric pricing is more the norm than an anomaly. 5 In particular, those studies nd that prices react faster to positive than to negative cost shocks (rockets and feathers pattern). In general, most tests of asymmetric pricing are done estimating a dynamic error correction model of the type y t = m+ P i=0 + i (x t i ) + + m P i (x t i ) + (y t 0 x t ) + " t () i=0 where y t is the change in the output price in period t and x t is the change in input price and " t is iid. The last term in parenthesis is the error correction term that accounts for the current deviations from the long-run equilibrium price level. The parameter is expected to be negative and = (sometimes imposed and not estimated). The rockets and feathers pattern is supported by the data when the cumulative response function (CRF) P to positive shocks is above the one for negative cost shocks ( m b + P i > m b i for m Min [m + ; m ]). In general, data restrictions prevent the econometrician from including a su cient number of lags in () such that the CRF is estimated for all the periods where the price accommodates to the shock. 6 A simple dynamic environment where the static game presented in the previous section is repeated over time can be used to explain the rockets and feathers pattern. At the beginning of each period, nature chooses a high or low production cost with probabilities and ( ). Firms set their prices and consumers their searching rules simultaneously. After the market clears, nature draws another production cost shock while consumers learn the previous cost realization. Since the main motivation for this model is to explain asymmetric pricing in competitive markets with atomistics rms, I do not consider the possibility of collusion. There are two sources of price variation over time. Production cost changes and/or changes in consumers expectations. For simplicity, let the probability of high costs follow a Markov process = h(c t ) with h (c H ) = and h (c L ) = ( ). The state of the economy is represented by the past and current cost realizations k t = (c t ; c t ) with k t 5 See footnote 4 in the introduction for empirical work on asymmetric pricing. 6 Although the complete adjustmet to a one-time cost change should imply a common nal price level regardless of the sign of the shock (otherwise mark-ups will grow inde nitely with very volatile inputs), the number of periods to complete the adjustment could be di erent. Thus, there are two possible type of rockets and feathers. A vertical asymmetry refers to higher CRF for the rst periods of adjustment while a horizontal asymmetry implies that the adjustment to a positive shock is completed in less periods than to a negative shock. For the reasons said above, there is no evidence of horizontal rockets and feathers. i=0 i=0 0

11 K = fll; LH; HL; HHg. The transition matrix is P = () where P ij = Pr (s t = K (j) js t = K (i)) : The unique invariant distribution for K is = f=; ( ) =; ( ) =; =g : In this simpli ed model, it takes only two periods for prices to fully adjust to an isolated cost shock. After a cost shock, rms increase (decrease) prices reacting to bigger (lower) production costs and in the following period, they adjust prices to be consistent with consumers updated prior. We are interested in nding the conditions such that + 0 > 0 : Denote p k the average price in the market when state is k. The expected change in prices to a positive and negative cost shock are respectively: 4p E 4c + = Pr (HL) Pr (LHjHL) [p LH p HL ] + Pr (LL) Pr (LHjLL) [p LH p LL ] (3) 4p E = Pr (LH) Pr (HLjLH) [p LH p HL ]+Pr (HH) Pr (HLjHH) [p HH p HL ] (4) 4c and the di erence is 4p 4p E 4c + E = 4c ( ) [(p LH p LL ) (p HH p HL )] ( ) p t c t (5) Prices will be set asymmetrically as long as the reaction of prices to cost shocks is sensitive to the prior held by consumers. Clearly, there would be no asymmetry if cost shocks were iid ( = =) or if consumers held constant priors over time. A change in consumer s priors a ects the gains from search and therefore the equilibrium pool of informed consumers. This in turn a ects the pricing decision of the rm. In general, an increase in the expected production cost increases the expected minimum price more than the expected price in the market. This can be seen in (8). The gains from search E [p p min j] become atter as increases. Thus, the indi erent consumer has a lower search cost (see equation 9) and the equilibrium search intensity decreases with. When consumers expect higher production costs, they search less anticipating lower price dispersion: 0: The analysis is similar for the case of a degenerate g () : When an equilibrium has the property of = ; a change in does not have an e ect in the search intensity. 7 It is necessary that the equilibrium involves searching from consumers with positive search 7 For expositional purposes, I am assuming that the change in does not change the equilibrium type. c t

12 Figure 3: Gains from search and higher expected costs cost ( > ). Ignoring the instance of the unstable equilibrium, an increase in decreases consumer s search intensity. The probability with which consumers search is lower: q (s > 0; 0 ) > q (s > 0; 00 ) when 0 < 00 : Figure 3 shows this e ect for the case of low number of shoppers and moderate search costs. The expected market price for a given cost realization c and prior is given by E [pjc] = Z p F (p; c)dp (6) where the price distribution F (; c) is the market equilibrium distribution (F (; c; ) in (7) with = + ( ) g (es) from (9)). Integrating by parts and deriving: E (pjc) ( ) = + c Log > 0 (7) + it is easy to check that price adjustments to marginal cost is indeed sensible to the amount of search by consumers (hence ). The more search there is in equilibrium the bigger the passthrough. If = ; the pass-through is complete while if = 0 there is no price adjustment. It is important to note that the response of prices to production costs doesn t depend on the reserve price : This will become important when analyzing sequential search. Given (7) and the fact that higher priors imply less search, the sign of the asymmetry is determined by the process that determines : Under cost persistence consumers search more if past cost was low. Firms know that and compete more intensively. As a result, the pass-through is higher when previous cost is low than when it is high. The term in brackets in (5) is positive. The next proposition summarizes the results. Proposition 3 Prices rise faster than they fall when consumers search nonsequentially and there is cost persistence ( > =).

13 The result does not depend on the discrete nature of the cost level. Indeed, assume that every period production cost can go up or down with probability = Pr ct c t > j c t c t > = Pr ct c t < j c t c t < = > =: The states of the economy and transition matrix are equivalent to the c = fc L ; c H g case with H representing c > 0 and L = c < 0. 4 More sellers In this section, I extend the previous results to more atomistics markets. The setup of the model is the same as before with the only exception that n. The reason to present the results in a separate section is that the rms trade-o between low and high prices (business-stealing and surplus-appropiation e ects) changes in a way that the problem becomes less tractable and simulations are needed to characterize the gains from search for consumers. As before, I rst obtain the Nash best responses for the rms and then nd the market equilibrium of the stage game. Dynamics and the rockets and feathers result follow. Equations (3) to (6) as well as Proposition can be reexpressed to account for n > (see proof in Appendix and (Varian, 980)). The rms NR to a given number of informed consumers and production cost c implies a cdf : n ( )( p) F (p; c; ) = (8) n(p c) h i ( )( c) with support c + +(n ) ; : Again, the relationship between and prices implies F (; 0 ) > F (; 00 ) if 0 > 00. That is, rms set lower prices (mark-ups) as expected demand becomes more elastic. However, the traditional oligopoly model predictions on the relationship between number of rms and mark-up is not met. The presence of more stores in the market increases the likelihood of setting prices in the extremes of the distribution. But the strenghtening of the business-stealing and surplus-appropriation e ects is not symmetric. The changes in F () can be appreciated in Figure 4. As n increases, the probability of being the lowest price in the market decreases exponentially while the bene ts from charging high prices decrease at a rate =n. Thus, the surplus-appropriation e ect becomes relatively more important. In other words, even though the captive market becomes smaller with greater n, becoming the supplier of the informed consumers is harder. Fixing, the expected price in the market increases with the number of rms and in the limit the price distribution converges weakly to monopoly pricing (Stahl, 989; and Janssen and Moraga-González, 004). 8 still show that property. Since this is true for any ; the market equilibrium will 8 Monopoly SPE in a search model without shoppers was rst found by Diamond (Diamond, 97). 3

14 Figure 4: Equilibrium price distribution and number of stores (c=0,u=,ţ=0.) The gains from search for a consumer are E c [E [p p min jc; ; n]] = E c Z v p p ( c) n [ F (p)] n [ F (p)] dp (n ) (p c) ( p) (9) The e ect of n on the equilibrium search intensity is the combination of the expected prices and minimum prices. c, hence, decrease the search intensity. When n changes, it, the support of the price distribution increases and the E [p min ] is smaller. Thus, the gains from search are bigger with n and a market equilibrium will have consumers searching more. Proposition 4 Search intensity increases with n : E [p p min jc; ; n + ] > E [p p min jc; ; n] As in the duopoly case, E [p p min jc; n] is continuous in and increases as is away from the extremes. The conditions for uniqueness of Proposition as well as its corollary depend on the concavity of E [] in (9). From simulations (Figure 5.a and Table ), it can be shown that the expected spread has the same shape as in the duopoly case. For any n; expected prices decrease with, but E [p; n] and E [p min ; n] do it at di erent rates. This makes the gains from search increase at a decreasing rate until a maximum b (n) is reached. Then, E [p; n] starts converging to E [p min ; n] : Also, b (n) increases with n independent of and c: Similarly Figure 5.b shows the e ects of higher costs on gains from search. This leads us to the following conjecture and claim Conjecture E[p p minjc;n] c 0; E[p p min jc;n] 0 and has a maximum b (n) with b 0 > 0: Claim Proposition and its corollary hold when n > As in the duopoly case, higher production costs increase expected prices but expected minimum price increase as well. The latter e ect compensates the former and consumers nd less attractive to search when they expect higher costs. < 0 Assuming cost 4

15 (a) Number of rms (=c = ) (b) Cost variation (n = 00; = ) Figure 5: Conditional Gains from search n> =c = =c = 5 =c = 0 jn : 0: :68 0:7555 0:4958 :005 :0408 0:48377 :3076 : : 0: : : :6345 :9046 :347 0:7385 :33967 : :3 0: : : : :75007 : :85046 : : :4 0:57 0:8740 0: :83634 :3384 :4339 0:94088 :4893 :6337 0:5 0: : :9094 0:89045 :35558 : :00758 :54553 : :6 0: : : :9688 :37607 : :0496 :54803 :656 0:7 0: : :9363 0:94699 : :47778 : :5638 : :8 0: :8759 0:9676 0: : :4885 :0674 :57055 : :9 0: : :9638 0:9079 :39604 :4808 :03534 : : Table : Simulated E[p p min jc; n] n b (n) 0:6349 0:847 0:866 0:8704 0:8755 0:879 0:88 0:8844 0:8863 0:888 0:8894 Table 3: Maximum E[p p min jc; n] and n 5

16 persistence E(p) c > 0: c > 0 ; the only result needed to prove the rockets and feathers for n > is Proposition 5 Given conjecture, the Rockets and Feathers result holds for n>. 5 Sequential search In this section I explore the implications of changing the search protocol used by consumers to sequential search. A consumer that searches sequentially decides whether to search for lower prices after visiting the rst store or buy at the observed price. Thus, compared with nonsequential search, there is a gain in the sense that a consumer might not need to search if she nds a good deal in the rst price sampled. Sequential search can be optimal when the search technology does not allow for signi cant economies of scale in the sample size. All else equal, consumers uncertainty over production cost makes sequential searching more desirable than in the certainty case since consumers are better informed about the cost realization (hence, the market price distribution) after observing a price. The change in the search protocol used by consumers modi es the stage game presented in section II from simultaneous to a sequential-move game. After nature draws a production cost c C; rms choose their prices simultaneously and commit to them for period. Once prices are set, each consumer visits a random store and decides between buying at the price observed p 0 or searching (with a cost s i ) for a better price in the remaining store. A consumer that decided to search buys from the store with the lowest price of the two observed (perfect recall). Assume that the distribution of search costs g () is degenerate at s >> 0. The market demand is composed by shoppers and ( ) consumers with search cost s: A consumer i that visits a store j (p j = p 0 ) has conditional utility u ij (a i ; a i ; p) = a i [Min [p] s i ] + ( a i ) p j (0) Similarly, a rm j visited by the set of [0; ( ) =] nonshoppers has a payo 8 >< j (p j ; p j ; a; c) = (p j c) >: + R! a i d i fp j < p j g + fp j = p j g + s i =s () A consumer strategy is a function q i (; p 0 ; s i ) (A) of the observed price p 0 P and search cost. Since shoppers enjoy being informed, q i (; p 0 ; s = 0) = (search) for any p 0 : Firm j s strategy pro le is represented by all possible price distributions conditional on the cost realization: f jc () = (f jc (p)) pp;cc : 9 A SBNE (market equilibrium) consists 9 For expositional reasons, the cost realization now is expressed as a subindex of the strategy pro le instead of an argument of it. Z 0 9 >= ( a i ) d i fp j > p j g >; 6

17 on a strategy pro le = D ; F and system of beliefs 0 p 0 ; F p 0 such that i) P D = (q i (; 0) ; q i (; s)) in D is a best response to F = f c p; D pp; cc ; ii) F is a Nash best response (NR) to D, and iii) 0 = Pr c H jp 0 ; ; F is the Bayesian update of prior for each observed price consistent with F : An intuitive and desired property for the optimal search rule is that it preserves the reservation price property (RPP). In such a case, q would be a step function with q (p 0 ev; s) = 0 (don t search) and q (p 0 > ev; s) = (search) where ev is the reservation price. A feature of models that involve sequential search from unknown price distributions is that consumers search rules may not preserve the RPP. For example, a consumer that observes a low price p 0 might consider that the cost realization for the rms was low and continue searching for lower prices, while if he had observed a high price, the fact that high cost is more probable might make it a bargain. Assume that the price distributions chosen by rms for each production cost level are represented by F H (p; r) p[p H ;r] and F L (p; r) p[p H ;r] with F L (p; r) > F H (p; r) for all p and p H > p L The expected bene t of sampling one more price for a consumer that observed p 0 is the expected price from the other store, conditional on it being lower than p 0 : Z EG(p 0 ; r) = 0 (p 0 ) p 0 p H F H (p; r) dp + 0 (p 0 ) Z p0 p L F L (p; r) dp () A monotonic EG implies a unique (if there is one) reservation price ev such that EG (ev; r) = s: Two e ects take place when p 0 is observed: a direct and a learning e ect. The former is the standard e ect when sampling from a known distribution. High observed prices mean a higher probability of sampling a lower price next time. The learning e ect isolates the new information about the unknown sampling distribution obtained with p 0. When the learning e ect is opposite to the direct e ect EG might be non-monotonic and the RPP can be violated. As it is usual in the literature of optimal sampling from unknown distributions, assumptions are made to preserve the reservation price property. When the price distribution is exogenous, assumptions rely on F (Rothschild, 974). If the price distribution is endogenously determined, assumptions on either production cost structure or the number of shoppers guarantee a weak learning e ect. 0 I will assume that (for a given search cost s) the gap between the two possible production costs (c H c L ) is su ciently 0 For example, Benabou et. al. (993) assume low correlation in rm s marginal costs. In their model, a consumer that observes a low price knows that the rm has a low cost and needs to infer the cost of the other producer in order to decide to sample another price. When costs have low correlation, the learning e ect is dominated by the direct e ect and EG is monotonic. 7

18 low that guarantees the RPP. Thus, restrict consumer strategy pro les to the type: D = (q i (; 0) ; q i (; s)) in D (3) q i (p 0 ; 0) = for all p for p0 > ev q i (p 0 ; s) = 0 otherwise Shoppers search at any price below while nonshoppers search if the price is above ev: As in the case of nonsequential search, the existence of an atom of shoppers eliminates the possibility of a SPE (Stahl, 989). Furthermore, the upper bound for any price distribution is ev instead of the monopoly price. Lemma Any rm NR implies p ev and f c (p = ev) > 0. A consequence of this lemma is that in any market equilibrium, consumers with positive search cost never search ( = ). As in Proposition, there is no pure strategy equilibrium for the rms and the price distribution does not present any mass points or gaps on the support [p c; ev]. A rm that sets a price ev sells to captive consumers while if it charges lower prices, the likelihood of capturing the informed consumers increases. In equilibrium, the rm is indi erent between the reserve price and the prices that generate the same expected pro t: j (p j ; c; ev) = ( F c (p j ; ev)) + ( ) ( ) (p j c) = (ev c) = j (ev; c) ; c fc L ; c H g Lemma 3 Given the number of shoppers and consumers search rule D from (3); there is a unique rm Nash best response that implies: ( )(ev p) F c (p; ev) = p [p (p c) c; ev] ; c fc L ; c H g (5) with p c = c + ( )(ev c) + : Consumers choose their optimal search strategies by maximizing their expected utility () given F and prior Using (5) and Bayes rule, the posterior probability of high cost becomes (4) 0 = ( 0 p0 < p H FH 0 FH 0 +( )F L 0 p 0 p H (6) Below, I show that there is no rm NR if the search rule does not satisfy the RPP. 8

19 Figure 6: Unique reservation price Thus, there is no learning e ect over p 0 < p H and EG (p 0 < p H ; ev) increases with observed prices. At the same time, for p 0 p H ; 0 > and decreases with p 0 : That is, when observed prices are supported by both, high and low production costs, the learning e ect reinforces the direct e ect and EG (p 0 p H ; ev) is also monotonic in p 0: To characterize the market equilibrium, we need to nd an optimal reserve price given that rms price accordingly. Uninformed consumers are indi erent between searching or not when the observed price is equal to the reservation price. At the same time, rms anticipate ev correctly and price accordingly. Thus, an equilibrium is characterized by EG(p 0 = ev; ev) s (7) Figure 6 shows the expected gains from search for the case where { = ; = =; s = 0:5; c H = =; = =5g: EG is not monotonic in p 0 but, the assumption of low c H guarantees a unique reservation price. Intuitively, the closer c H is to c L, the closer p H is to p L. Therefore, the array of possible observed prices that reveal low cost realization are never high enough to justify searching. From the point of view of the rms, the relevant reservation price is any root in (7) below :The next proposition characterizes the market equilibrium. Proposition 6 Under sequential search and assuming RPP (c H c L su ciently small), there is a unique market equilibrium given by (3), (5) and (6) with ev = Min farg solve(7); g If the assumption on low c H c L is relaxed, the possibility of non-monotonic search rules arises. Consider the case where ( ) uninformed consumers have a search rule q consisting of two reservation prices (ev L ; ev H ): 8 0 p 0 ev L < ep >< ev q = L < p 0 < ep 0 ep p >: 0 ev H ev H p 0 with ep > c H. A rm chooses prices given (; q) and -when cost realization is low- takes into account that the ( ) = potentially captive consumers search if p (ev L ; ep) are chosen. 9

20 Proposition 7 There is no (symmetric) market equilibrium when consumers have nonmonotonic search rules with two reservation prices. Even though in a market equilibrium, only shoppers search for low prices, the search rule chosen by the uninformed consumers in uences nal prices by setting an upper bound to them. As the number of shoppers increases, the expected prices decline for two reasons. First, holding the search strategies xed, more shoppers imply more competition and expected prices decrease since p c shifts down and Fc > 0. Second, lower expected prices imply lower equilibrium reservation price in (7) thus, lower prices charged by the rms. Similarly, the amount of informed consumers is not a ected by. The e ect of higher expected production costs occur through the reservation price chosen by the uninformed consumers. An increase in doesn t a ect the search gains when low prices are observed EG (p 0 < p H ; ev) but decreases EG (ev; ev). Assuming c L = 0, EG(ev; ev) = c H EG (ev; ev) < 0 ev c H ( ) Therefore the reservation price will be higher (lower search intensity) when a higher production cost is expected. As in the case of nonsequential search, the search intensity (through reservation price) is lower when a higher production cost is expected. Nevertheless, there is no room for asymmetric pricing with sequential searching in this setting. The equivalent to equation (5) would be: 4p E 4c + 4p E = 4c ( ) p t ev (8) c t ev c t As can be seen from (7), p c only depends on the number of informed consumers and not on their reserve price. Proposition 8 There is no price asymmetry when consumers have search cost s f0; sg and search sequentially. 6 Conclusion 0

21 7 Appendix Proof. [Proposition ] This proof is done for the n rms case since it is also used in Section III. Therefore, p ( )( c) = c + +(n ) in (5). To show that F (; c; ) is a unique symmetric NR the proof is divided in three steps (to simplify notation, ignore the fact that F is conditional on (c; )). First, it shows that there are no point masses in the equilibrium pdf. Second, for " > 0; F (p + ") > 0 and F ( ") <. Last, there are no gaps in the support of F (p). Assume there exist a price bp (p ; ] such that Pr (p = bp) F (fbpg) > 0 (by de nition, F (fp g) = 0). Then, there is an arbitrary small " such that F (fbp "g) = 0:A rm could deviate from F () by applying F d () similar to F () with the exception that F d (fbpg) = 0 and F d (fbp "g) = F (fbpg) : The expected gains for the deviator can be decomposed to four scenarios, depending on the prices charged by the other rms. Let p l be their lowest of the n prices in the market. If p l < bp " : If p l > bp : When p l = bp : nx n j j= nx n F (bp ") j [ F (bp ")] n j ( ) " j n j= Lastly, if p l (bp F (fbpg) j [ F (fbpg)] n j (9) ( ) " + [ F (bp)] n (30) n "; bp) ; the expected gains are: (p c) j ( ) nx n [F (bp) F (fbpg) F (bp ")] j [ F (bp)] n j (p c) j j= n + " ( ) n (3) + " (3) As "! 0, (9) and (30) go to zero while (3) and (3) remain positive.. Suppose F ( ") =. Then at setting p = generates an increase in pro ts (with respect to ") and no loss in customers. Similarly, if F (bp + ") = 0; it has to be that (bp + ") = () : By charging p = bp+"=; pro ts are bigger: (bp + "=) > (p ) = () : 3. Suppose there exists an interval (p ; p ) such that F (p ) = F (p ) : Then, by placing some density on bp (p ; p ) ; a rm will gain by increasing its markup. There is no expected loss since by part of the proof, there are no ties at p. Given,,, and 3 above, the only function that satis es s (p)( F (p)) n + f (p)f (p) = ()

22 is: F (p) = ( )( p) n(p c) n Proof. [Lemma ] I rst show that there exists a unique global maximum b for E [p p min ] and strict local concavity around E [p p min j = b] : Then, concavity everywhere is provided. From (8), E[p p min ] ( c) ( ) ( + ) + = 3 log ( ) ( + ) E[] with Lim!0! c E[] 3 and Lim!! : The term in curly brackets determines the sign of this expression. Critical points are at = b 6= f0; g; log + = ( + ) ( ) ( + ) At = 0, LHS = RHS: The di erence in slopes between RHS and LHS is: (33) LHS RHS = 4 ( ) ( ) ( + ( )) which is positive (negative) for < (>) =. Since at = ; LHS > RHS; there is a unique critical point at b > 0:5: The second derivative of (8) is: E[p p min ] = ( c) ( ) ( + ) 4 Using (33) and rearranging, at b; E[p p min ] = (3 + ( (3 + ))) + (3 ) ( ) ( + ) log ( c) b 3 ( b) ( b) ( b) ( + b) b 4 < 0 For concavity everywhere, (3 + ( (3 + ))) + (3 ) ( ) ( + ) log At = 0; both expressions are equal to zero. For > 0; it can be veri ed that LHS > RHS > 0 Numerically, the maximum can be shown to be b t 0:63486

23 Proof. [Corollary ] Reexpress (9) using (8) ( E [c]) log ( ) + = g () At = g (0) ; the RHS is positive while the LHS is zero. By Lemma, LHS is concave and lower than. Thus, g cuts from below the expected gains from search at least once. If g(0) > b; it is easy to see that there is a unique solution to (9). If g(0) < b; the possibility of multiple solutions is eliminated under the assumptions of concave g (s) on the relevant range Proof. [Proposition 3] Let the equation in (9) be represented by G: Then es = G G es < 0 From (8), the numerator is negative. the denominator is G es = g g es + E [p p minjc; b] < 0 Since at es the inverse cdf cuts the expected price di erential from below, the term in parenthesis is negative. From (7) E [p] c = + + ( ) Log > 0 ( + ) Therefore, E[p] c < 0 and equation (5) is negative when h0 > 0 ( < =). The same argument applies to the case of degenerate g (). E [p p min j = + ( ) q] = s could have one or two roots q depending on the size of and s: The stable equilibrium has E [] cutting s from above. As increases, E [] gets atter and q (hence ) decreases.: Proof. [Proposition 4] As long as the conditional gains from search increase with n; es q n > 0 in (9) and n 0 in a stable equilibrium of (0). The gains from search are: E [p p min jc; n] = Z v p pn [ F (p)] n f (p) dp = De ne z = F (p). Then, p = Changing variables, E [p p min jc; n] = Z 0 Z v p p(v c) (n ) (p c) (v p) n [ F (p)]n dp ( )+cnzn (n )(p c)( p) and dp = ( )n(n )( c)zn dz: (z( )+z n ) ( ) + cnz nz n n Z ( ) + nz n dz = nz n + dz ( ) nzn

24 wlg, the marginal cost can be normalized to 0 and adjusted to 0. De ne A n+ = + ( ) (n + ) zn and A n = + ( ) nzn : Z E [p p min jn + ] E [p p min jn] = 0 Z = 0 = 0 0 z n = ( ) [n (n + ) z] A n+ A n dz = n=(n+) Z 0 z n = ( ) [n (n + ) z] A n+ A n dz 0 h + ( ) (n + ) n n+ 0 n i + 0 n ( ) n n n+ (n + ) z n nz n dz = A n+ A n Z n=(n+) Z 0 z n = ( ) [(n + ) z n] dz A n+ A n z n [n (n + ) z] dz = 0 ( ) Proof. [Lemma ] Given non-shoppers reservation price ev; assume that rms set prices according to a cdf F c () with upper bound bp: It is clear that bp < ev:is not possible since a rm could increase revenues and keep the same number of consumers by setting p = ev: Suppose bp > ev. A rm that charges p = bp would not capture any customers while by ( ) charging p = ev the customers are at least : Thus, the only possibility left is bp = ev Proof. [Lemma 3] Directly from Lemma and Proposition. Proof. [Proposition 6] Assume wlg c L = 0: From (), the upper bound for EG (p 0 < p H ; ev) is given by Lim EG (p 0 < p H; ev) = ev ( ) c H + ev ( ) Log p 0!p H ev ( ) + c H This limit grows with c H. Assuming c H su ciently low, EG (p 0 < p H ; r) < s and thus ev > p H : For observed prices (p 0 > p H ), using p 0 = ev in (), EG (ev; ev) = ev (ev c H ) [ev c H ( )] + ( ) Log + there are two roots to EG (ev; r) = s:and the smaller one can be ignored since EG ev 0 for ev c H : h h ii EG (ev; ev) + ( ) Log + = ev (ev ( ) ch ) + ( ) c ev [ev ( ) c H ] H 4 (34)

25 Proof. [Proposition 7] By Lemma, p ev H : Expected pro ts for any p have to satisfy (p) (ev H c) ( ) =: As in Proposition, an equilibrium can not consist on pure strategies nor the price distribution have mass points or gaps over [p ; ev L ] [ (ep; ev H ]. Also, F (ev H ") < as well as F p c H + " > 0 Assume rst that F (p 0 ) = F (ev L ) for p 0 (ev L ; ep) : The expected pro ts are (ev H ) = (ev H c) ( ) = (35) (p) = (p c) f( ) = + [ F (p)]g p [p ; ev L ] [ (ep; ev H ] (36) (ep) = (ep c) f( ) = + [ F (ep)] + F (fepg) =g (37) and there is no F (p) that satis es (35), (36) and (37) : If p 0 (ev L ; ep) are considered, expected pro t is p 0 = p 0 c + F p 0 + F (ep) F p 0 Clearly, Lim p 0!ep F (p0 ) < F (ep) and thus an atom of probability is needed on ep 5

26 References Bacon, R. W. (99): Rockets and feathers: the asymmetric speed of adjustment of UK retail gasoline prices to cost changes, Energy Economics, 3(3), 8. Benabou, R., and R. Gertner (993): Search with Learning from Prices: Does Increased In ationary Uncertainty Lead to Higher Markups, The Review of Economic Studies, 60(), Borenstein, S., A. C. Cameron, and R. Gilbert (997): Do Gasoline Prices Respond Asymmetrically to Crude Oil Price Changes?, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, (), Boyd, M. S., and B. W. Brorsen. (988): Price Asymmetry in the U.S. Pork Marketing Channel, N.C.J. Agricultural Economics, 0, Braverman, A. (980): Consumer Search and Alternative Market Equilibria, The Review of Economic Studies, 47(3), Deltas, G. (004): Retail Gasoline Price Dynamics and Local Market Power, Discussion paper, Working Paper. Diamond, P. A. (97): A model of price adjustment, Journal of Economic Theory, 3(), Eckert, A. (00): Retail price cycles and response asymmetry, Canadian Journal of Economics, 35(), Goodwin, B. K., and M. T. Holt (999): Price Transmission and Asymmetric Adjustment in the U.S. Beef Sector, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 8(3), Hannan, T. H., and A. N. Berger (99): The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence from the Banking Industry, The American Economic Review, 84(4), Janssen, M. C., and J. L. Moraga-González (004): Strategic Pricing, Consumer Search and the Number of Firms, The Review of Economic Studies, 7(4), 089 8(30). Karrenbrock, J. D. (99): The behavior of retail gasoline prices: symmetric or not?, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, (Jul), 9 9. Lewis, M. (003): Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Consumer Search: An Examination of the Retail Gasoline Market, Discussion Paper , CSEM working paper- Center for the Study of Energy Markets. 6

Rockets and Feathers Understanding Asymmetric Pricing

Rockets and Feathers Understanding Asymmetric Pricing Rockets and Feathers Understanding Asymmetric Pricing [Job Market Paper] Mariano Tappata UCLA January 2006 Abstract Prices rise like rockets but fall like feathers. This stylized fact of most markets is

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online Appendix June 7, 206 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration

More information

Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1

Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1 Competition, Product Safety, and Product Liability 1 Yongmin Chen 2 University of Colorado Boulder and Zhejiang University Xinyu Hua 3 Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Abstract. A rm s incentive

More information

EconS Bertrand Competition

EconS Bertrand Competition EconS 425 - Bertrand Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction Today, we

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure Essi Eerola RUESG, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland Niku Määttänen Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain and The Research Institute

More information

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis

Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly. Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Price-Matching in a Sequential Search Duopoly Aleksandr Yankelevich Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis Competitor Based Price Clauses Competitor Based Price Clauses: any price guarantee

More information

Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers

Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth: The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers David Gill University of Oxford John Thanassoulis University of Oxford April 2007 Abstract In this paper we study

More information

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Ricardo Cavalcanti Getulio Vargas Foundation Ed Nosal Cleveland Fed November 006 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We describe counterfeiting activity

More information

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Imperfect Price Information and Competition mperfect Price nformation and Competition Sneha Bakshi April 14, 2016 Abstract Price competition depends on prospective buyers information regarding market prices. This paper illustrates that if buyers

More information

Consumers search. Industrial Organization. Bernard Caillaud. October 20, Master APE - Paris School of Economics

Consumers search. Industrial Organization. Bernard Caillaud. October 20, Master APE - Paris School of Economics Industrial Organization Master APE - Paris School of Economics October 20, 2016 Consumers inertia as a source of market power We have seen how firms market power rests on differentiation, real or perceived,

More information

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth David Gill Division of Economics University of Southampton John Thanassoulis Dept. of Economics & Christ Church

More information

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion

Notes and Comments on Search Costs and. Equilibrium Price Dispersion. Moshe Barach. Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion Notes and Comments on Search Costs and Equilibrium Price Dispersion Moshe Barach Based on Information, Search and Price Dispersion By Michael R. Baye, John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten Various models of

More information

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models Munich Discussion Paper No. 2010-25 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

Part II. Market power

Part II. Market power Part II. Market power Chapter 3. Static imperfect competition Slides Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies Paul Belleflamme and Martin Peitz Cambridge University Press 2009 Introduction to Part

More information

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange fee Hans Zenger a; a European Commission, DG Competition, Chief Economist Team, 1049 Brussels, Belgium February 14, 2011 Abstract Two widely discussed

More information

Competitive Bundling

Competitive Bundling Competitive Bundling Jidong Zhou Department of Economics NYU Stern School of Business March 24 (Incomplete Draft) Abstract This paper presents a model of competitive bundling with an arbitrary number of

More information

Search with learning: understanding asymmetric price adjustments

Search with learning: understanding asymmetric price adjustments Search with learning: understanding asymmetric price adjustments Huanxing Yang and Lixin Ye In many retail markets, prices rise faster than they fall. We develop a model of search with learning to explain

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements O A Florian Morath Johannes Münster June 17, 2016 This supplementary appendix to the article Online shopping and platform design

More information

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares Uniform and Targeted dvertising with Shoppers and symmetric Loyal Market Shares Michael rnold, Chenguang Li and Lan Zhang October 9, 2012 Preliminary and Incomplete Keywords: informative advertising, targeted

More information

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm.

Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm. Centralization versus Decentralization: An Application to Price Setting by a Multi-Market Firm. Ricardo Alonso Univeristy of Southern California Wouter Dessein University of Chicago and Toulouse School

More information

Search and Categorization

Search and Categorization MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Search and Categorization Chaim Fershtman and Arthur Fishman and Jidong Zhou Tel Aviv University, Bar-Ilan University, NYU Stern December 03 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5366/

More information

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note

The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies. A Cautionary Note Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 812 The Environmental Impact of Bertrand and Cournot Duopolies.

More information

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist Economics 335 March 3, 999 Notes 8: Models of Spatial Competition I. Product differentiation A. Definition Products are said to be differentiated if consumers consider them to be imperfect substitutes.

More information

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2 EconS 425 - Vertical Pricing Restraints 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 38 Introduction

More information

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia March 30, 2014 Abstract We analyze how the market power of firms in consumer search markets depends on how consumers form beliefs

More information

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract Information externalities in a model of sales John Morgan Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University Martin Sefton School of Economics, University of Nottingham Abstract We anlayze Varian's (1980) Model

More information

Linking Reputations: The Signaling and Feedback Effects of Umbrella Branding

Linking Reputations: The Signaling and Feedback Effects of Umbrella Branding MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Linking Reputations: The Signaling and Feedback Effects of Umbrella Branding Jeanine Miklos-Thal 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/11045/ MPRA Paper No. 11045,

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia February 15, 2014 Abstract We analyze two unexplored aspects of the Wolinsky model (Wolinsky (1986)

More information

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (Ph.D.) Introduction In this class, we will see two papers that will be used as building blocks of most of this

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors gratefully acknowledge

More information

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero

Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly. Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Are Prices a Good Signal of the Degree of Product Differentiation in Oligopoly Markets with Asymmetric Information? Miguel Ángel Ropero Department of Applied Economics Faculty of Economics University of

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Discussion paper No. 113 Cannibalization may Allow a Cost-inefficient Firm to Earn more than a Cost-effcient Firm in a Duopoly with Two Vertically Differentiated Goods Ryoma Kitamura

More information

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley 1 Overview of the Course This is a readings course. The lectures

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text. 1 Monopoly A monopolist is de ned as a single seller of a well-de ned product for which there are no close substitutes. In reality, there are

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors acknowledge nancial support

More information

URL:

URL: Behaviour-Based Price Discrimination under Advertising and Imperfectly Informed Consumers Rosa-Branca Esteves Sofia Cerqueira 08/ 014 Behaviour-Based Price Discrimination under Advertising and Imperfectly

More information

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly.

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly. Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly. Maarten C.W. Janssen University of Vienna, Austria and Tinbergen Institute Rotterdam, The Netherlands. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas,

More information

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Yongmin Chen Department of Economics University of Colorado Boulder, CO 80309 September 2006 Abstract. This paper considers variants of a dynamic duopoly

More information

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Inferring the strategy space from market outcomes. Authors: Flavio Menezes, John Quiggin. Working Paper: R13_1

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Inferring the strategy space from market outcomes. Authors: Flavio Menezes, John Quiggin. Working Paper: R13_1 013 TITLE: Inferring the strategy space from market outcomes 011 RSMG Working Paper Series Risk and Uncertainty Program Authors: Flavio Menezes, John Quiggin Working Paper: R13_1 Schools of Economics and

More information

NET Institute*

NET Institute* NET Institute* www.netinst.org Working Paper #06-02 September 2006 Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet Yongmin Chen and Chuan He University of Colorado at Boulder * The Networks, Electronic

More information

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013

The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution. Ofer Cornfeld. June 2013 The origins of an equilibrium wage distribution Ofer Cornfeld Tel-Aviv University (TAU) June 2013 The empirical attributes of the earnings distribution, Neal and Rosen (2000): "Earnings distributions...

More information

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game

On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game On cleaner technologies in a transboundary pollution game Hassan Benchekroun a Amrita Ray Chaudhuri b January 2009 a Department of Economics, McGill University, 855 Sherbrooke Ouest, Montreal, QC, Canada,

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO.

WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. WORKING PAPER SERIES* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ALFRED LERNER COLLEGE OF BUSINESS & ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE WORKING PAPER NO. 2008-14 ASYMMETRIC MARKET SHARES, ADVERTISING, AND PRICING: EQUILIBRIUM

More information

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Universidade de veiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Área Científica de Economia E/nº 41/007 Entry Decision and

More information

SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY. Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita

SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY. Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita SERVICE PROVISION ON A NETWORK WITH ENDOGENOUS CONSUMPTION CAPACITY Nikolaos Georgantzís and Carlos Gutiérrez-Hita WP-AD 008-01 Corresponding author: N. Georgantzís: LEE/LINEEX and Economics Dept., Universitat

More information

Competition and Trust.

Competition and Trust. Competition and Trust. Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini, Pedro Teles y, Revision April 2006 Abstract We study the interaction of competition and reputation as e - ciency enhancing mechanisms. We analyze

More information

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly EconS 425 - Perfect Competition and Monopoly Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing TI 2004-068/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing Maarten C.W. Janssen José Luis Moraga-González* Matthijs R. Wildenbeest Faculty of Economics,

More information

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations V. V. Chari, Mikhail Golosov, and Aleh Tsyvinski Working Paper October

More information

Entry and Merger Policy

Entry and Merger Policy 7 85 October 07 Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux, Yassine Lefouili and Wilfried Sand Zantman Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux y Yassine Lefouili z Wilfried Sand-Zantman x August 07 Abstract This

More information

Two Lectures on Information Design

Two Lectures on Information Design Two Lectures on nformation Design 10th DSE Winter School Stephen Morris December 2015 nformation Design Usually in information economics, we ask what can happen for a xed information structure... nformation

More information

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe Fall 2010 Contents 1 Motivation 2 2 The Krugman and Venables (1995) model 2 2.1 Key assumptions...................................

More information

Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing

Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing Competition for Exclusive Customers: Comparing Equilibrium and Welfare under One-Part and Two-Part Pricing James D. Reitzes y Glenn A. Woroch z October 2006 Abstract This paper compares one-part pricing

More information

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1 EconS 305 - Competitive Markets Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu October 11, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 19 October 11, 2015 1 / 48 Introduction Today,

More information

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly

The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly The Welfare E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in a Di erentiated Oligopoly Takanori Adachi School of Economics Nagoya University Noriaki Matsushima ISER Osaka University November 17, 2010 2 1.

More information

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

EconS Monopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Monopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu October 26, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 24 October 26, 2015 1 / 47 Introduction Last time, we

More information

Consumer Search and Dynamic Price Dispersion: An Application to Gasoline Markets

Consumer Search and Dynamic Price Dispersion: An Application to Gasoline Markets Consumer Search and Dynamic Price Dispersion: An Application to Gasoline Markets Ambarish Chandra Mariano Tappata y July 7, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the role of imperfect information in explaining

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy

More information

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy Arastou KHATIBI and Wouter VERGOTE y August 009 Abstract When selling their products domestically or internationally rms rely on more than just the price as a strategic

More information

Harvard University Department of Economics

Harvard University Department of Economics Harvard University Department of Economics General Examination in Microeconomic Theory Spring 00. You have FOUR hours. Part A: 55 minutes Part B: 55 minutes Part C: 60 minutes Part D: 70 minutes. Answer

More information

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture nformation Design: Murat Sertel Lecture stanbul Bilgi University: Conference on Economic Design Stephen Morris July 2015 Mechanism Design and nformation Design Mechanism Design: Fix an economic environment

More information

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006 Problem 1. Shorter problems. (35 points) Solve the following shorter problems. 1. Consider the following (simultaneous) game of chicken. This is a game in

More information

Advertising Competition in Retail Markets

Advertising Competition in Retail Markets Singapore Management University Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University Research Collection School of Economics School of Economics 3-2010 Advertising Competition in Retail Markets Kyle

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 19, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 31 November 19, 2015 1 / 32 Introduction We are now

More information

A Simple Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Allocation of the Commons

A Simple Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Allocation of the Commons A Simple Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Allocation of the Commons Juan-Pablo Montero AER 2008, 98:1, 496 518 Juan-Pablo Montero () AER 2008, 98:1, 496 518 1 / 16 Introduction Regulatory authorities

More information

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 School of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003 1. Strategic Interaction and Oligopoly

More information

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS*

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 0022-1821 Volume XLVIII December 2000 No. 4 INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* Joseph Farrell{ and Michael L. Katz{ We consider innovation

More information

Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information. about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García

Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information. about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García Price setting in a differentiated-product duopoly with asymmetric information about demand * Miguel Ángel Ropero García Department of Applied Economics University of Malaga El Ejido 6, 29071 Malaga Spain

More information

EconS Endogenous Market Size

EconS Endogenous Market Size EconS 425 - Endogenous Market Size Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 35 Introduction Let s contrinue

More information

EconS Asymmetric Information

EconS Asymmetric Information cons 425 - Asymmetric Information ric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization ric Dunaway (WSU) cons 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 45 Introduction Today, we are

More information

Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Discriminating Against Captive Customers Mark Armstrong, John Vickers Number 858 October, 2018 Department of Economics Manor Road Building, Manor Road Oxford,

More information

Advertising and Collusion in Retails Markets

Advertising and Collusion in Retails Markets Advertising and Collusion in Retails Markets Gea Myoung Lee, Kyle Bagwell March 2008 Paper No. 09-2008 ANY OPINIONS EXPRESSED ARE THOSE OF THE AUTHOR(S) AND NOT NECESSARILY THOSE OF THE SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS,

More information

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - First-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41 Introduction

More information

A Reversal of the Green Paradox: The Anticipatory E ects of Taxation

A Reversal of the Green Paradox: The Anticipatory E ects of Taxation A Reversal of the Green Paradox: The Anticipatory E ects of Taxation Ana Espinola-Arredondo, Félix Muñoz-García y, and Isaac Duah z School of Economic Sciences Washington State University Pullman, WA 99164

More information

Discriminating Against Captive Customers

Discriminating Against Captive Customers MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Discriminating Against Captive Customers Mark Armstrong and John Vickers University of Oxford October 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/89284/ MPRA Paper

More information

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - Second-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 46 Introduction

More information

AN ASCENDING AUCTION FOR INTERDEPENDENT VALUES: UNIQUENESS AND ROBUSTNESS TO STRATEGIC UNCERTAINTY. Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris

AN ASCENDING AUCTION FOR INTERDEPENDENT VALUES: UNIQUENESS AND ROBUSTNESS TO STRATEGIC UNCERTAINTY. Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris AN ASCENDING AUCTION FOR INTERDEPENDENT VALUES: UNIQUENESS AND ROBUSTNESS TO STRATEGIC UNCERTAINTY By Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris January 27 Updated March 27 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

More information

GAME THEORY: Analysis of Strategic Thinking Exercises on Repeated and Bargaining Games

GAME THEORY: Analysis of Strategic Thinking Exercises on Repeated and Bargaining Games GAME THEORY: Analysis of Strategic Thinking Exercises on Repeated and Bargaining Games Pierpaolo Battigalli Università Bocconi A.Y. 2006-2007 Exercise 1. Consider the following Prisoner s Dilemma game.

More information

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits by Fan Li* Abstract Many software and video game firms offer a free demo with limited content to help buyers better assess the likely value

More information

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors. Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors. Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin 0 TITLE: Intensity of Competition and the Number of Competitors 0 RSMG Working Paper Series Authors: Flavio M. Menezes & John Quiggin Schools of Economics and Political Science The University of Queensland

More information

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

Competition in Two-Sided Markets Competition in Two-Sided Markets Mark Armstrong Department of Economics University College London August 2002: revised May 2005 Abstract There are many examples of markets involving two groups of agents

More information

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers EC 36 - Lecture 11&1 Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers What are vertical restraints? In most markets producers do not sell directly to consumers but to retailers who then sell to consumers. Some

More information

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION THE JOURNAL O INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 00-181 Volume LVII June 009 No. Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/ PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION LEVENT KUTLU

More information

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation Roman Inderst y Zlata Jakubovic z Dragan Jovanovic x November 2013 Abstract Our analysis starts from the observation that with progressive consolidation

More information

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics Área Científica de Economia E/nº 4/007 Discriminatory Limit

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Information, Search, and Price Dispersion

Information, Search, and Price Dispersion Information, Search, and Price Dispersion Michael R. Baye Kelley School of Business Indiana University John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

More information

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012.

A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET. April 2012. 1 A COMPARISON OF THE COURNOT AND STACKELBERG COMPETITION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION MARKET April 2012 Bralind Kiri bralind.kiri@gmail.com PhD Student, Department of Economic Theory and

More information

On Quantity Competition and Transmission Constraints in Electricity Market

On Quantity Competition and Transmission Constraints in Electricity Market On Quantity Competition and Transmission Constraints in Electricity Market Daniel A. Benitez y March 12, 2004 (Work in Progress) Abstract In this paper we characterize equilibria in a quantity game where

More information

Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1

Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1 Mixed oligopoly equilibria when rms objectives are endogenous 1 Philippe De Donder Toulouse School of Economics (IDEI and GREMAQ-CNRS) John E. Roemer Yale University First version: September 2006 This

More information

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices

Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Rationing Poor Consumers to Reduce Prices Simona Grassi Ching-to Albert Ma Max Weber Fellow Department of Economics European University Institute Boston University Villa La Fonte, Via Delle Fontanelle,

More information

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

EconS Monopoly - Part 1 EconS 305 - Monopoly - Part 1 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu October 23, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 23 October 23, 2015 1 / 50 Introduction For the rest

More information

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text. 1 Applying the Competitive Model The focus of this chapter is welfare economics. Note that "welfare" has a much di erent meaning in economics

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Bundling and Foreclosure Tina Kao Australian National University Flavio Menezes University of Queensland September 29, 2006

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

IO Experiments. Given that the experiment was conducted at a sportscard show, the sequence of events to participate in the experiment are discussed.

IO Experiments. Given that the experiment was conducted at a sportscard show, the sequence of events to participate in the experiment are discussed. IO Experiments 1 Introduction Some of the earliest experiments have focused on how di erent market institutions a ect price and quantity outcomes. For instance, Smith s 1962 paper is a response to Chamberlain

More information

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist University of California, Davis Department of Economics Time: 3 hours Reading time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Industrial Organization June 27, 2006 Answer four of the six

More information

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly Lin Liu Marshal School of Management University of Southern California X. Henry Wang Department of Economics University of Missouri-Columbia and Bill

More information