Elections at what cost? The impact of electricity subsidies on groundwater extraction and agricultural production DRAFT

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Elections at what cost? The impact of electricity subsidies on groundwater extraction and agricultural production DRAFT"

Transcription

1 Elections at what cost? The impact of electricity subsidies on groundwater extraction and agricultural production DRAFT Reena Badiani Katrina K. Jessoe January 23, 2011 Abstract In India, electric utilities are owned and operated by the government. This paper explores whether these utilities have functioned to maximize social welfare and whether electricity pricing, through the provision of agricultural subsidies, has been manipulated for political purposes. We first explore the benefits of electricity subsidies to the agricultural sector between 1995 and A simple model predicts that electricity subsidies lower the price of groundwater extraction and, in turn, increase agricultural revenues. To isolate the impact of electricity prices on groundwater extraction and revenues, we exploit year-to-year variation in state electricity prices across districts that differ in hydrogeological characteristics. We find that a 10 percent decrease in subsidies would reduce groundwater extraction by 5.4 percent, costing farmers 12 percent in agricultural revenues. Despite the gains in agricultural revenue, the short-run costs of these subsidies exceed the short-run benefits six-fold, suggesting another rationale for the subsidies. Political capture partly explains the persistence of these subsidies, which have historically increased by 10% in the year preceding an election. World Bank Dept. of Agricultural and Resource Economics, UC Davis Corresponding author kkjessoe@ucdavis.edu; phone:(530) This has been funded in part by the United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) under the Science to Achieve Results (STAR) Graduate Fellowship Program (FP ), the Heinz Fellowship for Environmental Scholars and the V. Kann Rasmussen Foundation grant. The authors, alone, are responsible for any errors. 1

2 1 Introduction As environmental and energy infrastructure in developing countries expands, governments need to consider how to best regulate markets characterized as natural monopolies such as the supply of clean water, sanitation and electricity. With natural monopolies, governments face a dilemma - how to supply a good at least cost while avoiding monopoly pricing? In the U.S., the government has taken a variety of regulatory approaches. It has allowed private firms the opportunity to bid on the rights to the monopoly, regulated the return that a natural monopoly can make on capital, or provided the good itself through an enterprise owned and operated by the government. In the U.S., electricity - the good of interest in this study - is most often privately provided. By contrast in India, the setting for this research, electricity is provided by public enterprise in the form of State Electricity Boards. Public provision of electricity may better achieve the objective of social welfare maximization as compared to a private firm that seeks to maximize profits. However, it is susceptible to political capture (Vickers and Yarrow 1991) since the managers of the State Electricity Boards are accountable to state elected officials who are in turn accountable to voters. This paper tests the compatibility of public enterprise as an approach to manage the provision of electricity in developing countries, examining the extent to which current agricultural electricity markets in India function to maximize social welfare and whether they are susceptible to political pressure. Previous literature has evaluated the comparative performance of public and private enterprise in developed (Vickers and Yarrow 1991) and developing countries (Estache and Wren-Lewis 2009), finding mixed evidence as to whether the privatization of natural monopolies improved efficiency. In developed countries, the lack of consensus in these studies can be largely explained by differences in regulatory policy. In developing countries, regulatory policy and the institutional framework, rather than the form of ownership, largely determine the relative performance of private and public enterprise (Estache and Wren-Lewis 2009). These findings are primarily theoretical or anecdotal, and when empirical have focused on water utilities (Clarke et al. 2009, Estache and Rossi 2002, Galiani et al. 2005, Kirkpatrick et al. 2006). 1 With a few exceptions (Cubbin and Stern 2006, Hawdon 1996, Zhang et al. 2008), little attention has been paid to the electricity sector. Electricity in India provides an ideal setting to measure the benefits from the public provision of electricity and to test if this market is captured by political interests. In India, many attribute the poor and unreliable electricity service supplied by the State 1 A literature exists on telecommunications privatization, though our focus of this study is on energy and environmental infrastructure. 2

3 Electricity Boards (SEBs) to electricity subsidies for agriculture. Subsidies to the agricultural sector are large - Birner et al (2007) present evidence suggesting that the amount spent on agricultural electricity subsidies exceeds state spending on health or education if two states in India. The long-run costs of electricity subsidies have been widely documented, and the need for an overhaul and restructuring of the state electricity boards has been advocated by the Indian government itself (Dubash and Rajan 2001, Dubash 2007). The annual commercial losses from SEBs are large in magnitude and growing - in 2001 the SEBs rate of return on capital amounted to -39.5% (Tongia, 2003). This negative profit was largely fueled by increased expenditure on agricultural electricity subsidies and a decline in the cross-subsidies provided by the commercial and industrial sectors. 2 Though SEBs have been operating at a loss and the quality of electricity continues to worsen, these subsidies remain in-tact. This paper examines the rationale behind this persistence by first investigating the agricultural benefits from these subsidies to determine if the short-run benefits of these subsidies dominate the short-run costs. It then evaluates the political capture attained by these subsidies. Anecdotal evidence suggests that these subsidies are not without their benefits. The expansion and uptake of tube wells for irrigation was largely expedited by subsidized electricity prices, which reduced the price of groundwater extraction. In turn, this growth in irrigation increased agricultural yields, lowered food prices, increased demand for agricultural labor and disproportionately benefited landless farmers (Briscoe and Malik 2006, Modi 2005). However, these benefits may have come at the cost of groundwater exploitation (Strand 2010). India has increasingly relied on groundwater extraction for agriculture and is currently the largest extractor of groundwater, consuming 250 cubic km of groundwater annually. demand for groundwater increases, extraction in some districts has begun to exceed the replenishable supply. Between 2002 and 2004, the percentage of districts reporting exploited groundwater resources increased from 8% to 17%. 3 In this paper, we examine the impact of agricultural electricity subsidies on groundwater usage and exploitation, and the subsequent effect of these subsidies on agricultural production, using panel data from 350 districts (the U.S. equivalent of a county) between 1995 and We exploit variation in electricity prices over time and across states (the U.S. equivalent of a state). In India, state governments are authorized to set electricity prices, therefore electricity prices vary across states. There is also substantial heterogeneity in prices 2 To fund these subsidies, states charged higher prices to the industrial and commercial sectors, where the prices charged often exceeded the marginal cost of supply. This increase in production costs, encouraged the use of captive power plants by commercial and industry sectors, thereby lowering the base from which the SEBs funded these subsidies. 3 According to the Central Ground Water Board of India, mining/over-extraction occurs when annual extraction of groundwater exceeds annual recharge. As 3

4 across time; this occurs because states respond to economic and political pressures by changing agricultural electricity subsidies. In our empirical model, we use within state variation in electricity prices between 1995 and 2004 to estimate the short-run effect of agricultural electricity subsidies on district groundwater extraction and agricultural output. Preliminary results from an OLS model with district fixed effects suggest that electricity subsidies led to an increase in groundwater extraction and an increase in crop revenues. Since electricity prices are likely to be correlated with unobservables such as the political party in power or the relative importance of the agricultural sector, we are concerned that exploiting variation of electricity prices across states and time will yield biased estimates. To isolate the effect of electricity prices on groundwater extraction and agricultural output, we turn to hydrology literature to construct a measure for the effective price of groundwater (Domenico et al. 1968, Martin and Archer 1971). Our identification strategy isolates the differential effect of electricity subsidies on districts characterized by different effective groundwater prices. To measure the price of groundwater, we use two fixed district hydrological characteristics - the minimum and maximum depth to the aquifer. This strategy allows us to estimate a model that controls for both district unobservables (soil type) and time-variant state unobservables (other agricultural subsidies). While this model does not quantify the direct effect of state electricity prices on groundwater extraction, it estimates the effect of a related price, the interaction of aquifer depth and electricity price, on groundwater extraction. In the hydrology literature, the price of groundwater extraction is measured as this interaction term. Consistent with the predictions from our theoretical model, our results indicate that electricity subsidies increased groundwater extraction and agricultural revenues. We find that a 25 percent increase in electricity prices generates a 2.2 percent decrease in groundwater extraction and a 4.9 percent reduction in agricultural revenues, where this reduction in revenues is not driven by changes in crop price, but by changes in the quantity produced. Though electricity subsidies increased agricultural revenues, we find that the short-run costs of these subsidies exceed the annual benefits. If we reduced the average subsidy by 10 percent, we predict that district agricultural revenues would decrease by 33.5 million Rupees annually. However, average government expenditure on district subsidies would reduce by 185 Rs annually. A simple back of the envelope calculation reveals that the short-run costs of these subsidies outweigh the benefits by more than six-fold. Further, the cost of these subsidies would likely increase if we considered the linkages between these subsidies and the future costs of groundwater exploitation. Despite the cost of these subsidies, they endure. We now explore the political economy behind the persistence of these subsidies. In particular, do state politicians manipulate agri- 4

5 cultural electricity prices to gain electoral votes? A suite of studies has empirically examined the relationship between elections and agricultural lending by publicly owned banks, expenditure on road construction and tax collection in India to investigate hypotheses about the political capture of publicly owned goods (Cole 2009, Chaudhuri and Dasgupta 2005, Ghosh 2006, Khemani 2004). These studies find that funding for road construction and agricultural loans provided by publicly owned banks increased during election years, suggesting that political capture partly explains the provision of these goods. Our research contributes to this literature, finding that politicians may be trying to gain votes by manipulating electricity prices. In the year preceding a pre-scheduled election, electricity prices reduce by roughly 1.4 paise or 10%, controlling for district and year unobservables. 4 This is a substantial decrease, given that the mean electricity price is 14 paise per kwh over this period. We posit that electricity subsidies provide substantial gains to politicians, since they give politicians a means to increase rural incomes, and hence support, during elections. 2 Background to the Electricity Sector and Subsidies Prior to 1948, private entities and local authorities generated approximately 80 percent of electricity in India (Dubash and Rajan 2001). With the Electricity Supply Act of 1948, states gained control over electricity generation and each state organized a vertically integrated State Electricity Board (SEB). Though jurisdiction over electricity is shared between the central and state governments, SEBs function as autonomous institutions. They have the authority to set and collect electricity tariffs, and are responsible for the three core elements of electricity provision - generation, transmission and distribution. While SEBs have the authority to price electricity, electricity pricing has often been at the discretion of the state government and politicians rather than the SEBs (Gulati and Narayanan, 2003). Electricity pricing, or lack thereof, emerged as a powerful political tool in the late 1970s during the post green revolution period. As agricultural profits and the need for a stable water supply increased during the green revolution, the farming workforce organized into a powerful political coalition. The trend between elections and electricity pricing began in Andhra Pradesh in 1977, when the Congress party was the first in India to campaign on the basis of free power. By 1989, the government was spending 25 percent of total expenditure on agricultural electricity subsidies, and politicians were required to maintain these subsidies to either gain election or remain in power (Dubash and Rajan 2001). For example in 2004, the Congress Party on Andhra Pradesh campaigned on free power (Dubash 2007). 5 4 One hundred paise equal one Rupee. 5 In states where the commercial and industrial sectors comprise the influential and dominant political lob- 5

6 The electricity pricing strategies of SEBs have been linked to a number of negative features of the electricity sector. Many SEBs were not reimbursed by the state for the agricultural subsidies. Second, SEBs engaged in a system of cross-subsidization, whereby commercial and industrial users were charged high rates partly to cover the losses. Despite raising tariffs for these users, SEBs faced growing theft and financial losses which has been argued to have contributed to low frequency, brownouts and blackouts (Dubash and Rajan 2004; McKenzie and Ray 2004). Beginning in the early 1990s, state governments passed a series of electricity reforms intended to introduce competition and to reduce the role of the state in the electricity sector. On the distribution side, these reforms however have had limited, if any, success during the time period examined in this paper, 1995 to Although the government implemented multiple reforms during this period that were aimed at increasing competition in the electricity sector, these bills had relatively little impact on distribution and tariff setting in the electricity sector. By contrast, there has been greater progress in opening up generation and transmission to private sector competition. At the national level, the earliest attempts to reform the sector focused on meeting the shortfall in generating capacity. The Electricity Laws (Amendment) Act of 1991 changed the 1948 Electricity (Supply) Act to allow private generators into the market with their tariffs regulated by the government. This reform was largely unsuccessful in attracting new entrants, due in part to strong safeguard policies. Since the passage of this act, growth in public sector capacity has been more than double generation growth in the private sector (Tongia, 2004). State governments, in collaboration with the World Bank, also introduced legislation that aimed to separate the vertically integrated SEBs into generation, distribution and transmission companies. These reforms were first implemented, in collaboration with the World Bank, in the state of Orissa beginning in By 1998, the reforms had separated the Orissa State Electricity Board into two generation companies, one transmission enterprise and four distribution companies. Part of the agreement with the World Bank included the reform of tariffs to allow suppliers to become financially solvent. However, the government slowed down the rise in tariffs through negotiations with the Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission (Toniga, 2004). bies, politicians follow a reverse campaign strategy. Politicians promise to reduce or eliminate the electricity subsidies provided to farmers. 6

7 3 Theoretical Model This section presents an agricultural production model, which draws heavily on Provencher and Burt (1993). The economy examined is a rural economy with many identical farmers, who choose water inputs and the fraction of their land to plant with water intensive crops. The farmers draw water using electric pumps from a common stock of replenishable groundwater. The model makes predictions on how variation in electricity subsidy feeds through to the price of electricity facing farmers, thus affecting groundwater usage and the water intensity of crop choice. 3.1 Groundwater The economy consists of N identical farmers who have access to the groundwater stock in district d. The total groundwater stock at the end of time t is given by x dt. In every time period, the groundwater resource is recharged r units. An individual farmer chooses to consume u t units of groundwater. We assume that irrigation water does not leak back into the groundwater resources. Since farmers are identical, their groundwater use in every period is the same. Therefore, the stock of groundwater available for use in period t + 1 is given by: x t+1 = x t Nu t + r (1) 3.2 Farmer - Individual Profit Maximization Each of the N identical farmers is endowed with A units of land. The agricultural sector uses two inputs in production - land and water - to produce two crops, crop 1 and crop 2. Land and water are complements in production. Production of both crops is modeled using a Cobb-Douglas technology, which is increasing and concave in all inputs and the crops vary in the output shares of inputs. Therefore when faced with the same vector of input prices, the optimal input choices for the two crops will differ. The cost of extracting groundwater, conditional upon each farmer owning a well, reflects multiple factors. First, electricity is used to pump water from the groundwater stock. The marginal cost of a unit of electricity is given by p w. The farmer faces a subsidized groundwater price, p w, where p w = p w s. Furthermore, the per unit cost of extracting electricity - c(x t ) - is convex in the stock of groundwater. The greater the stock, the lower the cost of pumping groundwater: c/ x < 0. Conceptually, a decline in the stock of groundwater in a given groundwater basin will result in a decline in the water table as well as a decline in water 7

8 pressure, raising the cost of pumping water. Landowners choose the fraction of land and water inputs they will devote to each crop in order to maximize profits, given the input and output prices they face: Π(A) = max A1,w 1,w 2 p 1 F 1 (u t ξ, A 1 ) + p 2 F 2 (u t (1 ξ), A A 1 ) p w c(x t )u t = p 1 (u t ξ) α A β 1 + p 2 u t (1 ξ) γ (A A 1 ) δ p w c(x t )u t Crop 1 is more water-intensive than crop 2: α > γ, and α+β 1, δ +γ 1. In addition, assume for simplicity that α + β = δ + γ. Since drawing water in period t will affect the stock of water available to be drawn in period t + 1, the farmer faces the following dynamic problem: v(x t ) = max ut,ξ,a1 [p 1 (u t ξ) α A β 1 + p 2 (u t (1 ξ)) γ (A A 1 ) δ p w c(x t )u t (2) +βv(x t (N 1)u (x t ) u t + r)] s.t. x t (N 1)u (x t ) u t 0 where β represents the discount factor and v(x t ) is the present value from agricultural production over an infinite planning horizon when the initial state is x t. The dynamic problem is subject to an inequality constraint, which restricts the farmers groundwater consumption in the current period to less than or equal to the total groundwater stock available today. Maximizing the equation above with respect to u t yields the following first order conditions: The corresponding Lagrangian expression to the maximization above is given by: v(x t ) = max ut,ξ,a1 [p 1 (u t ξ) α A β 1 + p 2 (u t (1 ξ)) γ (A A 1 ) δ p w c(x t )u t (3) +βv(x t (N 1)u (x t ) u t + r)] + λ t (x t (N 1)u (x t ) u t ) F 1 + F 2 c(x t ) p w λ t = β v t+1 u t u t x t+1 (4) λ t (x t (N 1)u t (x t ) u t ) = 0 (5) The final term, β v t+1 x t+1 represents the private opportunity cost of current groundwater extraction, since consuming water in the current period reduces the groundwater stock available for future consumption. Therefore the marginal product of water lies above the current marginal cost of water due to the private inter-temporal opportunity cost. The farmer chooses to allocate water across crops by equating the marginal product of 8

9 water across crops: F 1 ξ = F 2 ξ (6) Finally, the farmer chooses the amount of land to devote to each crop in order to equalize the marginal product of land: A β 1 1 F 1 A 1 = F 2 A 1 = δp 2u γ α t (1 ξ) γ (A A 1 ) δ 1 βp 1 ξ α Note that water consumption is greater when farmers are individually optimizing than when optimization occurs at the community level. This is because users only take into account the private costs associated with groundwater pumping. However, the individual fails to consider the costs of their private groundwater consumption on the community. The first arises because groundwater consumption in period t makes the stock constraint more costly in period t + 1. The second arises because groundwater consumption in period t increases the cost of pumping water in period t + 1, since it increases the depth from which groundwater must be pumped. Therefore the socially optimal individual groundwater use is less than the privately optimal groundwater use. These results are discussed in greater depth in Provencher and Burt (1993). 3.3 Testable Predictions 1. The total water used increases as the price of groundwater decreases, i.e. as the groundwater subsidy increases:. 2.1 The fraction of land and water devoted to the water intensive crop increases as the price of water decreases, i.e. as the subsidy increases: since α > γ, A 1 ξ p w < 0, while (A A 1) p w > 0 and (1 ξ) p w > 0 p w < 0 and 2.2 Total agricultural production increases as the subsidy increases, i.e. as the effective price of groundwater decreases. Production of the water intensive crop increases by more than production of the non-water intensive crop. 3. Increasing total water consumption beyond the replenishable recharge reduces the groundwater stock available for future use and decreases future profits, through increas- 9

10 ing the cost of groundwater extraction as well as reducing water inputs. 4 Estimation strategy In this section, we put forward a strategy used to test the predictions of the model. In this draft of the paper, we focus on the static predictions of the model. Future drafts of the paper will examine both the static and dynamic predictions of the model. Prediction 1 states that the total groundwater consumed rises as the price of electricity falls. A first strategy is to estimate this using a simple OLS model: Q d it = β 0 + β 1 R it + β 2 p E jt + β 3 X it + λ t + γ j + u it. (7) Groundwater consumption, Q d it, is a continuous variable defined as the quantity (million cubic meters (mcm)) of groundwater extracted in district i and year t. We control for groundwater capacity by including the annual replenishable supply of groundwater in district i and year t, R it, where the replenishable supply varies annually depending on rainfall. Since our measure of capacity is restricted to the replenishable quantity of groundwater, it is exogenous to annual groundwater demand. The price of electricity in state j and year t is denoted by p E jt. The amount of rainfall in district i and year t and whether rainfall is reported is captured in X it. Year dummies control for any trend in groundwater extraction over time. The error structure includes γ j, a district fixed effect, and u it, an idiosyncratic error term. Standard errors are clustered at the district level. Since, at any given electricity price, the quantity of electricity supplied is often constrained below demand in India, this implies that the price of electricity may not be a sufficient statistic to capture how subsidies affect groundwater demand. The state governments may also alter electricity provision through other channels, such as via increasing generation (the average load factor in India in 2001 was 72%) or via turning a blind eye to thefts. We therefore estimate the effect of other electricity measures that may affect groundwater extraction including generation and transmission and distribution losses. Identification of the effect of these other electricity measures on district groundwater demand comes from state-year variation in electricity prices controlling for time-invariant district unobservables and year shocks. Since all districts in a state face the same electricity prices, electricity prices will not differ across districts within a state. The same does not hold true for the other electricity measures. Capacity, generation, and transmission and distribution losses 10

11 may differ across districts within a state if politicians or the state electricity boards selectively allocate these subsidies to preferred or disadvantaged districts. Because of this, coefficient estimates on generation, capacity, and transmission and distribution losses may suffer from omitted variables bias. In a final specification for groundwater demand, we estimate equation (7) conditional on generation, capacity, and transmission and distribution, allowing us to test whether the effect of electricity prices on groundwater demand is robust to the inclusion of other subsidies. To test the effect of electricity subsidies on agricultural production and crops sown, we estimate a variation of equation 7, V it = β 0 + β 1 R it + β 2 p E jt + β 3 X it + λ t + γ j + u it. (8) In a first model, V it denotes the value of agricultural output, measured as the sum over all crops in a district-year of crop-specific revenues. In other models, the dependent variable reflects the district market price of a crop grown in year t. The crops used in the analysis include cotton, rice, sugar, wheat, sorghum and millet, where the first three crops describe water intensive crops and the latter three crops describe non-water intensive crops. 4.1 Incorporating hydrology Our current specification will generate biased coefficient estimates of the effect of electricity prices on groundwater extraction, β 2, since electricity prices are likely to be correlated with unobservables such as the political party in power, the state s agricultural economy and the weight placed on agricultural welfare in the social planner s utility function. To identify the effect of electricity subsidies on groundwater extraction, we turn to the water resources literature to construct a measure for the price of groundwater extraction. The price of groundwater extraction depends on electricity prices, the depth to the aquifer and the interaction of these two variables. The water resources literature uses the latter variable, the interaction of electricity prices and depth to the water table, to measure the price of groundwater (Domenico et al. 1968, Miller and Archer 1971). Borrowing from this literature, we estimate a variation of equation 7 in which we interact electricity prices with groundwater characteristics: Q d it = α 0 + α 1 R it + α 2 R it p E jt + α 3 p GW min i GW max p E jt + α 4 pi p E jt + α 5 X it + λ jt + γ i + u it. (9) The variables p GW min and p GW max describe fixed district hydrological characteristics that 11

12 measure the price to access a unit of groundwater. The first variable measures the minimum depth one would need to drill to reach the aquifer. This variable does not describe the depth to the water table; rather it captures the hydrogeology of the district. Regardless of whether the water table increases or decreases, one would need to drill to this minimum depth to reach the aquifer. The second hydrological characteristic p GW max describes the maximum depth of the aquifer. When combined with minimum well depth, this variable measures the size of the aquifer (i.e. how much the aquifer can hold). If we think about p GW min as the depth to the aquifer and p GW max as the size of the aquifer, then we can characterize R it as the quantity of water that replenishes or fills this aquifer annually. We include interactions of electricity prices and each groundwater variable in our estimating equation. In this model, we continue to control for the replenishable supply of groundwater, rainfall and time invariant district unobservables. We also include state-year fixed effects that control for shocks common to all districts within a state such as electricity prices or state government elections. The coefficient of interest, α 3, will capture the differential effect of changes in electricity prices in a single state year on two districts which differ in their aquifer depths, controlling for fixed district characteristics. We predict that an increase in electricity prices should decrease demand for groundwater relatively more in districts with deeper minimum well depths (i.e. higher groundwater prices). This identification strategy assumes that the differential effect of a change in electricity prices across two districts with different hydrological characteristics will be uncorrelated with district unobservables that vary over time, such as development assistance programs. We test for the robustness of our results to these channels. 5 Data This paper uses four main sources of data: district groundwater data collected by the Central Groundwater Board, state assembly election data compiled by the Election Commission of India, annual state electricity price and generation data collected by the Power and Energy Division of the Planning Commission and agricultural data compiled by the Directorate of Economics and Statistics within the Indian Ministry of Agriculture. 5.1 Groundwater Data District groundwater data (where the U.S. equivalent of a district is a county) on extraction and recharge from 2004 were provided for 350 districts from 15 states. Obtaining data on groundwater has been our greatest constraint - groundwater assessments are expensive and 12

13 difficult to undertake and are therefore rarely conducted. We form an unbalanced panel of groundwater data for these districts using groundwater data from 331 districts in 1995, 19 districts in 1997, 31 districts in 1998, 197 districts in 2002 and 350 districts in Summary statistics on groundwater demand, the replenishable supply, groundwater development and exploitation are provided in Table 1. In 1998, average district consumption in Madhya Pradesh accounts for 60 percent of the annual replenishable supply and over-exploitation of groundwater occurs in 23 percent of the state s districts. 6 In 2002, average district consumption amounted to 59 percent of the annual replenishable groundwater supply. In 38 percent of the 170 districts, groundwater consumption exceeds the replenishable supply. In the 2004 data, average district consumption amounts to 64 percent of the replenishable groundwater supply and 17 percent of the 204 districts are classified as over-exploited. Between 2002 and 2004, groundwater development increased by 15 percent and the number of exploited districts grew by 10 percent (panel data is available for 169 districts). Data collected in 2002 by the Central Groundwater Board of India (CGWB) spatially characterize fixed hydrogeological characteristics in the states of Bihar, Uttar Pradesh, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu and Rajasthan. Variation in groundwater characteristics is at the district level, where the minimum and maximum depth to the aquifer are calculated as the district mean. 5.2 Election Data Data on elections were gathered from the Election Commission of India. There are two types of state elections in India, midterm and scheduled elections. Constitutionally scheduled elections are held every 5 years after the last election. Midterm elections occur when the lower parliament declares the state government incapable of ruling its constituent. Since the frequency and timing of midterm elections varies by state, there is substantial variation in pre-scheduled electoral cycles by state. We observe that the majority of midterm elections occurred during the politically turbulent 1970s. The fraction of states holding an election in 1995, 1997, 2002 and 2004 is shown in Table 2. In these years, the majority of elections were scheduled elections. 6 The annual replenishable groundwater resource is calculated as the sum of monsoon and non-monsoon recharge. 13

14 5.3 Electricity data Electricity data were gathered from three primary sources: The Annual Report on the Working of State Electricity Boards and Electricity Departments published by the Power and Energy Division of the Planning Commission between 1992 and 2002, multiple volumes of Average Electric Rates and Duties in India published by the Central Electricity Authority and multiple volumes of Energy, a publication by the Center for Monitoring the Indian Economy in India. Data on states electricity prices, measured in 1986 paise per kilowatt hour (paise/kwh), were collected for the period The electricity prices captured are average tariffs, measured as the revenues from sale to particular sectors divided by the units sold. Trends in agricultural electricity prices are displayed in Figures 1 and 2. Figure 1 illustrates mean electricity prices over time, showing that between 1995 and 2004 prices have ranged from 9.6 to 20.6 paise. In addition to variation in electricity prices over time, electricity prices also vary across states. The mean electricity price in each state significantly differs from mean electricity prices in at least two other states. In Figure 2, electricity prices are disaggregated by state for a subsample of states. With the exception of Tamil Nadu, prices significantly differ within a state over time. In India, electricity prices also vary by sector with industrial and commercial users paying higher fees. The mean electricity price for agriculture in our sample was 14.7 paise as compared to 103 paise for industrial users. Table 3 presents descriptive statistics on electricity during the period. Generation and total capacity are captured at a state level and are measured in millions of kw hours. While both generation and capacity have increased substantially during the period, evidence suggests that generation has not increased in line with demand (Tongia, 2004). Transmissions and distribution losses, which reflect both losses due to both technical reasons and theft, have risen substantially over the period examined. The unit cost to supply electricity represents the cost incurred by the utility to supply a unit of electricity to consumers. The components considered for calculations include the cost of fuel, operations and maintenance expenditure, establishment and administration cost, interest payment liability, depreciation and the cost of power purchase. The subsidy to agricultural users can be backed out by examining the difference between unit costs and the tariff paid by agricultural users. The subsidy to the agricultural sector increases over the period, from approximately 60 paise per kilowatt hour, to over 80 paise. The subsidy account for approximately 87% of the cost of electricity - on average, the price faced by agricultural users is 13% of the cost of electricity. 14

15 5.4 Agricultural production data District-year level data on agricultural yields comes from two publications at the Ministry of Agriculture - the Agricultural Situation in India and the Area and Production of Principal Crops in India. In order to decouple the effects of price changes from output changes, we create a Lespeyres volume index of total, water and non-water intensive output using average 1995 prices. Prices were taken from Agricultural Prices in India. Agricultural data include agricultural production in a district-year and whether or not a crop is grown in a district-year. Data are available for 1995, 1997, 2002 and Total agricultural production is measured as the sum of production in wheat, rice, cotton, sugar, sorghum, and millet, weighted by the average 1995 market price of these crops. These six crops were chosen due to the widespread availability of data on these crops during the period examined and their prevalence across India. Water-intensive output is measured as the weighted sum of production in sugar, rice and cotton. Rice is grown in 76 percent of the district-years, sugar is grown in 63 percent of the district-years while cotton is grown in 48 percent of the district-years. Sorghum, wheat and millet are defined as non-water intensive crops. Wheat, sorghum and millet were grown in 55, 40 and 38% percent of districts in 1995, respectively. The water intensity of these crops was defined according to their relative levels of water usage, as defined by the FAO. In 1995, 61% of total production was attributable to water intensive crops. 6 Results Table 4 reports results from the estimation of equation 7, an OLS model of demand for groundwater. Identification in the model comes from state-year shocks in electricity prices, generation, capacity and, transmission and distribution losses, controlling for fixed district unobservables. We report results for the effect of electricity prices on groundwater extraction in column 1. Results for the impact of generation, capacity and T&D losses on groundwater extraction are presented in columns 2-4, though we are cautious in interpreting these results due to omitted variables bias. 7. We also look at the effect of electricity prices on groundwater extraction conditional on generation, capacity and transmission and distribution losses (column 5). We find that on average district demand for groundwater decreases by 3.3 million cubic meters with with a 1 paise increase in the price of electricity. Our results suggest that a 25 percent increase in the agricultural price of electricity, where the mean price of electricity is 7 We are currently investigating whether district year data on generation, capacity and transmission and distribution losses exists. 15

16 12.16 paise/kwh, will reduce mean groundwater demand by 10 mcm or roughly 1.9 percent. If electricity subsidies were reduced by 10%, where the average subsidy over the duration of the study amounted to 85 paise/kwh, demand for groundwater would decrease by 4.7 percent. It should be noted that while these results suggest a price inelastic demand for groundwater, the source of variation exploited imply that the estimates capture only a shortrun elasticity of demand. In the long-term as the area and the crops cultivated responds to changes in the price of groundwater, the demand response is likely to be greater. When we estimate the effect of one type of electricity subsidy on groundwater extraction, our results suggest that capacity, generation and electricity prices are each significant in explaining district demand for groundwater. Once we condition each electricity subsidy on the other electricity subsidies, electricity price is the only subsidy that significantly impacts groundwater extraction. Conditional on other electricity subsidies, a 1 paise increase in electricity prices is predicted to decrease groundwater extraction by 3.5 million cubic meters. This result mirrors that reported in column 1, suggesting that our results are robust to the inclusion of other subsidies. In Table 4 coefficient estimates on electricity prices may be downward biased since unobservables - the political party in power or the size of a state s agricultural economy - that may increase groundwater extraction may also be negatively correlated with electricity prices. To identify the effect of electricity prices on groundwater extraction, we estimate equation 9, a district fixed effects model in which we interact groundwater characteristics with agricultural electricity prices and control for state-year shocks; results are reported in Table 5. In this model we are unable to measure the direct effect of electricity prices on demand for groundwater. Rather we estimate the differential effect of electricity prices on districts with different minimum well depths within a state-year. We find evidence that an increase in electricity prices reduces groundwater extraction relatively more in districts with deeper wells (higher priced groundwater sources). For a district with the mean tube well depth (57 m), we find that a 25 percent increase in the agricultural price of electricity reduces groundwater extraction by mcm or 2.2 percent. Our results suggest that a 10% decrease in the average electricity would reduce district groundwater extraction by 5.4 percent. 6.1 Agricultural production We have demonstrated that electricity subsidies induced an increase in groundwater extraction. Assuming that electricity subsidies affected agricultural production through the channel of groundwater extraction, we now present results for the subsequent effect of these subsidies on agricultural production - prediction 2. Table 6 presents results. Column 1 re- 16

17 ports results from the estimation of equation 8, an OLS model of the value of agricultural output on electricity prices. This model estimates the effect of state-year electricity prices on agricultural revenues within a district, controlling for year shocks. Our results suggest that a 1 paise increase in electricity prices, which approximates an 8.25 percent price increase, induces a 5.2 percent reduction in agricultural revenues. This finding is both economically and statistically significant, and suggests a large reduction in annual revenues should electricity subsidies be reduced. For examples, a 25 percent increase in electricity prices would reduce revenues by 15.8 percent and a 10 percent reduction in subsidies would lower revenues by more than one-third. The magnitude of the estimated impact of electricity prices on agricultural revenues suggests that unobservables that are positively correlated with groundwater extraction may also systematically increase agricultural revenues. For example, fertilizer subsidies, the other dominant agricultural subsidy in India, will likely lead to an increase in groundwater extraction and agricultural output. To isolate the effect of electricity subsidies (via the channel of groundwater extraction) on agricultural output, we estimate equation 9, an OLS model in which we interact electricity prices with minimum well depth, except now importantly the dependent variable is agricultural revenues. Column 2 reports results. Consistent with the predictions in our theoretical model, we find that electricity subsidies led to a significant increase in agricultural revenues. Our results suggest that a 1 paise increase in the price of electricity would cause a 1.5% decrease in agricultural revenues. Compared to column 1, electricity prices have a less substantial impact on agricultural revenues; a 25 percent increase in electricity prices is predicted to reduce agricultural revenues by 4.7 percent. A 10% reduction in the subsidy would lower agricultural revenues by 11 percent. This evidence suggests that electricity subsidies in India benefited farmers, when benefits are measured as agricultural revenues. However, if we simply estimate the effect of electricity subsidies on agricultural outputs the stimulus provided by these subsidies will be largely overstated. In fact, the predicted impacts of electricity subsidies in the interaction model are less than one-third those reported in the simple OLS model. If we breakdown agricultural revenues by water intensive and non-water intensive crops, we observe significant changes in water intensive crop revenues in response to a change in electricity prices (col. 3). All things equal, we would expect water intensive crop revenues to be more responsive to electricity prices, since these crops use more water and hence electricity. Indeed, consistent with our theoretical predictions, we find that revenues from water intensive crops are sensitive to price changes, reducing by approximately 3.4 percent with a 1 Rs increase in electricity prices (col 3). By contrast, we observe no change in 17

18 non-water intensive crops in response to a change in electricity prices (col. 4). The government introduced agricultural subsidies to lower average food prices and to increase agricultural revenues. We have already shown that these subsidies increased agricultural revenues. We now evaluate whether they reduced the price of crops. We estimate equation 8 and equation 9 where the dependent variables are crop price. Table 7 reports results. We find no significant impact of electricity subsidies on the price of cotton in the simple OLS model (column 1) or in the interaction model (column 2-5). Our results suggest that in the short-run electricity subsidies did not significantly impact the price of food crops, where our results apply to cotton (col. 2) jowar (col. 3), wheat (col. 4) and sugar (col. 5). These results are, however, unsurprising given the heavy involvement of the state in price setting for agricultural products (Gulati and Narayan 2003). 7 Measuring the short-run net benefits In India, electricity subsidies for agriculture were introduced as a poverty alleviation tool. Advocates of these subsidies argued that they would increase agricultural productivity, reduce food prices and increase the incomes of the rural poor. Indeed, we find evidence that subsidized electricity prices, which lowered the price to access groundwater, led to an increase in agricultural revenues. However, these agricultural benefits are not without their costs. In this section, we conduct a back-of-the envelope cost-benefit analysis to evaluate the short-run net benefits of electricity subsidies. A comprehensive cost-benefit analysis would include all the benefits and costs associated with electricity subsidies. We restrict our measure of benefits to agricultural revenues, though electricity subsidies most likely generated other benefits such as an increased food supply. We also underreport the costs of these subsidies. Costs estimates are confined to the direct cost of the subsidy, defined as the difference between the unit cost to supply electricity and the price paid by agricultural users to consume electricity. Cost estimates would increase if we considered the linkages between these subsidies and groundwater exploitation. In the case that groundwater is over-exploited, cost estimates must reflect the scarcity value of the resource - the fact that the consumption of a unit of groundwater today prevents the future consumption of that unit. A second limitation of the cost-benefit analysis is that we cannot compare the costs of switching from a policy in which electricity is priced at the marginal cost to one in which electricity is priced at the status-quo. Rather this cost-benefit analysis predicts the change in benefits and costs if there was a 10% reduction in the subsidy. We calculate the net benefits of a 10 percent reduction rather than a complete removal of the subsidy due to concerns 18

19 about out of sample predictions. In our sample, the average per unit cost of electricity is 85 paise per kwh, though farmers on average only pay paise per kwh. There is no overlap between agricultural prices and the unit cost of supply; electricity prices for agriculture range between 0 and 39 paise whereas the unit cost of supply ranges between 57 and 119 paise. Since there are no observations in which the agricultural price equals the unit cost of electricity, we cannot reasonably predict the impact of unit cost pricing on agricultural revenues. By contrast if we reduce the subsidy by 10%, the calculated price of electricity overlaps with the observed price of electricity in all states in the study with the exception of two. To measure the net benefits of these subsidies, we first perform a simple counterfactual and estimate what groundwater agricultural revenues would have been if the electricity subsidy was reduced by 10 percent. The difference between actual agricultural revenues and revenues under a 10 percent reduction in the subsidy reflects the net benefits of these subsidies, where we calculate net benefits annually. Coefficient estimates from the model in which minimum aquifer depth is interacted with electricity prices are used in the policy simulation. The average annual benefits conferred to district agricultural revenues from these subsidies amounted to $33.5 million Rs. To measure the annual cost of electricity subsidies, we first translate groundwater extraction into electricity usage using a methodology developed in Zhu et al.. The total energy in million watt hours (Mwh) necessary to pump Q mcm of water from an aquifer is given by, E = φ W h (10) where h measures average groundwater depth. We assume that h equals the minimum depth to the aquifer; this measure of groundwater depth provides a lower bound for the energy necessary to extract groundwater. The coefficient φ is defined as γ ρ g/1000 where φ denotes pumping efficiency which we take to be 0.55, ρ is the density of water (1000 kg/m 3 ) and g is the acceleration of gravity (9.8 m/s 2 ). Energy usage is calculated for each district-year. The annual of cost of electricity subsidies equals electricity usage multiplied by 10 percent of the agricultural subsidy. The annual costs of these subsidies are large, totaling at 185 million Rs per district. A simple back of the envelope calculation reveals that the annual costs of a 10 subsidy reduction outweighed the benefits by more than a 150 million Rupees. If we calculate the net benefits of these subsidies using coefficient estimates from the OLS model with electricity prices (which predict a 33 percent reduction in revenues), we continue to find that the costs exceed the benefits by more than 80 million Rupees (roughly 2 million dollars). As 19

20 mentioned earlier, this study likely understates the benefits of electricity subsidies. However, the benefits from agricultural electricity subsidies would need to increase more than 5-fold for the benefits of this policy to outweigh the costs. Cost estimates would also increase if we considered (1) the linkages between these subsidies and groundwater exploitation and (2) the negative externality imposed by emissions. 8 Political capture In India electricity shortages are pervasive with many individuals receiving electricity for only a portion of the day. Over time, the provision of reliable electricity services has only worsened as industrial users begin to build their own capacity, thereby reducing the base of users that pay the marginal cost for electricity. These shortages are partly attributable to electricity subsidies, since SEBs are operating at a loss and do not have the capital to repair existing generation sources or construct additional capital. Even if we ignore the long-term impact of subsidized agricultural electricity, this paper shows that in the shortrun, the annual cost of electricity subsidies outweighs the benefits six-fold. We now explore one possible explanation for the continued use of these subsidies. This section investigates the linkages between state elections and agricultural electricity prices to discern whether electricity subsidies partly function as a state political tool to gain rural votes. 8.1 State elections In India, members of the SEBs are appointed by elected state officials who hold office in the legislative assembly. These state legislative assemblies, referred to as Vidhan Sabhas, are directly elected bodies whose size varies according to the population. As stated in the constitution, state legislative assembly elections are scheduled every five years. However if the lower parliament finds the state government unfit to rule, the government can issue an election, referred to as a midterm election, prior to the end of the five year term. Recently state midterm elections have become more common, though the frequency of midterm elections varies by state (NIC 2009). If a midterm election occurs, a constitutionally scheduled election will occur five years later. Due to midterm elections, there is substantial variation in electoral cycles across states. 8.2 The impact of state elections on electricity prices It is important to distinguish between the anticipated impacts of midterm elections and pre-scheduled elections on electricity pricing. Since midterm elections occur if the central 20

21 government views the state government as incapable, these elections are likely to be strongly correlated with the political climate of a state, the relationship between the federal and state political parties in office and the economic climate. A simple OLS model that estimates the effect of all lead elections years on electricity prices might be biased, since elections may capture the effect of political unrest or a weak economy on electricity prices. By contrast, scheduled constitutional elections occur every five years independent of the political climate, the relationship between political parties and voter preferences. Our identification strategy exploits this exogenous variation in pre-scheduled elections to test for the presence of electoral cycles in electricity pricing. Other studies have employed a similar approach using pre-scheduled elections to estimate the effect of state elections on crime, road construction and revenue (Chaudhuri and Dasgupta 2005, Cole 2009, Ghosh 2006, Khemani 2004). In Figure 3, we illustrate the rationale for this approach. For the state of Rajasthan, we graph electricity prices between 1996 and 2005 and indicate the years, 1997 and 2002, that precede a pre-scheduled election. Graphically, we observe a decrease in electricity prices prior to pre-scheduled election years. We estimate an OLS model with district and year fixed effects, p E jt = β 0 + β 1 elec jt + β 2 X it + λ t + γ i + u it (11) The dependent variable p E jt measures the annual price of electricity in a state. The variable of interest elec jt is an indicator variable set equal to one if a pre-scheduled election occurs in state j in year t + 1. We choose to use lead election year since politicians campaign in the year preceding an election. We control for annual rainfall and whether rainfall is reported X it, year fixed effects and district fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the district. Since political campaigns occur in the year preceding an election, we predict that politicians will increase agricultural subsidies in the year prior to an election to secure the agricultural sector s vote. Results from an OLS model of agricultural electricity prices on pre-scheduled elections are presented in Table 8. As shown in column 1, we find on average a 1.4 paise decrease in the price of electricity in the year preceding a pre-scheduled election. Since electricity prices in our sample range between 0 and 55 paise per kwh, with a mean price of paise, our results suggest that politicians reduce electricity prices on average by 10 percent in the year preceding an election. To test whether the relationship between electricity prices and elections is spurious, we estimate the effect of lagged pre-scheduled elections on electricity prices. As reported in 21

22 column 2, we find that in the year following a pre-scheduled election, electricity prices on average increase. Lastly, we estimate the effect of midterm and pre-scheduled elections on electricity prices, where we include two indicator variables that are each set equal to 1 in the year preceding a midterm and pre-scheduled election, respectively. Conditional on midterm elections, electricity prices continue to decrease in the year preceding a scheduled election. Our work fits within a growing literature that provides evidence of electoral cycles in crimes, revenues and public infrastructure (Chaudhuri and Dasgupta 2005, Cole 2009, Ghosh 2006, Khemani 2004). Similar to these studies, our results suggest that political capture partly explains the persistence of agricultural electricity subsidies. In the years preceding a scheduled state election, the price of electricity significantly drops, even after controlling for annual shocks and fixed district unobservables. Though state electricity boards operate at a loss and these subsidies only induce small increases in agricultural revenues, these subsidies provide a strong political tool for politicians. More generally, we find that public ownership of electric utilities provides managers with an incentive to maintain or even increase electricity subsidies in politically sensitive years. 9 Conclusion We motivate this paper by asking if the public provision of electricity in rural India maximized social welfare and was captured by voting interests. In rural India, agricultural electricity prices are heavily subsidized, and we explore whether these subsidies correct an existing market failure, thereby increasing total welfare. We measure the benefits of this policy as the change in agricultural output from these subsidies. We find that a 1 paise increase in electricity prices raises agricultural output by 1.6 percent. However this comes at a cost. A 10% reduction in the subsidy would reduce government costs by $185 million Rs in each district. We estimate that the costs of the subsidy are five times larger than the benefits. Though restrictive in the benefits and costs considered, our cost-benefit analysis reveals that state ownership of electricity did not lead to a maximization of social welfare. If electricity in India were privatized and subject to appropriate regulation, we anticipate that the annual losses from electricity provision would decrease. Our research suggests that political capture offers one explanation for the persistence of these subsidies. To maintain their political position, state politicians have an incentive to price electricity below its efficient price, especially during politically sensitive periods. We find evidence for this behavior. First agricultural electricity prices are priced below the efficient price - the price agricultural users pay for electricity equals 13 percent of the unit cost of supply. Second, agricultural prices are manipulated during politically sensitive 22

23 periods. Our research suggests that the price of electricity decreases in the year preceding an election. While many are skeptical about the privatization of utilities in developing countries, our research shows that public ownership of electricity does not necessarily increase social welfare and is captured by the interest of voters. In light of this, privatization of electricity, with appropriate regulation, may improve social welfare in developing countries. References [1] Besley, Timothy and Burgess, Robin, (2002), The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4): [2] Birner, Regina, Surupa Gupta, Neera Sharma and Nethra Palaniswamy, (2007), The Political Economy of Agricultural Policy Reform in India: The Case of Fertilizer Supply and Electricity Supply for Groundwater Irrigation, New Delhi, India: IFPRI [3] Briscoe, John and Malik, R.P.S., (2006), India s Water Economy: Bracing for a Turbulent Future, New Dehi, India: Oxford University Press. [4] Chaudhuri, Kausik and Dasgupta, Sugato, (2005), The Political Determinants of Central Governments Economic Policies in India: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of International Development, 17: [5] Clarke, George, Kosec, Katrina and Wallsten, Scott, (2009), Has Private Participation in Water and Sewerage Improved Coverage? Empirical Evidence from Latin America, Journal of International Development 21: [6] Cole, Shawn, (2009), Fixing Market Failures or Fixing Elections? Agricultural Credit in India, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1(1): [7] Cubin, John and Stern, Jon, (2006), The Impact of Regulatory Governance and Privitzation on Electricity Industry Generation Capacity in Developing Economies, The World Bank Economic Review 20(1): [8] Domenico, P.A., Anderson, D.V., and Case, C.M., (1968), Optimal Ground-Water Mining, Water Resources Research, 4(2): [9] Dubash, Navroz K., (2007), The Electricity-Groundwater Conundrum: Case for a Political Solution to a Political Problem, Economic and Political Weekly,

24 [10] Dubash, Navroz K. and Rajan, Sudhir Chella, (2001), Power Politics: Process of Power Sector Reform in India, Economic and Political Weekly 36(35): [11] Estache, Antonio and Rossi, Martin A., (2002), How Different is the Efficiency of Public and Private Water Companies in Asia? The World Bank Economic Review 16(1): [12] Estache, Antonio and Wren-Lewis, Liam, (2009), Toward a Theory of Regulation for Developing Countries: Following Jean-Jaques Laffont s Lead, Journal of Economic Literature, 47(3): [13] Galiani, Sebastian and Gertler, Paul and Schargrodsky, Ernesto, (2005), Water for Life: The Impact of the Privatization of Water Services on Child Mortality, The Journal of Political Economy 113(1): [14] Ghosh, Arkadipta, (2006), Electoral Cycles in Crime in a Developing Country: Evidence from the Indian States, working paper. [15] Gulati, Ashok and Narayanan, S., (2000), Demystifying Fertiliser and Power Subsidies in India, Economic and Political Weekly, 35(10): [16] Gulati Ashok and Sudha Narayanan (2003), The Subsidy Syndrome in Indian Agriculture, New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press. [17] Hawdon, D., (1996), Performance of Power Sectors in Developing Countries - A Study of Efficiency and World Bank Policy using Data Envelopment Analysis, Surrevy Energy Economics Centre Discussion Paper 88, University of Surrey. [18] Khemani, Stuti, (2004), Political cycles in a developing economy: effect of elections in the Indian states, Journal of Development Economics 73: [19] Kirkpatrick, Colin, Parker, David, and Zhang, Yin-Fang, Empirical Analysis of State and Private-Sector Provision of Water Services in Africa, World Bank Economic Review 20(1): [20] Martin, William E., and Archer, Thomas, (1971), Cost of Pumping Irrigation Water in Arizona: 1891 to 1967, Water Resources Research 7(1): [21] McKenzie, Dave and Ray, I., (2004), Household Water Delivery Options in Urban and Rural India, Prepared for 5th Stanford Conference on Indian Economic Development, June 3-5,

25 [22] Modi, Vijay (2005), Improving Electricity Services in Rural India, Working Paper No. 30. Center on Globalization and Sustainable Development. [23] Rana, M.S., (2006), India Votes: Lok Sabha and Vidhan Sabha Elections , New Delhi, India: Sarup and Sons. [24] Scheierling, S. M., Loomis, J.B., and Young R. A., (2006), Irrigation water demand: A meta-analysis of price elasticities, Water Resources Research 42 doi: /2005wr [25] Strand, Jon, (2010), The Full Economic Cost of Groundwater Extraction, Policy Research Working Paper Industry, OECD Economic Studies No. 32. [26] Vickers, John and Yarrow, George, (1991), Economic Perspectives on Privatization, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(2): [27] Zhang, Yin-Fang, Parker, David and Kirkpatrick, Colin, (2008), Electricity Sector Reform in Developing Countries: An Econometric Assessment of the Effects of Privatisation, Competition and Regulation, Journal of Regulatory Economics 33(2): [28] Zhu, Tingju, Ringler, Claudia and Cai, Ximing, (YEAR), Energy Price and Groundwater Extraction for Agriculture: Exploring the Energy-Water-Food Nexus at the Global and Basin Levels, working paper. 25

26 Table 1: Summary Statistics on Supply and Demand for Groundwater District variable Year Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Aggregate demand Available gw supply GW development Percent exploited Aggregate demand Available gw supply GW development Percent exploited Aggregate demand Available gw supply GW development Percent exploited Aggregate demand Available gw supply GW development Percent exploited Aggregate demand Available gw supply GW development Percent exploited Notes: Data from Central Groundwater Board. The unit of observation is a district. Aggregate demand and available groundwater supply are measured in million cubic meters (mcm). GW development is defined as the ratio of groundwater demanded over the the annual replenishable supply. The annual replenishable groundwater resource is calculated as the sum of monsoon and non-monsoon recharge. A district is defined as exploited if groundwater development is greater than 1. 26

27 Table 2: Summary Statistics on Supply and Demand for Groundwater Variable Year States Districts Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Election (Any) Midterm Election Prescheduled Election Election (Any) Midterm Election Prescheduled Election Election (Any) Midterm Election Prescheduled Election Election (Any) Midterm Election Prescheduled Election Election (Any) Midterm Election Prescheduled Election Notes: The unit of observation is a state, the number of districts examined is given in column 4. Scheduled elections refer to constitutionally prescheduled elections, where elections are scheduled to occur 5 years after the previous election. Midterm elections refer to elections occuring in the intermittent time period due to a lack of confidence in parliament. 27

28 Table 3: Summary Statistics on Electricity Prices and Capacity District variable Year States Districts Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Agricultural Electricity Price Industrial Electricity Price Generation Subsidy Agricultural Electricity Price Industrial Electricity Price Generation Subsidy Agricultural Electricity Price Industrial Electricity Price Generation Subsidy Agricultural Electricity Price Industrial Electricity Price Generation Subsidy Notes: The unit of observation is a state, the number of districts examined is given in column 4. Electricity prices and subsidies are measured in 1986 paise. Electricity generation are measured in million kilowatt hours. Electricity subsidies are measured as the difference between the electricity price and the unit cost. 28

29 Table 4: OLS models of demand for groundwater Demand Groundwater (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Replenishable supply 0.255** 0.259** 0.260** 0.257** 0.256* (0.128) (0.131) (0.128) (0.129) (0.131) Rural electricity price ** ** (1.546) (1.487) Generation *** ( ) ( ) Capacity ** ( ) (0.0259) T&D losses (1.747) (2.062) Log rain (26.89) (32.42) (27.03) (26.82) (33.81) Fixed effects district district district district district year year year year year Observations R-squared Notes: The dependent variable is the quantity in million cubic meters of groundwater extraction by district year. Columns 1-5 report results from an OLS model with standard errors in parentheses. Asterisks denote significance; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 29

30 Table 5: OLS model of demand for groundwater with interaction Groundwater extraction exploited exploited -150% Replenishable gw supply 0.305** -7.70e e-05** (0.141) (4.54e-05) (1.74e-05) Elec price * gw supply e e-06* ( ) (1.20e-06) (7.22e-07) Elec price*min well depth *** -1.32e e-05 (0.0218) (4.09e-05) (3.01e-05) Log rain (10.27) (0.0136) ( ) Fixed effects district district district state*year state*year state*year Observations R-squared Notes: The dependent variable is the quantity in million cubic meters of groundwater extraction by a district in a year. Columns 1-5 report results from an OLS model with standard errors. Regression includes dummy for rain reported and avg max well depth*electricity price. in parentheses. Asterisks denote significance; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 30

31 Table 6: OLS model of agricultural production (1) (2) (3) (4) Value agricultural product All crops All crops H20 intensive crops Non-H20 intensive crops Replenishable gw supply -6.43e ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Elec price *** ( ) Elec price * gw supply 3.71e e e-05 (2.17e-05) (2.17e-05) (2.82e-05) Elec price*min well depth *** *** (5.50e-05) (5.41e-05) ( ) Log rain (0.120) (0.0901) (0.0926) (0.148) Fixed effects district district district district year state*year state*year state*year Observations R-squared Notes: The dependent variable is the log of agricultural revenue in a district in a year. Columns 1-5 report results from an OLS model with standard errors. Regression includes dummy for rain reported and avg max well depth*electricity price. in parentheses. Asterisks denote significance; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 31

32 Table 7: OLS model of crop prices Price Cotton Cotton Sugar Jowar Wheat Replenishable gw supply ( ) (0.0128) ( ) ( ) ( ) Elec price ag (1.145) Elec price*min well depth * (0.0174) (0.0102) ( ) ( ) Fixed effects district district distric district district state*year state*year state*year state*year state*year Observations R-squared Notes: The dependent variable is the real price in kg of each crop a district in a year. Columns 1-5 report results from an OLS model with standard errors. Regression includes dummy for rain reported, log rain and avg max well depth*electricity price. in parentheses. Asterisks denote significance; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 8: OLS model of electricity prices Electricity prices Electricity prices Electricity prices Pre-scheduled election *** *** (0.355) (0.342) Replenishable supply * ( ) ( ) ( ) Log rain (0.317) (0.294) (0.292) Pre-scheduled election lag 5.300*** (0.712) Midterm election *** (0.228) Fixed effects district district district year year yearr Observations R Notes: The dependent variable is the price for a kwhr of electricity in a district-year. Pre-scheduled election is an indicator variable for whether there was a prescheduled election in year t + 1. Asterisks denote significance; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 32

33 Figure 1: Electricity prices in India

34 Figure 2: Electricity prices by state in India

35 Figure 3: Electricity prices and elections in Rajasthan

Electricity Prices, Groundwater and Agriculture: The Environmental and Agricultural Impacts of. Electricity Subsidies in India

Electricity Prices, Groundwater and Agriculture: The Environmental and Agricultural Impacts of. Electricity Subsidies in India Electricity Prices, Groundwater and Agriculture: The Environmental and Agricultural Impacts of Electricity Subsidies in India Reena Badiani Katrina Jessoe Abstract In this paper we estimate the effect

More information

Page 1 of 26 (www.unapcaem.org)

Page 1 of 26 (www.unapcaem.org) Farm Mechanization in Punjab: Social, Economic and Environmental Implications Gurharminder Singh Sr. Scientific Officer, Punjab State Council for Science & Technology, INDIA Page 1 of 26 () Page 2 of 26

More information

Farmer Suicides in India: Levels and Trends across Major States,

Farmer Suicides in India: Levels and Trends across Major States, University of Massachusetts - Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Economics Department Working Paper Series Economics 2016 Farmer Suicides in India: Levels and Trends across Major States, 1995-2011 Deepankar

More information

Common Sense Economics: What Everyone Should Know About Wealth and Prosperity (Gwartney, Stroup, Lee, and Ferrarini ~ St. Martin s Press, 2010)

Common Sense Economics: What Everyone Should Know About Wealth and Prosperity (Gwartney, Stroup, Lee, and Ferrarini ~ St. Martin s Press, 2010) 1 Common Sense Economics: What Everyone Should Know About Wealth and Prosperity (Gwartney, Stroup, Lee, and Ferrarini ~ St. Martin s Press, 2010) Reading Guide Part III. Economic Progress and the Role

More information

Decentralization Without Representation (or Mobility): Implications for Rural Public Service Delivery

Decentralization Without Representation (or Mobility): Implications for Rural Public Service Delivery Decentralization Without Representation (or Mobility): Implications for Rural Public Service Delivery Tewodaj Mogues International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) (Paper with Katrina Kosec, IFPRI)

More information

Economic implications of land degradation on sustainability and food security in India

Economic implications of land degradation on sustainability and food security in India Agropedology 23, 13(2), 19-27 Economic implications of land degradation on sustainability and food security in India A. K. VASISHT, R. P. SINGH AND V. C. MATHUR Division of Agricultural Economics, Indian

More information

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Daniel A. Sumner and William Matthews 1

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Daniel A. Sumner and William Matthews 1 THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY Daniel A. Sumner and William Matthews 1 ABSTRACT Farm subsidies have been a part of U.S. agriculture for eight decades. The 2014 farm bill changed the form of

More information

IMPO P RT R AN A C N E C E O F G RO R UN U D N W

IMPO P RT R AN A C N E C E O F G RO R UN U D N W Introduction IMPORTANCE OF GROUNDWATER Global Groundwater Situation ACWADAM s database Sources for presentation CGWB, various publications FAO-database Various United Nations publications. UN World Water

More information

WATER AWARENESS PROGRAM (WAP) FOR FARMERS (Moga, Punjab)

WATER AWARENESS PROGRAM (WAP) FOR FARMERS (Moga, Punjab) WATER AWARENESS PROGRAM (WAP) FOR FARMERS (Moga, Punjab) Understand Conserve Protect Nestlé India OBJECTIVE OF THIS PROGRAM This program has been specially designed by Nestlé to create awareness amongst

More information

Agriculture Sector Analysis

Agriculture Sector Analysis Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Dissemination Note Series Romania: Toward a Low Carbon and Climate Resilient Economy

More information

ELECTRIC COST OF SERVICE AND RATE DESIGN STUDY

ELECTRIC COST OF SERVICE AND RATE DESIGN STUDY DRAFT Report ELECTRIC COST OF SERVICE AND RATE DESIGN STUDY Navajo Tribal Utility Authority August 2007 DRAFT NAVAJO TRIBAL UTILITY AUTHORITY ELECTRIC COST OF SERVICE AND RATE DESIGN STUDY Table of Contents

More information

Water Policy and Poverty Reduction in Rural Area: A Comparative Economywide Analysis for Morocco and Tunisia

Water Policy and Poverty Reduction in Rural Area: A Comparative Economywide Analysis for Morocco and Tunisia Water Policy and Poverty Reduction in Rural Area: A Comparative Economywide Analysis for Morocco and Tunisia Workshop on Agricultural Trade and Food Security in the Euro-Med Area Antalya, Turkey, September

More information

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6 Econ 792 Labor Economics Lecture 6 1 "Although it is obvious that people acquire useful skills and knowledge, it is not obvious that these skills and knowledge are a form of capital, that this capital

More information

Progress and Potential of Horticulture in India

Progress and Potential of Horticulture in India Ind. Jn. of Agri.Econ. Vol.63, No.3, July-Sept. 2008 SUBJECT I TRIGGERING AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT THROUGH HORTICULTURE CROPS Progress and Potential of Horticulture in India Ramesh Chand, S.S. Raju and

More information

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy

Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Kyoto University, Graduate School of Economics Research Project Center Discussion Paper Series Global Reuse and Optimal Waste Policy Hide-Fumi Yokoo and Thomas C. Kinnaman Discussion Paper No. E-09-002

More information

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes. These notes provided by Laura Lamb are intended to complement class lectures. The notes are based on chapter 12 of Microeconomics and Behaviour 2 nd Canadian Edition by Frank and Parker (2004). Chapter

More information

Asian Journal of Agriculture and Rural Development. Analysis of Rice Production Instability in Southeast Asian Countries

Asian Journal of Agriculture and Rural Development. Analysis of Rice Production Instability in Southeast Asian Countries Asian Journal of Agriculture and Rural Development journal homepage: http://aessweb.com/journal-detail.php?id=5005 Analysis of Rice Production Instability in Southeast Asian Countries Mamma Sawaneh Department

More information

Supply Response of Cereal Crop Farmers to Price and Non-Price Factors in Rajasthan State of India

Supply Response of Cereal Crop Farmers to Price and Non-Price Factors in Rajasthan State of India Journal of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development Vol. 3(2), pp. 230-235, August, 2017. www.premierpublishers.org. ISSN: XXXX-XXXX AJAERD Review Article Supply Response of Cereal Crop Farmers to

More information

The fate of agriculture in MENA countries

The fate of agriculture in MENA countries Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis Rosenberg International Forum on Water Policy Aqaba, Jordan March 24-25, 2013 Water scarcity and agriculture in MENA Water

More information

A STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY OF EU ON PRODUCTION OF COTTON IN GREECE: IMPLICATIONS FOR U.S. COTTON EXPORTS

A STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY OF EU ON PRODUCTION OF COTTON IN GREECE: IMPLICATIONS FOR U.S. COTTON EXPORTS A STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY OF EU ON PRODUCTION OF COTTON IN GREECE: IMPLICATIONS FOR U.S. COTTON EXPORTS Final Report: Cotton Inc. Project #12 228 Srinivasa Konduru, Department

More information

CHAPTER 16 Socio-ecology of groundwater irrigation in India

CHAPTER 16 Socio-ecology of groundwater irrigation in India 16-Deb Roy.qxd 02-10-2002 20:07 Pagina 307 CHAPTER 16 Socio-ecology of groundwater irrigation in India A. Deb Roy (1) & T. Shah (2) International Water Management Institute (IWMI), India Program Office,

More information

Tariff Circular & Tariff Schedules. (Effective from 01 st April 2015)

Tariff Circular & Tariff Schedules. (Effective from 01 st April 2015) Tariff Circular & Tariff Schedules (Effective from 01 st April 2015) Madhya Gujarat Vij Company Limited Corporate Office, S.P. Vidyut Bhavan, Race Course, Vadodara-390 007 1465/2014 ANNEXURE: TARIFF SCHEDULE

More information

Methodology for calculating subsidies to renewables

Methodology for calculating subsidies to renewables 1 Introduction Each of the World Energy Outlook scenarios envisages growth in the use of renewable energy sources over the Outlook period. World Energy Outlook 2012 includes estimates of the subsidies

More information

Regional Pattern of Agricultural Growth and Rural Employment in India: Have Small Farmers Benefitted?

Regional Pattern of Agricultural Growth and Rural Employment in India: Have Small Farmers Benefitted? Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 26 (Conference Number) 2013 pp 1-11 Regional Pattern of Agricultural Growth and Rural Employment in India: Have Small Farmers Benefitted? M.L. Nithyashree* and

More information

The Crop Connection: Impact of Cell Phone Access on Crop Choice in Rural Pakistan

The Crop Connection: Impact of Cell Phone Access on Crop Choice in Rural Pakistan The Crop Connection: Impact of Cell Phone Access on Crop Choice in Rural Pakistan Saher Asad Lahore University of Management Sciences saher.asad@lums.edu.pk June 20, 2016 ABCDE 2016 Saher Asad (LUMS) Crop

More information

NREGA: A Component of Full Employment Strategy in India. Prof. Indira Hirway Center For Development Alternatives Ahmedabad

NREGA: A Component of Full Employment Strategy in India. Prof. Indira Hirway Center For Development Alternatives Ahmedabad NREGA: A Component of Full Employment Strategy in India Prof. Indira Hirway Center For Development Alternatives Ahmedabad This Paper This paper argues that NREGA could be an important first step of a full

More information

THE EFFECT OF IRRIGATION TECHNOLOGY ON GROUNDWATER USE

THE EFFECT OF IRRIGATION TECHNOLOGY ON GROUNDWATER USE 3rd Quarter 2010 25(3) THE EFFECT OF IRRIGATION TECHNOLOGY ON GROUNDWATER USE Lisa Pfeiffer and C.-Y. Cynthia Lin JEL Classifications: Q15, Q25, Q38 The High Plains (Ogallala) Aquifer is the largest freshwater

More information

CH2356 Energy Engineering Wind Power. Dr. M. Subramanian

CH2356 Energy Engineering  Wind Power.  Dr. M. Subramanian CH2356 Energy Engineering Wind Power Dr. M. Subramanian Associate Professor Department of Chemical Engineering Sri Sivasubramaniya Nadar College of Engineering Kalavakkam 603 110, Kanchipuram(Dist) Tamil

More information

National Water Demand Management Policy

National Water Demand Management Policy National Water Demand Management Policy Introduction In 1997, the Ministry of Water and Irrigation developed Jordan s Water Strategy and the following four policies, which include: Water Utility Policy;

More information

Pumpset Energy Efficiency: Agriculture Demand Side Management Program

Pumpset Energy Efficiency: Agriculture Demand Side Management Program International Journal of Agriculture and Food Science Technology. ISSN 2249-3050, Volume 4, Number 5 (2013), pp. 493-500 Research India Publications http://www.ripublication.com/ ijafst.htm Pumpset Energy

More information

A Balance Sheet of Performance of Large dams in India The case of irrigation and flood control

A Balance Sheet of Performance of Large dams in India The case of irrigation and flood control 1 A Balance Sheet of Performance of Large dams in India The case of irrigation and flood control Over the last 51 years of water resources development in Independent India, the nation has spent over Rs.

More information

Fracking and Land Productivity: The Effects of Hydraulic Fracturing on Agriculture

Fracking and Land Productivity: The Effects of Hydraulic Fracturing on Agriculture Fracking and Land Productivity: The Effects of Hydraulic Fracturing on Agriculture Naima Farah University of Calgary IWREC Annual Meeting The World Bank, Washington, DC September 2016 Introduction Can

More information

Input Subsidy Programs in Asia What lesson can we learn for Africa

Input Subsidy Programs in Asia What lesson can we learn for Africa Input Subsidy Programs in Asia What lesson can we learn for Africa Shahidur Rashid (presenting) Paul A. Dorosh, IFPRI M.K. Mujeri, BIDS INPUT SUBSIDY PROGRAM IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 16 APRIL 2013 WASHINGTON

More information

Two Blades of Grass: The Impact of the Green Revolution

Two Blades of Grass: The Impact of the Green Revolution Two Blades of Grass: The Impact of the Green Revolution Douglas Gollin 1 Casper Worm Hansen 2 Asger M. Wingender 3 Nairobi, July 7, 2017 1 Oxford University 2 University of Copenhagen 3 University of Copenhagen

More information

KR Sriram Principal Director of Audit Economic & Service Ministries

KR Sriram Principal Director of Audit Economic & Service Ministries KR Sriram Principal Director of Audit Economic & Service Ministries Total Annual Precipitation Average Annual Potential Average Annual Utilisable Water (a) Surface Water (b) Ground Water Net Annual Ground

More information

The Price Loss Coverage (PLC) Program of the 2014 Farm Bill

The Price Loss Coverage (PLC) Program of the 2014 Farm Bill Staff Report No. 2014-10 July 2014 The Price Loss Coverage (PLC) Program of the 2014 Farm Bill Michael A. Deliberto and Michael E. Salassi Department of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness Louisiana

More information

African Cities and The Structural Transformation: Evidence from Ghana and Ivory Coast

African Cities and The Structural Transformation: Evidence from Ghana and Ivory Coast African Cities and The Structural Transformation: Evidence from Ghana and Ivory Coast Remi Jedwab Paris School of Economics & LSE ABCDE 2011 Conference, 01 June 2011. 1 / 33 Research Question Introduction

More information

Dynamics of Labour Demand and its Determinants in Punjab Agriculture

Dynamics of Labour Demand and its Determinants in Punjab Agriculture Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 26 (No.2) July-December 2013 pp 267-273 Dynamics of Labour Demand and its Determinants in Punjab Agriculture Y. Latika Devi, Jasdev Singh*, Kamal Vatta and Sanjay

More information

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models Preface Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics 1.1 Economic Models 1.1.1 Positive and Normative Analysis 1.1.2 The Market Economy Model 1.1.3 Types of Economic Problems 1.2 Mathematics

More information

Liberalization, Investment, and Regulation: The Key Factors for the Development of the Electronic Communications Market

Liberalization, Investment, and Regulation: The Key Factors for the Development of the Electronic Communications Market Liberalization, Investment, and Regulation: The Key Factors for the Development of the Electronic Communications Market Jonida Gjika, PhD Electronic Communications and Postal Authority of Albania doi:

More information

CONSERVATION AND DEMAND MANAGEMENT CODE FOR ELECTRICITY DISTRIBUTORS

CONSERVATION AND DEMAND MANAGEMENT CODE FOR ELECTRICITY DISTRIBUTORS Ontario Energy Board Commission de l énergie de l Ontario CONSERVATION AND DEMAND MANAGEMENT CODE FOR ELECTRICITY DISTRIBUTORS Issued: September 16, 2010 Table of Contents 1. GENERAL AND ADMINISTRATIVE

More information

Cost of Cultivation and Yield Rates of Paddy Crop in Agriculture: A Comparative Study between Irrigated and Un-Irrigated Areas of Telangana State

Cost of Cultivation and Yield Rates of Paddy Crop in Agriculture: A Comparative Study between Irrigated and Un-Irrigated Areas of Telangana State Asian Journal of Agriculture & Life Sciences Vol. 1(2), April 2016: 48-53 Website: www.crsdindia.com/aajals.html e-issn: 2455-6149 ORIGINAL ARTICLE and Yield Rates of Paddy Crop in Agriculture: A Comparative

More information

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data Andreas Mueller 1 Stockholm University First Draft: May 15, 2009 This Draft: August 11, 2010 Abstract This paper provides new evidence

More information

GABON, NATIONWIDE WATER & POWER. Case Study (Water and Power) Project Summary:

GABON, NATIONWIDE WATER & POWER. Case Study (Water and Power) Project Summary: GABON, NATIONWIDE WATER & POWER Case Study (Water and Power) Project Summary: In July 1997, the government of Gabon signed a twenty-year concession contract with a private French consortium to operate

More information

EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California

EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California Bradley J. Rickard, Assistant Professor, Agribusiness Department California Polytechnic State University, San

More information

An economic analysis of production of sugarcane under different method of irrigation in Durg division of Chhattisgarh

An economic analysis of production of sugarcane under different method of irrigation in Durg division of Chhattisgarh 2018; 6(1): 1389-1393 P-ISSN: 2349 8528 E-ISSN: 2321 4902 IJCS 2018; 6(1): 1389-1393 2018 IJCS Received: 20-11-2017 Accepted: 21-12-2017 Umesh Jaiswal Jayant Nishad AK Koshta Professor, Department of Vijay

More information

Technology and incentive regulation in the Italian motorways industry

Technology and incentive regulation in the Italian motorways industry XI Riunione Scientifica SIET Napoli, 3-5 ottobre 2007 Technology and incentive regulation in the Italian motorways industry Luigi Benfratello Alberto Iozzi Paola Valbonesi Università di Torino Università

More information

Property Rights and Collective Action for Pro-Poor Watershed Management

Property Rights and Collective Action for Pro-Poor Watershed Management Property Rights and Collective Action for Pro-Poor Watershed Management Watersheds are simultaneously managed at various social and spatial scales, from microcatchments to transnational river systems and

More information

Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs

Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs Mohammad Amin* December, 2009 Using a new dataset on informal or unregistered firms in Ivory Coast, Madagascar and Mauritius, this paper

More information

SOME ASPECTS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA

SOME ASPECTS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA SOME ASPECTS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA R. A. Sherwin, Agricultural Attache Australian Embassy, Washington, D. C. Before discussing government programs relating to agriculture in Australia I propose

More information

PAKISTAN BALOCHISTAN SMALL SCALE IRRIGATION PROJECT (SSIP) PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB1661 Project Name

PAKISTAN BALOCHISTAN SMALL SCALE IRRIGATION PROJECT (SSIP) PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB1661 Project Name PAKISTAN BALOCHISTAN SMALL SCALE IRRIGATION PROJECT (SSIP) PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB1661 Project Name Balochistan Small Scale Irrigation Project Region SOUTH ASIA

More information

Philippine Agricultural and Food Policies: Implications on Poverty and Income Distribution

Philippine Agricultural and Food Policies: Implications on Poverty and Income Distribution Philippine Agricultural and Food Policies: Implications on Poverty and Income Distribution Caesar B. Cororaton (Virginia Tech) Erwin L. Corong (IFPRI) Presented at the Annual Meeting of International Agricultural

More information

ECONOMICS OF SUGARCANE CULTIVATION IN ANDHRA PRADESH (A Case Study of Visakhapatnam District)

ECONOMICS OF SUGARCANE CULTIVATION IN ANDHRA PRADESH (A Case Study of Visakhapatnam District) Synopsis of the thesis entitled ECONOMICS OF SUGARCANE CULTIVATION IN ANDHRA PRADESH (A Case Study of Visakhapatnam District) By KARRI NARASIMHA PUSAPPA Research Director Prof. M.BHAVANI SHANKAR RAO M.A.,

More information

Indian Pulses Market.

Indian Pulses Market. Indian Pulses Market Indian Pulses Market India is the largest producer, importer and consumer of pulses, accounting for 25% of global production from 35% of global area under pulses. However, the productivity

More information

Chapter 5. Introduction. Learning Objectives. Public Spending and Public Choice. Why have shortages existed in markets for vaccines?

Chapter 5. Introduction. Learning Objectives. Public Spending and Public Choice. Why have shortages existed in markets for vaccines? Chapter 5 Public Spending and Public Choice Introduction Why have shortages existed in markets for vaccines? Why might the government have a role in trying to correct this situation? Copyright 2008 Pearson

More information

Economics Challenge Online State Qualification Practice Test. 1. An increase in aggregate demand would tend to result from

Economics Challenge Online State Qualification Practice Test. 1. An increase in aggregate demand would tend to result from 1. An increase in aggregate demand would tend to result from A. an increase in tax rates. B. a decrease in consumer spending. C. a decrease in net export spending. D. an increase in business investment.

More information

CROP VARIETY IMPROVEMENT AND INFANT MORTALITY IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD

CROP VARIETY IMPROVEMENT AND INFANT MORTALITY IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD CROP VARIETY IMPROVEMENT AND INFANT MORTALITY IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD Prabhat Barnwal, Aaditya Dar, Jan von der Goltz, Ram Fishman, Gordon C. McCord, Nathan Mueller Motivation The health and welfare impacts

More information

Irrigation, Agricultural Performance and Poverty Reduction in China. Bryan Lohmar Economic Research Service United States Department of Agriculture

Irrigation, Agricultural Performance and Poverty Reduction in China. Bryan Lohmar Economic Research Service United States Department of Agriculture Draft March 2005 Irrigation, Agricultural Performance and Poverty Reduction in China Qiuqiong Huang* and Scott Rozelle Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis

More information

1 What are three cropping seasons of India? Explain any one in brief. 2 Discuss three main impacts of globalization on Indian agriculture.

1 What are three cropping seasons of India? Explain any one in brief. 2 Discuss three main impacts of globalization on Indian agriculture. 1 What are three cropping seasons of India? Explain any one in brief. 2 Discuss three main impacts of globalization on Indian agriculture. 3.Distinguish between rabi and kharif season? 4. What is Horticulture?

More information

Factors responsible for the performance of cooperative sugar factories in North-Eastern Karnataka

Factors responsible for the performance of cooperative sugar factories in North-Eastern Karnataka Factors responsible for the performance of cooperative sugar factories in North-Eastern Karnataka Yasmeen*, Suresh S. Patil and N. Vijaykumar Department of Agricultural Economics, College of Agriculture,

More information

Guidelines for the Development of a Policy for Managing Unsolicited Proposals in Infrastructure Projects

Guidelines for the Development of a Policy for Managing Unsolicited Proposals in Infrastructure Projects Draft Document Shared for Consultation Purposes Only Not for Redistribution Guidelines for the Development of a Policy for Managing Unsolicited Proposals in Infrastructure Projects March 2017 Draft Document

More information

Benefits of Irrigation Water Transfers in the National River Linking Project: A Case Study of Godavari (Polavaram)-Krishna Link in Andhra Pradesh

Benefits of Irrigation Water Transfers in the National River Linking Project: A Case Study of Godavari (Polavaram)-Krishna Link in Andhra Pradesh Benefits of Irrigation Water Transfers in the National River Linking Project: A Case Study of Godavari (Polavaram)-Krishna Link in Andhra Pradesh Anik Bhaduri, Upali A. Amarasinghe and Tushaar Shah International

More information

ESTIMATING GENDER DIFFERENCES IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY: BIASES DUE TO OMISSION OF GENDER-INFLUENCED VARIABLES AND ENDOGENEITY OF REGRESSORS

ESTIMATING GENDER DIFFERENCES IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY: BIASES DUE TO OMISSION OF GENDER-INFLUENCED VARIABLES AND ENDOGENEITY OF REGRESSORS ESTIMATING GENDER DIFFERENCES IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY: BIASES DUE TO OMISSION OF GENDER-INFLUENCED VARIABLES AND ENDOGENEITY OF REGRESSORS by Nina Lilja, Thomas F. Randolph and Abrahmane Diallo* Selected

More information

Response of Inequality to a Growth Rate Slowdown in Japanese Economy during the Lost Decades

Response of Inequality to a Growth Rate Slowdown in Japanese Economy during the Lost Decades Response of Inequality to a Growth Rate Slowdown in Japanese Economy during the Lost Decades N. Sudo, M. Suzuki, T. Yamada May 27, 2014@CIGS Response of Inequality to a Growth Rate Slowdown N. Sudo, M.

More information

Chapter 4 Agriculture

Chapter 4 Agriculture Chapter 4 Agriculture Types of Farming Primitive Subsistence Farming Practiced on small patches of land. Involves family/community labour. Uses primitive tools such as hoe, digging sticks etc. Predominance

More information

John Deere. Committed to Those Linked to the Land. Market Fundamentals. Deere & Company June/July 2014

John Deere. Committed to Those Linked to the Land. Market Fundamentals. Deere & Company June/July 2014 John Deere Committed to Those Linked to the Land Market Fundamentals Deere & Company June/July 2014 Safe Harbor Statement & Disclosures This presentation includes forward-looking comments subject to important

More information

Review of Saudi Arabia Municipal Water Tariff

Review of Saudi Arabia Municipal Water Tariff World Environment 213, 3(2): 66-7 DOI: 1.5923/j.env.21332.5 Review of Saudi Arabia Municipal Water Tariff Omar K M Ouda Department of Civil Engineering, Prince Mohamed Bin Fahd University, Al Khobar, Kingdom

More information

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Suman Ghosh Kameshwari Shankar Abstract A common form of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) by firmsistoagreetodonatea fixed portion of private

More information

Tackling Tariff Design. Making distribution network costs work for consumers

Tackling Tariff Design. Making distribution network costs work for consumers Tackling Tariff Design Making distribution network costs work for consumers Contents Introduction 02 What s driving change? 05 Alternative tariff designs 07 Impacts on consumers bills 11 Reflections and

More information

Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA): common themes and issues arising from five pilot studies.

Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA): common themes and issues arising from five pilot studies. Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA): common themes and issues arising from five pilot studies. Prepared for the Joint World Bank/IMF/DFID PSIA Workshop, October 15-17, 2002 Lucia Hanmer & Barbara

More information

WEC IWRM Seminar Sana a March 2010

WEC IWRM Seminar Sana a March 2010 Components of IWRM study program at WEC and its relevance to water sector in Yemen by Prof. Dr.Abdulla Babaqi WEC IWRM Seminar Sana a 15-16 March 2010 Outline Current situation of the water sector Needs

More information

ASSESSMENT OF BACKWARD AND FORWARD LINKAGES IN INDIAN ECONOMY: AN INPUT-OUTPUT BASED ANALYSIS

ASSESSMENT OF BACKWARD AND FORWARD LINKAGES IN INDIAN ECONOMY: AN INPUT-OUTPUT BASED ANALYSIS CHAPTER 6 ASSESSMENT OF BACKWARD AND FORWARD LINKAGES IN INDIAN ECONOMY: AN INPUT-OUTPUT BASED ANALYSIS 6.1 Introduction Over the years the Indian economy has undergone a structural change in its sectoral

More information

Factors Affecting Cotton Production in Pakistan: Empirical Evidence from Multan District

Factors Affecting Cotton Production in Pakistan: Empirical Evidence from Multan District Volume V, Issue I1, Dec, 2009, pg. 91-100 Factors Affecting Cotton Production in Pakistan: Empirical Evidence from Multan District Imran Sharif Chaudhry, Muhammad Bashir Khan Department of Economics, Bahauddin

More information

Conservation Payments, Liquidity Constraints and Off-Farm Labor: Impact of the Grain for Green Program on Rural Households in China

Conservation Payments, Liquidity Constraints and Off-Farm Labor: Impact of the Grain for Green Program on Rural Households in China Draft: April 12, 2007 Conservation Payments, Liquidity Constraints and Off-Farm Labor: Impact of the Grain for Green Program on Rural Households in China Emi Uchida *,, Scott Rozelle and Jintao Xu Department

More information

Keywords: trade liberalization, edible oil imports, India, CGE, simulation analysis

Keywords: trade liberalization, edible oil imports, India, CGE, simulation analysis Trade Policy Analysis of Edible Oil Imports of India under CGE framework K.M.Shivakumar, S.Kombairaju and M.Chandrasekaran Department of Agricultural Economics, Tamil Nadu Agricultural University, Coimbatore

More information

Boom Before Bust? The Industrial Organization of Groundwater

Boom Before Bust? The Industrial Organization of Groundwater Boom Before Bust? The Industrial Organization of Groundwater Ujjayant Chakravorty and E. Somanathan May 9, 203 Abstract Recent decades have seen an explosion in the drilling of wells and extraction of

More information

IEc. Assessing Economy-wide Effects: An Application of the Methods Paper Recommendations for Uganda s Ministry of Water and Environment

IEc. Assessing Economy-wide Effects: An Application of the Methods Paper Recommendations for Uganda s Ministry of Water and Environment IEc Assessing Economy-wide Effects: An Application of the Methods Paper Recommendations for Uganda s Ministry of Water and Environment Collins Amanya, Uganda MWE Kenneth Strzepek, MIT and Harvard Kennedy

More information

The Basics of Supply and Demand

The Basics of Supply and Demand C H A P T E R 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano CHAPTER 2 OUTLINE 2.1 Supply and Demand 2.2 The Market Mechanism 2.3 Changes in Market Equilibrium 2.4 Elasticities

More information

Efficiency and Equity in Two-Part Tariffs: The Case of Residential Water Rates

Efficiency and Equity in Two-Part Tariffs: The Case of Residential Water Rates DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES EPPP DP No. 2012-08 Efficiency and Equity in Two-Part Tariffs: The Case of Residential Water Rates Simon Porcher December 2012 Chaire Economie des Partenariats Public-Privé Institut

More information

MEMO 27 June District heating and combined heat and power in China

MEMO 27 June District heating and combined heat and power in China MEMO 27 June 2013 File no. Ref. Ole Odgaard Page 1 District heating and combined heat and power in China District heating has expanded rapidly in Northern China since the beginning of the 1990 s. Residential

More information

B. Dayakar Rao*, Deep Narayan Mukherjee and Vilas A. Tonapi. ICAR-Indian Institute of Millets Research, Hyderabad , Telangana.

B. Dayakar Rao*, Deep Narayan Mukherjee and Vilas A. Tonapi. ICAR-Indian Institute of Millets Research, Hyderabad , Telangana. Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 30 (Conference Number) 2017 pp 183-191 DOI: 10.5958/0974-0279.2017.00033.7 Strategies for Doubling Farmers Income in Nutri-Cereals by 2022: Impact of Reduction

More information

Direction of Trade and Export Competitiveness of Chillies in India

Direction of Trade and Export Competitiveness of Chillies in India Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 29 (No.2) July-December 2016 pp 267-272 DOI: 10.5958/0974-0279.2016.00053.7 Direction of Trade and Export Competitiveness of Chillies in India I. Bhavani Devi

More information

Rocky Mountain Power Docket No Witness: Joelle R. Steward BEFORE THE PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF UTAH ROCKY MOUNTAIN POWER

Rocky Mountain Power Docket No Witness: Joelle R. Steward BEFORE THE PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF UTAH ROCKY MOUNTAIN POWER Rocky Mountain Power Docket No. 13-035-184 Witness: Joelle R. Steward BEFORE THE PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF UTAH ROCKY MOUNTAIN POWER Direct Testimony of Joelle R. Steward Cost of Service

More information

Agricultural Policy Development in Thailand

Agricultural Policy Development in Thailand Agricultural Policy Development in Thailand Charuk Singhapreecha Faculty of Economics, Chiang Mai University INTRODUCTION This paper examines the policy transition in various stages of Thailand s economic

More information

MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY AND EFFICIENCY OF POTATO PRODUCTION IN TWO SELECTED AREAS OF BANGLADESH: A TRANSLOG STOCHASTIC FRONTIER ANALYSIS

MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY AND EFFICIENCY OF POTATO PRODUCTION IN TWO SELECTED AREAS OF BANGLADESH: A TRANSLOG STOCHASTIC FRONTIER ANALYSIS Progress. Agric. 21(1 & 2): 233 245, 2010 ISSN 1017-8139 MEASUREMENT OF PRODUCTIVITY AND EFFICIENCY OF POTATO PRODUCTION IN TWO SELECTED AREAS OF BANGLADESH: A TRANSLOG STOCHASTIC FRONTIER ANALYSIS A.

More information

Conservation Pricing and Groundwater Substitution

Conservation Pricing and Groundwater Substitution Conservation Pricing and Groundwater Substitution by Eric C. Schuck Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Colorado State University Fort Collins, CO 80523 and Gareth P. Green Department of

More information

Energy Resources and Policy Handout: Wind power

Energy Resources and Policy Handout: Wind power Energy Resources and Policy Handout: Wind power 1. The Resource Wind energy is very widespread, with mean wind speeds in excess of 5 m/s being quite common. It is not in general a predictable or dependable

More information

Government of Uganda, United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) And World Bank

Government of Uganda, United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) And World Bank Government of Uganda, United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) And World Bank Brief description Project title: The Poverty and Social Impact Analysis (PSIA) of the Proposed National Land Use Policy

More information

Chapter: 1.1 Energy Scenario

Chapter: 1.1 Energy Scenario Chapter: 1.1 Energy Scenario Part-I: Objective type questions and answers 1. The energy sources, that are either found or stored in nature are a) Secondary Energy Sources b) Primary Energy Sources c) both

More information

Gross Domestic Product

Gross Domestic Product Question 1: What is GDP? Answer 1: From a macroperspective, the broadest measure of economic activity is gross domestic product (GDP). GDP represents all the goods and services that are produced within

More information

Temperature extremes, moisture deficiency and their impacts on dryland agriculture in Gujarat, India

Temperature extremes, moisture deficiency and their impacts on dryland agriculture in Gujarat, India Drought: Research and Science-Policy Interfacing Andreu et al. (Eds) 2015 Taylor & Francis Group, London, ISBN 978-1-138-02779-4 Temperature extremes, moisture deficiency and their impacts on dryland agriculture

More information

EFFECTS OF UNILATERAL TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES: Applications of CGE Models of Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka

EFFECTS OF UNILATERAL TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES: Applications of CGE Models of Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka ESCAP SOUTH AND SOUTH-WEST ASIA OFFICE EFFECTS OF UNILATERAL TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES: Applications of CGE Models of Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka Selim Raihan DEVELOPMENT

More information

Input Subsidy vs Farm Technology Which is More Important for Agricultural Development?

Input Subsidy vs Farm Technology Which is More Important for Agricultural Development? Agricultural Economics Research Review Vol. 27 (No.1) January-June 2014 pp 1-18 DOI: 10.5958/j.0974-0279.27.1.001 Input Subsidy vs Farm Technology Which is More Important for Agricultural Development?

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics University of Minnesota June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING AND PRODUCTION ECONOMICS FIELD Instructions: Write your code

More information

Proceedings of the Annual Conference of NEEA held at Dibrugarh, Assam in February POVERTY AND ENVIRONMENTAL DEGRADATION IN RURAL INDIA: A NEXUS

Proceedings of the Annual Conference of NEEA held at Dibrugarh, Assam in February POVERTY AND ENVIRONMENTAL DEGRADATION IN RURAL INDIA: A NEXUS POVERTY AND ENVIRONMENTAL DEGRADATION IN RURAL INDIA: A NEUS Purusottam Nayak Abstract Inspired by the worldwide debate on the issue, the present paper is a humble attempt to test the nexus between poverty

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Jong Kook Shin 1 Chetan Subramanian 2 Abstract This paper extends a simple Schumpeterian growth model to demonstrate that bubbles can generate

More information

6. The law of diminishing marginal returns begins to take effect at labor input level: a. 0 b. X c. Y d. Z

6. The law of diminishing marginal returns begins to take effect at labor input level: a. 0 b. X c. Y d. Z Chapter 5 MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS 1. The short run is defined as a period in which: a. the firm cannot change its output level b. all inputs are variable but technology is fixed c. input prices are fixed

More information

A Study on Farm Households Coping Strategies Against the Impact of Climate Change on Agriculture: A Study in Cuddalore District

A Study on Farm Households Coping Strategies Against the Impact of Climate Change on Agriculture: A Study in Cuddalore District INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF BUSINESS MANAGEMENT, ECONOMICS AND INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY Vol. 3, No. 1, January-June 2011: 151-156 A Study on Farm Households Coping Strategies Against the Impact of Climate Change

More information

Irrigation Reforms in Andhra Pradesh

Irrigation Reforms in Andhra Pradesh Irrigation Reforms in Andhra Pradesh CVSK Sarma Secretary Irrigation, GOAP J. Raymond Peter ED, INPIM 5 th March, Water Week The World Bank, Washington DC Andhra Pradesh Area 0.275 m. Km 2 population (2001)

More information