Market size, technology choice, and market structure

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Market size, technology choice, and market structure"

Transcription

1 Market size, technology choice, and market structure Walter Elberfeld and Georg GÄotz y June 29, 2001 Abstract We introduce technology choice into a model of monopolistic competition and analyze the structural e ects of changes in market size. A larger market leads to the adoption of a large scale technology. If a technology switch occurs, the number of rms decreases, and a rationalizing e ect arises: individual and aggregate output increases; prices fall. This need not bene t consumers since a technology switch is associated with a decrease in product variety. Keywords: technology choice, monopolistic competition, shakeout, variable elasticity of substitution JEL classi cation: L10 Staatswissenschaftliches Seminar, UniversitÄat zu KÄoln, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, D KÄoln, Germany, elberfeld@wiso-r10.wiso.uni-koeln.de y Department of Economics, University of Vienna, BWZ - BrÄunnerstr. 72, A-1210 Vienna, Austria, georg.goetz@univie.ac.at 1

2 1 Introduction Market size and demand growth are key variables in the explanation of market structure, technological change and industry evolution. The size of the market limits the advantages of specialized work and machinery. This relationship was already stated by Adam Smith in his famous theorem that `the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. Increases in demand often induce the adoption of new and usually more specialized technology, which are typically characterized by higher xed costs and lower variable costs. The introduction of a new technology with higher xed costs necessitates a larger rm size. The implications of the technology switch for market structure are, however, ambiguous. On the one hand, non-switching rival rms may lose market share, and perhaps have to exit. This would reduce the number of rms. On the other hand, a larger market can be expected to accommodate a larger number of rms if free entry prevails. Thus, it is not clear, a priori, whether the introduction of a new technology increases or decreases the number of active rms in the market. Empirically, it has been observed that rm numbers rst rise, then later fall, as an industry evolves. In a study of 46 major developing industries, Gort and Klepper (1982) found that most of these markets have experienced some degree of shakeout in the number of rms at some point in their history. In extreme cases the number of producers fell by 90 % or more over 15 to 20 years despite robust growth in output. A number of authors has attempted to explain the phenomenon of industry shakeouts theoretically. For instance, Klepper and Graddy (1990) rely on chance events and exogenous factors. These e ects in uence the number of potential entrants to the industry, the growth rate of incumbents, as well as the ease of imitation of industry leaders and thereby a ect the ultimate number and the size distribution of rms in the industry. Jovanovic and MacDonald (1994) explain a non-monotonic time path in the number of rms using a competitive model in which innovation opportunities fuel entry and relative failure to innovate prompts exit. According to the model of Carree and Thurik (2000), the non- 2

3 monotonicity in rm numbers found in many young industries is a consequence of the gradual decline in unit costs. The common feature of all these papers is that they use a dynamic framework to explain characteristic features of an industry life cycle. In the present article, we propose a static model to answer the question why industry shakeouts can occur. We set out a model of monopolistic competition, in which technology choice is endogenous. Firms are allowed to choose from a binary set of technologies. They may choose either a technology with high xed costs and low marginal costs (largescale technology) or one with low xed but high marginal costs (small-scale technology). Within this framework, we show that technology choice leads to a non-monotonic relation between market size and the number of rms. If market size reaches a critical value and a technology switch occurs, some rms have to exit so that the total number of rms in the industry decreases. By giving an example, we demonstrate that the fall in the number of rms may be drastic. A technology switch and the resulting market consolidation are accompanied by a rationalizing e ect: individual and aggregate output increases; prices fall. Our approach of explaining industry shakeouts can be seen as complementary to the above cited models. Its distinguishing features are the reliance on the importance of demand growth for the adoption of new technologies as well as its simplicity. Both the theoretical and empirical literature on the relationship between market size and market structure is extensive; see, for example, Schmalensee (1989), and Scherer and Ross (1990). Among the most important work, using a static model, has been done by Shaked and Sutton (1987), and Sutton (1991), (1998). Sutton (1991) has argued that the relationship between market size and concentration varies between industries, depending on the existence of exogenous or endogenous sunk costs. Using an oligopolistic model of vertical product di erentiation, he showed that the traditional growth-entry mechanism may not work in industries in which advertising and/or R&D outlays play an important role. Neumann et al. (2001) have analyzed a static Cournot oligopoly with homogenous prod- 3

4 ucts to relate horizontal concentration to market size and xed costs. Assuming that higher xed costs yield a lower level of marginal costs, a vertical and horizontally growing market is shown to cause horizontal concentration to decline if there is free entry. Both Sutton (1991) and Neumann et al. (2001) use a continuous set of technologies from which rms can choose. This implies that their models do not exhibit the drastic nonmonotonicity in rm numbers, which is an important feature of our model, where the technology set is discrete. Whether the process of technology adoption in an industry is better described by continuous or discrete opportunity sets, is ultimately an empirical question. While the assumption of a continuous set is more appropriate if innovations result from a large number of small changes, discrete sets should be assumed if the improvement in productivity results from major technological breakthroughs. The market model we use is a derivation of the Dixit/Stiglitz (1977) model of monopolistic competition. However, rather than restricting ourselves to the well-known and often used case of a utility function yielding a constant elasticity of substitution (CES), we consider the more general case of variable elasticity of substitution (VES) proposed by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). Contrary to the CES-speci cation, the VES-case exhibits the comforting feature of a negative relationship between the number of rms and the price they charge. The "large group" assumption (Chamberlin, 1965) underlying the market structure of monopolistic competition ensures virtually no strategic interaction among rms. Yet, individual rms have monopoly power because they produce a special brand of a differentiated product. The former feature allows us to focus on the e±ciency argument, that is the cost minimization argument, for a technology switch. By the latter feature, we capture the market power e ects of a technology switch. In view of the trade-o between productive e±ciency and product variety, our welfare analysis answers the question whether rms make e±cient technological choices in the decentralized solution. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the framework, and characterizes the free entry equilibrium. In Section 3, we analyze the e ect of changes in market size. In Section 4, we brie y investigate social welfare. Section 5 concludes. 4

5 2 The framework We consider an industry in which a continuum of potential rms exists. The market structure is assumed to be monopolistically competitive, and entry into the industry is free. A rm can choose between two available technologies, S and L, forproducingits variety. Technology S entails low xed costs, f S, and high (constant) marginal costs, c S. Technology L exhibits high xed costs, f L, but low (constant) marginal costs, c L.Thus, we have f S <f L and c S >c L. Each active rm produces a single, unique variety of a di erentiated product. Therefore, the measure of rms equals the measure of brands available to the consumers. For simplicity, we refer to this measure as the "number of rms". The measure (number) of consumers is A. Each consumer maximizes the quasi-linear utility function of the form U = y + bc e =e 0 <e<1; (1) where y denotes the quantity of a numeraire. The consumption index C is of the Dixit- Stiglitz (1977) type and de ned as C = µz n where x(j) is the quantity consumed of variety j, and 0 v(x (j)) dj 1= 0 < <1; (2) v (x (j)) = ( k + mx(j) for x>0 0 for x =0 (3) with k 0andm>0. This functional form is proposed by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) as an example of a function which entails variable elasticity of substitution (VES) between any two varieties. The well known CES-speci cation arises as a special case, if k =0and m = 1. As will become clear below, the VES-speci cation has certain advantages over the CES-speci cation. Aside from being more general, it implies the intuitive feature that an increasing number of rms leads to lower prices. The budget constraint reads as y + Z n 0 p (j) x (j) dj = I; (4) 5

6 where I denotes the consumer's income and p(j) is the price of variety j. We assume that income is large, so that the numeraire will always be demanded by the consumer. A consumer's demand for variety i takes the form µz n e x(i) = k=m +(m e b) 1 1 e p(j) e 1 dj p(i) 1 1 : (5) 0 Since b and k in (5) are arbitrary constants, without loss of generality, we can set m =1. Furthermore, we de ne B = b 1=(1 e) and P = µz n 0 p(j) 1 dj ( 1)= ; where P denotes the Dixit-Stiglitz price index. With these de nitions, overall demand for variety i denoted by X(i) can be written as X(i) =Ax(i) =A ³ k + BP 1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) p(i) 1=(1 ) ; (6) which is a standard demand function with a nite cut-o price. The supplier of variety i treats P as a constant, and so perceives a demand elasticity of j (1 ) 1 f(p i )j( k + f(p i )) 1,wheref(p i )=BP 1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) p(i) 1=(1 ). Observe that the price sensitivity of demand increases with k, sothatitislowest,ifk = 0. In this case (CES-case), the elasticity of demand is a constant and equal to (1 ) 1. Finally, note that demand of a rm would be a decreasing function of P and thus a decreasing functions of the rivals' prices, if e>. In this case, the di erentiated goods would be complements rather than substitutes. To exclude this case, we assume e<. 2.1 Prices and pro ts Suppose that an industry structure has emerged, where n S rms produce with technology S (S- rms), and n L with technology L (L- rms). Firms' pro ts depend on the chosen technology. The pro t function of rm i, who chooses technology j, isgivenby (i) =(p(i) c j )X(i) f j ; j 2fS; Lg: (7) Firms maximize pro ts by choosing a price p i. A price equilibrium, where rms with the same technology choose the same price, must solve the following two rst order conditions: 6

7 0 k BP1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) ( p i c i )p (2 )=( 1) i A =0; i = S; L: (8) 1 In (8), the price index P can be computed as 1 P = ³ n S p =(1 ) S + n L p =(1 ) (1 )= L : If k = 0 (CES-case), we obtain the familiar pricing rule p i = c i =, which is independent of the number of rms. On the other hand, if k>0 (VES-case), the equilibrium prices p S and p L are decreasing functions of n S and n L. The fact, that prices decrease with the number of rms is a desirable and plausible feature of the model. It states that entry of new rms leads to more competition, resulting in lower prices. Since a rms's perceived elasticity of demand is increasing in k, prices in the VES-case are always lower than in the CES-case. Substituting p S and p L into (7) yields the equilibrium pro ts S = A (p S c S ) ³ k + Bp S 1 1+ P 1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) f L (9) for a rm using technology S, and L = A (p L c L ) ³ k + Bp L 1 1+ P 1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) f L (10) for a rm using technology L. 2.2 Entry and technology choice For any given industry structure (n S ;n L ), the equilibrium prices are functions of (n S ;n L ). Thus, reduced form pro ts are functions of the numbers of rms, ¼ i = ¼ i (n S ;n L ), i = S; L. Of course, an arbitrary industry structure need not represent an equilibrium state. If a rm using technology S can improve its pro ts by switching to technology L, itwantsto use technology L. Likewise, a rm using technology L maywanttoswitchtotechnology S. Thus, an equilibrium (industry) structure must satisfy the following no-switching condition: ¼ S (n S ;n L )=¼ L (n S ;n L ): (11) 7

8 Moreover, since entry into the market is free, in equilibrium the pro ts in (11) must be zero. Proposition 1 In equilibrium, all rms will (almost) always choose the same technology. 1 Proof see Appendix. According to Proposition 1, only two types of equilibrium structures can arise. One where all rms use technology S, and one where all rms produce with technology L. The outcome where S- rms and L- rms coexist can arise only as a knife-edge case. The non-existence of equilibrium structures with heterogeneous rms is due to our assumption that the market is monopolistically competitive. 2 In such a market, agents are `small', so that a single rm, when it switches from one technology to another, does not a ect the pro ts of its rivals. Therefore, the no-switching condition (11) requires that pro ts of all rms are exactly the same. This implies that equilibrium structures with heterogeneous rms, can arise only on a set with measure zero. 3 When agents are `large', a switch of technology by one rm in general a ects the pro ts of all rms, including those of the switching rm. Thus, an equilibrium is possible in which the pro ts of the two di erent types are di erent. In fact, this would happen if the switch to a more pro table technology reduced the pro ts of the latter type so much that the rm is better o by not switching. 4 To obtain further insight into the determinants of technology choice implied by Proposition 1, it is instructive to consider the special CES-case (k = 0). In this case, the 1 Exceptions can occur only on a parameter set of measure zero. 2 Using a model with monopolistic competition, Grossman and Helpman (1999) obtain a similar knifeedge result with respect to vertical integration. 3 The assumption of `small' agents also leads to robustness of the equilibrium with respect to the modes of entry and the timing structure of the model. It is irrelevant whether rms decide about entry, technology and pricing simultaneously or sequentially. As entry deterrence cannot occur, it does not matter whether rms enter simultaneously or sequentially. With `large' agents, for instance in a Cournot oligopoly, all these di erences lead to di erent results (see, for instance, Brander and Spencer (1983) and Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980) for issues regarding the timing structure, and McLean and Riordan (1989) for entry deterrence). 4 see Mills and Smith (1996), Elberfeld (2001) and GÄotz (2001). 8

9 no-switching and the zero-pro t conditions can be satis ed if, and only if, := ( c L c S ) 1 f S f L =0: (12) If <0 only L- rms are active, whereas only S- rms are active if >0. 5 This implies that technology choice depends on the cost structure in a way one would expect. The use of a particular technology is more likely the smaller its marginal or xed costs. Another determinant of technology choice is the degree of product di erentiation measured by the parameter. A market in which the nal goods are close substitutes ( close to 1) is likely to be one where rms use the technology, which entails lower marginal costs. The reason is that close substitutability makes pro ts highly sensitive to relative prices, and so the lower prices and the economies of scale associated with technology L become more important. 3 E ects of increasing market size In this section we analyze the structural e ects of changes in market size A. In the CEScase the answer to this question is simple. If k = 0, technology choice is independent of market size. Formally, this is an immediate consequence of the fact that A does not enter the parameter. Since rms use a mark-up pricing rule, which is independent of the number of rms, individual outputs do not change with market size. Otherwise, pro ts could not be kept at zero. Thus, if market size increases, the rise in aggregate output is solely caused by an increase in the number of rms. The VES{case is more complicated and more interesting. If k>0, individual prices are decreasing in the number of rms, implying that individual output increases with market size. A higher output provides an incentive to incur xed costs in order to lower marginal costs. Thus, in order to realize economies of scale, one should expect rms to choose the L{technology, when the market becomes su±ciently large. 5 In the general case, we can not calculate the dividing hyperplane, because the pricing rule can not be explicitly determined. 9

10 Proposition 2 For any market sizes A 1 >A 2 such that di erent technologies are used L is used in A 1 and S in A 2. Proof see Appendix. Proposition 2 con rms our intuition that in larger markets rms adopt technologies, which allow them to better achieve economies of scale. It may, however, be the case that technology S is used independently of market size. To understand this, recall that in the borderline case k = 0 individual output, and therefore technology choice, is independent of market size A (see (12)). If k is greater than zero, output per rm increases with A so that, in general, for market size su±ciently large, the adoption of the large scale technology becomes pro table. We cannot exclude, however, that for positive, but small k the increase in individual output due to increases in market size is too small to induce aswitchintechnology. Next, we explore the e ect of a technology switch on the equilibrium structure of the industry. Proposition 3 Suppose that due to an increase in market size a technology switch occurs. Then, prices and the number of rms decrease, whereas individual and aggregate output increases. Proof see Appendix. Propositions 2 and 3 provide us with the following story of the evolution of an industry. If demand is small, the level of production is too small to support technologies which rely on highly specialized equipment. Firms, therefore, use small scale technologies. However, as the market grows, the number of rms and output per rm increases. With increasing rm size, rms are better able to achieve scale economies. As a result, they may adopt a technology with higher xed costs and lower marginal costs. If a technology switch occurs, some rms will exit. The market wide adoption of the large scale technology entails a rationalizing e ect: individual and aggregate output increase; prices fall. 10

11 All these properties are described as stylized facts for the U.S. automobile tire industry by Jovanovic and MacDonald (1994, p. 324). Furthermore, the shakeout which took place in that industry is explained as the result of a single technological improvement, which is also the driving force in our model. Our approach di ers from the one Jovanovic and MacDonald (1994) in that the passing of a critical market size rather than the random arrival of a new technology causes the shakeout. Our explanation relates to the `demand pull' theory of technical change: Increases in demand induce the introduction of new technology. 6 The results of a simulation, presented in Figures 1-5, show in more detail how industry evolution looks like in our framework. The parameters used are =0:5;c L =1;c S =2;f L =50;f S =20;k =1;b = 100;e=0:25: (13) n A 7 A SB 12 A Figure 1. The equilibrium number of rms (strong line) and the second-best 7 (dashed line) number of rms as a function of market size. 6 For a survey of the 'demand pull' theory of technical change see Thirtle and Ruttan, The second-best criterion requires that rms break even. See Section 4 for a discussion of the welfare properties. 11

12 p A 7 A SB 12 A 2 Figure 2. The equilibrium price (strong line) and the second-best (dashed line) price as a function of market size. x A 7 A SB 12 A Figure 3. The equilibrium output per rm (strong line) and the second-best (dashed line) output per rm as a function of market size. Aggregate Output A Figure 4. Aggregate output of the di erentiated product, i.e. nx, as a function of market size. 12

13 Aggregate Expenditure A 7 A SB 12 A Figure 5. Aggregate expenditure for the di erentiated product, i.e. pnx, as a function of market size. As long as market size is smaller than A =4:5, all rms use the small scale technology S. However, if market size reaches the critical value A, all rms adopt technology L. The technology switch leads to a decline in the number of rms (see Figure 1), from n S =98:7 ton L =56:2, an increase in individual output (see Figure 2), from X S =15:8 to X L =57:8. Price declines from p S =3:3 top L =1:9. As c L =1andc S = 2, (relative) markups and price-cost margins (de ned as (p c)=p) increase. The diagrams relating to variables for the whole industry show that the fall in the number of rms is more than compensated by the rise in individual output. Industry output increases from to (Figure 4). The lower prices induce consumers to spend more on the variants of the di erentiated product, implying an increase in aggregate expenditure from to (Figure 5). With further increases of A, the number of rms rises again, price decreases further, outputs and aggregate expenditure increase further. 8 A notable feature of the model is the extent of the change in the number of rms. In the example, the number of rms decreases by as much as 40 percent. Thus, our model is able to generate severe shakeouts, as they are found in the life cycle of many industries (see, for instance, Klepper and Graddy (1990)). 8 Although our analysis is restricted to the case of two alternative technologies, one can imagine, that the presence of a third technology with smaller marginal costs than c L = 1 and larger xed costs than f L = 50, would generate another switch point A >A, at which the number of rms would jump down again. Thus, the speci c path of rm numbers is likely to be very sensitive to the set of available technologies. In contrast, outputs and prices are always monotonic functions of market size. 13

14 Our model sheds new light on a recent contribution by Neumann et al. (2001). These authors examine the relationship between market size and market structure in a Cournot oligopoly, where rms, by investing in R & D, generate process innovations. They show that larger markets induce both more process innovations and an increase in the number of rms. Neumann et al. argue that the elasticity of the number of rms with respect to market size should be between.5 and 1. Our analysis suggests that their upper bound is sensitive to the speci cation of their model. This can be most easily seen by considering the CES-case. If A increases by a factor t, the number of rms increases by more than t. The increase in the number of rms leads to a decrease of the price index P and thus to increased aggregate expenditure even though individual prices are constant. Thus, as long as the elasticity of the aggregate demand for the di erentiated product is greater than 1, i.e. e>0, the number of rms rises more than proportional. Our model puts also the lower bound into doubt. The non-monotonicity result of Proposition 3 shows that the number of rms might even fall. Neumann et al. estimate an elasticity of the number of rms with respect to market size (denoted by B in their model) of about.5 for a cross-section of 291 German manufacturing industries. Furthermore, 'estimates for individual industries from the balanced sample... indicate substantial di erences in the size of B across markets' (Neumann et al., 2001, p. 835). In view of our results, these di erences across industries are not surprising. In general, technological opportunities di er among industries. Therefore, di erent industries should be expected to move along di erent technological trajectories, implying diverse relationships between market size and market structure. A nal point we want to discuss in this section concerns the relationship between market size and competition. Asplund and Sandin (1999) argue that 'competition intensi es with market size' (p. 70). They use variable pro ts per capita as a measure of competition. In our model increasing market size leads to more competition in the sense of lower prices and lower price-cost margins in the regions where no technology switch occurs. However, comparing points just to the right and to the left of A in our example shows that market 14

15 power increases with market size in the sense that price-cost margins increase. 9 At the same time, prices continue to fall. Interestingly, this prediction ts quite well with some empirical results of Asplund and Sandin. They also obtain the result that prices in a large market (a duopoly, in their case) are lower than in a small market (with a monopoly rm), while pro ts are higher in the large market. They try to explain this 'unreasonable' result by referring to higher xed cost (in the duopoly case) giving lower marginal costs (p. 80). 4 Comparing market outcomes to the second best: an example In this section, we brie y analyze social welfare. We ask whether the technology choice in the market solution coincides with that of a social planner. As a welfare criterion we use the Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) second best solution, where rms must break even. Since free entry leads to zero pro ts of all rms, social welfare coincides with consumers' surplus: CS A(U I) = 1 e ABP e 1 e + Ak(nL p L + n S p S ): (14) e In the derivation of the r.h.s we used the indirect utility function and the budget constraint. The planner's optimization problem consists of maximizing consumers' surplus (see 14) subject to the zero-pro t conditions for the rms. For the CES-case, technology choice in the decentralized solution coincides with the choice of the social planner. The reason is that, in the market solution, individual output is the same as the socially optimal one (see Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977 and Beath and Katsoulacos, 1991). Given that rms are cost-minimizing, technology choices must coincide. Figure 1 shows that the technology choice of the social planner, in general, does not coincide with the market solution. It indicates that the second-best solution puts variety before economies of scale. There are more and smaller rms than in the market solution. The switch to the large scale technology occurs at a greater value of A (A SB =9:60). As 9 In our example the price-cost margin (p c)=p increases from 39% to 46%. 15

16 a result, prices are higher and rm output is smaller in the second-best solution compared to the market solution (see Figures 2 and 3). The fact that the planner's and the decentralised technology choice do not coincide has important consequences for the evaluation of the technology switch in the market solution. The switch causes a reduction in welfare. To see this, note that at A the price index P is the same irrespective of the technology used. It follows from (14) that consumers prefer a situation with many (small) rms charging high prices over a scenario with a small number of rms charging low prices. Thus, we obtain a seemingly surprising result that although a technology switch leads to lower prices and greater aggregate output, welfare decreases. The reason is that the loss in product variety resulting from a decrease in the number of rms dominates the gains from the improvements in productive e±ciency implied by the rationalizing e ect. This result sheds an interesting light on the evolution, for instance, of the retail sector. The superseding of corner shops by a much smaller number of supermarkets can be seen as a technology switch from a small-scale to a large scale technology. Our results show that, at least initially, this kind of structural change need not be an improvement from a social point of view. It takes quite an increase in market size (in our example until A = 9:10!) until the e±ciency gains of the large-scale technology dominate the loss in product variety. A further consequence of a technology switch is that trade liberalization need not be welfare improving for all countries. To see this, note that in our example a consumer's surplus, i.e. utility per head, is the same in a country of size A ~ =4:05, in which only the S-technology is used, and in a country of size A =4:53, in which the L-technology is used. If a country of size A 2 [ A; ~ A ) were to open up free trade with a (small) country of size A A, welfare in the former country would decrease due to the technology switch. In our example, the maximum welfare loss, incurred by a country of size A, which is joined by country of size ", amounts to 4:7% of the utility level before the technology switch. A welfare loss cannot arise if the size of the integrated economy is greater than A =5:00. 16

17 5 Conclusions In this paper we have investigated the relationship between market size and market structure, when technology choice is endogenous. Our framework yields a simple and fairly intuitive explanation for the phenomenon of industry shakeouts. An increase in the market size induces entry, and thus more competition. A smaller mark-up requires a larger output in order to cover the xed costs. With increasing production the switch to a large scale technology may become pro table. We showed that a technology switch always leads to a reduction in the number of active rms and is accompanied by a rationalizing e ect (individual and aggregate output increase). Our paper highlights also the welfare implications of the often severe structural change associated with growth. We showed that consumers need not bene t from a switch in technology. The reason is that the loss in product variety resulting from a decrease in the number of rms may dominate the gains from the improvements in productive e±ciency implied by the rationalizing e ect. Appendix Proof of Proposition 1 In equilibrium, we must have ¼ S (n S ;n L )=¼ L (n S ;n L )=0: (15) where ¼ S and ¼ L take the values given in (9) and (10), respectively. Now, suppose that the pair (¹n L ; ¹n S ) satis es these conditions, and de ne K ¹n L p L 1+ +¹nS p S 1+. Then, each element of the set Z = n (n L ;n S ):n L 2 h i 0; Kp L 1 ;ns = ³ K n L p L 1 ps 1 o (16) satis es (15), and therefore constitutes an equilibrium structure. Since all (n S ;n L ) 2 Z involve the same price index P = K (1 )=, the equilibrium prices p S and p L are constant on Z. To show that the set of parameters for which coexistence occurs has measure zero, consider the xed cost parameter f L associated with a particular equilibrium. Suppose 17

18 there exist other values of f L such that the conditions in (15) are satis ed. Since (n S ; 0) 2 Z, the zero-pro t condition ¼ S (n S ; 0) = 0 must be satis ed. Obviously, neither the equilibrium number n S nor the equilibrium price p S depend on f L. It follows that K = n S p S 1+ does not depend on fl either. The fact that K is independent of f L implies that that equilibrium prices and numbers of rms are independent of f L,forany(n S ;n L ) 2 Z. However, as (0;n L ) 2 Z, this is a contradiction, since the zero-pro t condition ¼ L (0;n L )= 0 is a function of f L. 2 Proof of Proposition 2 We proof the Proposition by contradiction. Suppose, contrary to the Proposition, that at A 1 technology S is used and technology L at A 2. Then, (0;n L ) satis es the no-switching and no-entry conditions ¼ S (0;n L ) <¼ L (0;n L ) = 0 (17) at A 2,wheren L denotes the equilibrium number of L{ rms. By de nition of n L we know that d L (0;n L )=da = 0. We prove that for all A>A 2 technology L is used. For this to hold, it su±ces to show that the total derivative d¼ S da à S L @n ; (18) if evaluated at (0;n L ), is negative. Note that the third term in brackets is zero, since due to the envelope S =@p S = 0. Next, we calculate the various partial derivatives in (18). Using the implicit-function theorem, we obtain from the free-entry condition = (1 e) n L µ 1 ³ e +e 1+Bkp L 1 nl p L 1+ A ( e) Substituting p L into the rst-order condition (8), and using the implicit-function theorem, (19) L = ( e) p L (c L p L L n L ((2 e) c L p L ) (20) The partial derivatives of S with respect to A, p S and n S can be easily inferred from (9). Substituting all these derivatives into (18), we obtain, after some tedious calculations: d¼ S (0;n L ) da = (p S c S )h (1 )((2 e)c L p L ) ; (21) 18

19 where h = B ( e) ³ e e 1 n L p L 1+ (c L p L ) p S 1+ k (1 ) ((2 e)c L p L ) +k (1 e)(p L =p S ) 1 1 ((2 )cl p L ) : Note that p L c L < 0 (see the main text). Thus, the sign of (21) is negative if and only if h<0. This inequality is certainly ful lled if, in h, wereplacetheterm(p L =p S ) 1 1 (< 1) by 1. The resulting inequality can be transformed into ( e) (c L p L ) µ k + BP e p 1+ S < 0 (22) This inequality holds, since >e, p L <c L =, and demand of each consumer (third term) is positive. We have shown that if technology L is used at A 2 it is also used at A 1 >A 2. A contradiction! 2 Proof of Proposition 3 The starting point of the proof is the fact that for A = A we obtain a knife-edge solution. If A = A, the following equations hold: L (0;n L )= S (0;n L ) and S (n S ; 0) = L (n S ; 0): (23) The left equation in (23) states that (0;n L ) constitutes an equilibrium structure, while the right equation says that (n S ; 0) is an equilibrium. From the proof of Proposition 1 we know that the price index in both equilibrium structures must be the same. It follows that n L p =( 1) L = n S p =( 1) S : (24) Using the implicit function theorem, the rst order condition for any rm type i in (8) implies that p i increases with c i. Thus, since c L <c S, it follows that p L <p S. This shows that prices fall, when a technology switch occurs. The inequality p L <p S and (24) imply that n L <n S, i. e. a technology switch leads to a decrease in the number of rms. It remains to be shown that aggregate output increases. n L X L >n S X S is equivalent to ( n L p 1=(1 ) L n S p 1=(1 ) S )P 1=(1 ) 1=(1 e) + k(n S n L ) > 0: (25) 19

20 Since n S >n L, (25) holds, if the rst term is positive, or equivalently, if (n L =n S ) 1 > p L =p S. We know that P = n (1 )= S p S = n (1 )= L p L so that (n L =n S ) (1 )= = p L =p S. The observation that (n L =n S ) 1 > (n L =n S ) (1 )= completes the proof. 2 Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Susanne Wied-Nebbeling, Gerhard Clemenz, the referees, the participants of the joint seminar of the University of Leipzig and the HHL, and the participants at the 1999 meetings of the Austrian Economic Association in Linz and of the German Economic Association in Mainz for helpful comments and discussions. References Asplund, M. and R. Sandin (1999), 'The Number of Firms and Production Capacity in Relation to Market Size', Journal of Industrial Economics 47, Beath, J. and Y. Katsoulacos (1991), The Economic Theory of Product Di erentiation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Brander, J.A. and B.J. Spencer (1983), 'Strategic Commitment with R&D: The Symmetric Case', Bell Journal of Economics 14, Carree, M.A. and A.R. Thurik (2000), 'The Life Cycle of the U.S. Tire Industry', Southern Economic Journal 67, Chamberlin, E.H. (1965), The Theory of Monopolistic Competition (8th ed.), Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Ma. Dasgupta, P. and J.E. Stiglitz (1980), 'Industrial Structure and the Nature of Innovative Activity', Economic Journal 90, Dixit, A.K. and J.E. Stiglitz (1977), 'Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity', American Economic Review 67, Elberfeld, W. (2001), 'Explaining Intraindustry Di erences in the Extent of Vertical Integration', Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, forthcoming. GÄotz, G. (2001), 'Non-existence of Free Entry Cournot Equilibrium: The Importance 20

21 of Market Size and Technology Choice', mimeo, University of Vienna. Gort, M. and S. Klepper (1982), 'Time Paths in the Di usion of Product Innovations', Economic Journal 92, Grossman, G.M. and E. Helpman (1999), 'Incomplete Contracts and Industrial Organization', NBER Working Paper No Jovanovic, B. and G.M. MacDonald (1994), 'The Life Cycle of a Competitive Industry', Journal of Political Economy 102, Klepper, S. and E. Graddy (1990), 'The evolution of new industries and the determinants of market structure', Rand Journal of Economics 21, McLean, R.P. and M.H. Riordan, (1989), 'Industry Structure with Sequential Technology Choice', Journal of Economic Theory 47, Mills, D.E. and W. Smith (1996), 'It Pays to Be Di erent: Endogenous Heterogeneity of Firms in an Oligopoly', International Journal of Industrial Organization 14, Neumann, M., J. Weigand, A. Gross and M.T. MÄunter (2001), 'Market Size, Fixed Costs and Horizontal Concentration', International Journal of Industrial Organization 19, Scherer, F.M. and D. Ross (1990), Industrial market structure and economic performance (3rd ed.), Houghton, Boston, Mass. Schmalensee, R. (1989), 'Inter-Industry Studies of Structure and Performance', in: Schmalensee, R. and R.D. Willig (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume II, North-Holland, Amsterdam, New York. Shaked, A. and J. Sutton (1987), 'Product Di erentiation and Industrial Structure', Journal of Industrial Economics 36, Sutton, J. (1991), Sunk Costs and Market Structure, MIT Press, Cambridge, Ma. Sutton, J. (1998), Technology and Market Structure: Theory and History, MITPress, Cambridge, Ma. Thirtle, C.G. and V.W. Ruttan (1987), The Role of Demand and Supply in the Generation and Di usion of Technical Change, Harwood Academic Publishers, Chur, London. 21

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design Ricardo Cavalcanti Getulio Vargas Foundation Ed Nosal Cleveland Fed November 006 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We describe counterfeiting activity

More information

Entry and Merger Policy

Entry and Merger Policy 7 85 October 07 Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux, Yassine Lefouili and Wilfried Sand Zantman Entry and Merger Policy Laure Jaunaux y Yassine Lefouili z Wilfried Sand-Zantman x August 07 Abstract This

More information

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING In many economic situations, there exists asymmetric information between the di erent agents. Examples are abundant: A seller has better information

More information

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity Countervailing Power and Product Diversity by Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Work in Progress December 6, 2003 Abstract To analyse the effects of countervailing power on product variety, I construct a

More information

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues Matthias Kräkel, University of Bonn Abstract We discuss the optimal sharing of broadcasting revenues given a central marketing system. The league s sports association

More information

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms

Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Dynamic Price Discrimination With Asymmetric Firms Yongmin Chen Department of Economics University of Colorado Boulder, CO 80309 September 2006 Abstract. This paper considers variants of a dynamic duopoly

More information

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy Emmanuel Petrakis and Anastasios Xepapadeas University of Crete This paper analyzes and compares delocation decisions

More information

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1007 Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model Winfried Koeniger Omar Licandro February 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Nonlinear pricing of a congestible network good. Abstract

Nonlinear pricing of a congestible network good. Abstract Nonlinear pricing of a congestible network good haïreddine Jebsi LEGI, Ecole Polytechnique, La Marsa and Faculté de Droit et des Sciences Economiques et Politiques de Sousse, Tunisia Lionel Thomas CRESE,

More information

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

Competition in Two-Sided Markets Competition in Two-Sided Markets Mark Armstrong Department of Economics University College London August 2002: revised May 2005 Abstract There are many examples of markets involving two groups of agents

More information

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation Roman Inderst y Zlata Jakubovic z Dragan Jovanovic x November 2013 Abstract Our analysis starts from the observation that with progressive consolidation

More information

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Lisa Planer-Friedrich Otto-Friedrich-Universität Bamberg Marco Sahm Otto-Friedrich-Universität Bamberg and CESifo This Version: June 15, 2015 Abstract We examine

More information

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth David Gill Division of Economics University of Southampton John Thanassoulis Dept. of Economics & Christ Church

More information

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects Krina Griva Nikolaos Vettas February 005 Abstract We examine price competition under product-specific network effects, in a

More information

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics Annual Report Endogenous R&D investment when learning and technological distance affects absorption capacity Author: Jorge Luis Paz Panizo

More information

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION THE JOURNAL O INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 00-181 Volume LVII June 009 No. Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/ PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION LEVENT KUTLU

More information

Discussion Paper No. 16. Platform Ownership. Volker Nocke* Martin Peitz** Konrad Stahl*** July 2004

Discussion Paper No. 16. Platform Ownership. Volker Nocke* Martin Peitz** Konrad Stahl*** July 2004 Discussion Paper No. 16 Platform Ownership Volker Nocke* Martin Peitz** Konrad Stahl*** July 2004 *Volker Nocke, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 3718 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA

More information

Question Collection. European Competition Policy Chair of Economic Policy

Question Collection. European Competition Policy Chair of Economic Policy Question Collection European Competition Policy Chair of Economic Policy Question 1: - Perfect Competition Suppose a perfect competitive market where all firms produce a homogenous good. Assume the cost

More information

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS*

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 0022-1821 Volume XLVIII December 2000 No. 4 INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS* Joseph Farrell{ and Michael L. Katz{ We consider innovation

More information

Vertical Pricing and Parallel Imports

Vertical Pricing and Parallel Imports Vertical Pricing and Parallel Imports Yongmin Chen Keith E. Maskus Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder July 2000 Abstract: When a manufacturer (or trademark owner) sells its product

More information

Two Lectures on Information Design

Two Lectures on Information Design Two Lectures on nformation Design 10th DSE Winter School Stephen Morris December 2015 nformation Design Usually in information economics, we ask what can happen for a xed information structure... nformation

More information

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series ISSN 1791-3144 University of Macedonia Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series International Environmental Agreements: An emission choice model with abatement technology Eftichios Sartzetakis and

More information

Should the Government Protect its Basic Research?

Should the Government Protect its Basic Research? MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Should the Government Protect its Basic Research? Guido Cozzi and Silvia Galli June 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/79622/ MPRA Paper No. 79622, posted

More information

Technology-Skill Complementarity

Technology-Skill Complementarity Technology-Skill Complementarity Nancy L. Stokey University of Chicago October 16, 2015 Becker Conference Stokey (University of Chicago) TSC 10/2015 1 / 35 Introduction This paper studies a simple general

More information

Search and Categorization

Search and Categorization MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Search and Categorization Chaim Fershtman and Arthur Fishman and Jidong Zhou Tel Aviv University, Bar-Ilan University, NYU Stern December 03 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5366/

More information

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly EconS 425 - Perfect Competition and Monopoly Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market Qihong Liu Jie Shuai January 18, 2014 Abstract Advancing in information technology has empowered firms with unprecedented flexibility when interacting

More information

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment James R. Markusen University of Colorado, Boulder University College Dublin ETH Zurich May

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors gratefully acknowledge

More information

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Cardiff Economics Working Papers Cardiff Economics Working Papers Working Paper No. E016/3 Gains from Variety? Product Differentiation and the Possibility of Losses from rade under Cournot Oligopoly with Free Entry David R. Collie pril

More information

Consumers Shopping Costs as a Cause of Slotting Fees: A Rent-Shifting Mechanism

Consumers Shopping Costs as a Cause of Slotting Fees: A Rent-Shifting Mechanism Consumers Shopping Costs as a Cause of Slotting Fees: A Rent-Shifting Mechanism Preliminary Version Stéphane Caprice y Vanessa von Schlippenbach z 2010 Abstract This paper explains the emergence of slotting

More information

Imperfect competition, productivity differences and proximity-concentration trade-offs

Imperfect competition, productivity differences and proximity-concentration trade-offs Ekonomia nr 40/2015 7 Imperfect competition, productivity differences and proximity-concentration trade-offs Andrzej Cieślik * Abstract In this paper we study how productivity differences between foreign

More information

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1 M. Soledad Arellano 2 and Pablo Serra 3 Universidad de Chile July 2007 1 The authors acknowledge nancial support

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Jong Kook Shin 1 Chetan Subramanian 2 Abstract This paper extends a simple Schumpeterian growth model to demonstrate that bubbles can generate

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia February 15, 2014 Abstract We analyze two unexplored aspects of the Wolinsky model (Wolinsky (1986)

More information

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture nformation Design: Murat Sertel Lecture stanbul Bilgi University: Conference on Economic Design Stephen Morris July 2015 Mechanism Design and nformation Design Mechanism Design: Fix an economic environment

More information

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition 13-1 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY Monopolistic Competition Pure monopoly and perfect competition are rare in the real world. Most real-world industries

More information

Pricing of delivery services and the emergence of marketplace platforms

Pricing of delivery services and the emergence of marketplace platforms IDEI 865 August 2016 Pricing of delivery services and the emergence of marketplace platforms Claire Borsenberger, Helmuth Cremer, Denis Joram and Jean Marie Lozachmeur 7 Pricing of delivery services and

More information

Reading: "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity" by A. Dixit and J. Stiglitz in AER (1977)

Reading: Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity by A. Dixit and J. Stiglitz in AER (1977) Reading: "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity" by A. Dixit and J. Stiglitz in AER (1977)...a workhorse for economics Rosella Nicolini First version: April 2011 This version: January

More information

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation Roman Inderst and Zlata Jakubovic and Dragan Jovanovic January 2015 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/61214/

More information

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - First-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41 Introduction

More information

Coalitions and Networks in Industrial Organization

Coalitions and Networks in Industrial Organization Coalitions and Networks in Industrial Organization Francis Bloch May 28, 2001 1 Introduction Recent years have witnessed a surge of interest in the formation of coalitions and networks in Industrial Organization.

More information

CARF Working Paper CARF-F-222. Exclusive Dealing and the Market Power of Buyers

CARF Working Paper CARF-F-222. Exclusive Dealing and the Market Power of Buyers CARF Working Paper CARF-F-222 Exclusive Dealing and the Market Power o Buyers Ryoko Oki Graduate School o Economics, University o Tokyo Noriyuki Yanagawa University o Tokyo July 2010 CARF is presently

More information

Loss Leader or Low Margin Leader? Advertising

Loss Leader or Low Margin Leader? Advertising Loss Leader or Low Margin Leader? Advertising And The Degree of Product Di erentiation Witness Simbanegavi y 18 August 008 Abstract This paper isolates the conditions that give rise to loss leader pricing.

More information

Market exit and lobby participation with heterogeneous rms

Market exit and lobby participation with heterogeneous rms Market exit and lobby participation with heterogeneous rms Vincent Rebeyrol and Julien Vauday y z May 9, 2006 Abstract Very preliminary Version, Comments are welcome We would like to specially thank Elisabeth

More information

Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage"

Web Appendix to Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage" Meredith L. Fowlie Abstract This appendix provides additional details and results to support the main

More information

Equilibrium parallel import policies and international market structure

Equilibrium parallel import policies and international market structure Equilibrium parallel import policies and international market structure Santanu Roy y and Kamal Saggi z Department of Economics Southern Methodist University Dallas, TX 75275-0496 First version: October

More information

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice Patrick Rey Toulouse School of Economics based on joint work with Zhijun Chen (University of Auckland and Ecole Polytechnique) Bergen, September 2011 atrick Rey

More information

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets Hend Ghazzai Assistant Professor College of Business and Economics Qatar University P.O. Box 2713 Doha, Qatar. Abstract Consumers' choice

More information

Multiproduct rms, nonlinear pricing and price discrimination Lecture notes

Multiproduct rms, nonlinear pricing and price discrimination Lecture notes Multiproduct rms, nonlinear pricing and price discrimination Lecture notes Estelle Cantillon November 29, 2007 1 Introduction In many industries, rms produce several products. This raises a new set of

More information

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed

More information

A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation

A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation Igal Hendel Aviv Nevo Northwestern University December 14, 2009 Hendel & Nevo (Northwestern University) A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation December 14, 2009 1 /

More information

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition Strategic Competition: An overview The economics of industry studying activities within an industry. Basic concepts from game theory Competition in the short run Best-response functions, best-response

More information

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model Subject Paper No and Title Module No and Title Module Tag 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model ECO_P3_M28 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Learning Outcomes 2. Introduction

More information

INTENSITY OF COMPETITION AND THE CHOICE BETWEEN PRODUCT AND PROCESS INNOVATION *

INTENSITY OF COMPETITION AND THE CHOICE BETWEEN PRODUCT AND PROCESS INNOVATION * Forthcoming in the International Journal of Industrial Organization INTENSITY OF COMPETITION AND TE COICE ETWEEN PRODUCT AND PROCESS INNOVATION * Giacomo onanno Department of Economics, University of California,

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market Richard J. Gilbert University of California Michael H. Riordan Columbia University CPDP-17-E October 2005 This article is written

More information

Estimating Dynamic R&D Choice: An Analysis of Costs and Long-Run Bene ts

Estimating Dynamic R&D Choice: An Analysis of Costs and Long-Run Bene ts Estimating Dynamic R&D Choice: An Analysis of Costs and Long-Run Bene ts Bettina Peters Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) Mark J. Roberts Pennyslvania State University and NBER Van Anh Vuong

More information

BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS.

BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS. WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No.01/12 TOMMY STAAHL GABRIELSEN AND BJØRN OLAV JOHANSEN BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS. Department of Economics U N I V E R S I T Y OF B E R G EN Buyer

More information

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework ARNAUD CHÉRON (GAINS-TEPP, UNIVERSITY OF LE MANS) Attribution Non commercial - No Derivative Work : http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.0/fr/

More information

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Akira Nishimori Aichi University Hikaru Ogawa Nagoya University Abstract We analyze the capacity choice of firms in a long run mixed oligopoly market, in which firms

More information

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22 Monopoly. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen November, Lecture Monopoly Outline. Chap : Monopoly. Chap : Shift in Demand and Effect of Tax Monopoly The monopolist is the single supply-side

More information

Spatial Development. Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos III and. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE.

Spatial Development. Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos III and. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. Spatial Development Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos III and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE April, 9 Abstract We present a theory of spatial development. A continuum

More information

The Economics of the Long Tail

The Economics of the Long Tail The Economics of the Long Tail Todd D. Kendall and Kevin K. Tsui Compass Lexecon and Clemson University October 20, 2008 Abstract Anderson (2006) argues that e-commerce and other new technologies improve

More information

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE MS # 1949 OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE Tsuyoshi TOSHIMITSU * Kwansei Gakuin University Final version March 2003 Abstract In a quality-differentiated duopoly where (i) quality is endogenously

More information

Monopolistic competition, endogenous markups, and growth

Monopolistic competition, endogenous markups, and growth ELSEVIER European Economic Review 38 (1994) 748-756 EUROPEAN ECONOMIC REVIEW Monopolistic competition, endogenous markups, and growth Jordi Gali Gruduute School of Business, Columbia University, 607 Uris

More information

R&D Investment and Export Dynamics

R&D Investment and Export Dynamics R&D Investment and Export Dynamics Bee Yan Aw The Pennsylvania State University Mark J.Roberts The Pennsylvania State University and NBER September 11, 2008 Daniel Yi Xu New York University Abstract A

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly Outline Barriers to Entry Profit Maximization under Monopoly Welfare Loss of Monopoly Multiplant Monopolist Price Discrimination Advertising in Monopoly

More information

Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness

Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness James A. Brander and Barbara J. Spencer Sauder School of Business University

More information

Analyzing Modes of Foreign Entry: Greenfield Investment versus Acquisition

Analyzing Modes of Foreign Entry: Greenfield Investment versus Acquisition Analyzing Modes of Foreign Entry: Greenfield Investment versus Acquisition Thomas Müller Discussion paper 2001-01 January 2001 Department of Economics, University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät

More information

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics Bee Yan Aw The Pennsylvania State University Mark J. Roberts The Pennsylvania State University and NBER March 2010 Daniel Yi Xu New York University

More information

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition Learning Objectives: Students should learn to:. The student will understand the ideas of strategic interdependence and reasoning strategically and be able

More information

"Nouvelle Loi de l Organisation du Marche de l électricité": Implications for the French Retail Market

Nouvelle Loi de l Organisation du Marche de l électricité: Implications for the French Retail Market "Nouvelle Loi de l Organisation du Marche de l électricité": Implications for the French Retail Market Anna Creti 1 J erôme Pouyet 2 Maria Eugenia Sanin 3 1 U. Paris Ouest, Ecole Polytechnique 2 PSE and

More information

Trading Tasks and Quality

Trading Tasks and Quality Trading Tasks and Quality F. Banu Demir November 30, 2011 Job Market Paper Abstract I present a trade model featuring North-South di erences in demand for quality and in quality of task supply. The model

More information

Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER16 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Describe and identify monopolistic competition. 2 Explain how

More information

International Outsourcing and Intra-Industrial Trade

International Outsourcing and Intra-Industrial Trade Lo, International Journal of Applied Economics, 2(2), September 2005, 69-82 69 International Outsourcing and Intra-Industrial Trade Chu Ping Lo National Cheng Kung University Krugman (979) demonstrated

More information

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, 10 12 September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne Institutional quality and contract complexity: the effects on the intensive and extensive margins of trade

More information

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1 Abstract. Revenue management (RM) is the art and science of predicting consumer behavior and optimizing price and product availability to maximize

More information

Entry and competition in differentiated products markets. Catherine SCHAUMANS & Frank VERBOVEN

Entry and competition in differentiated products markets. Catherine SCHAUMANS & Frank VERBOVEN Entry and competition in differentiated products markets by Catherine SCHAUMANS & Frank VERBOVEN Econometrics Center for Economic Studies Discussions Paper Series (DPS) 11.23 http://www.econ.kuleuven.be/ces/discussionpapers/default.htm

More information

Wage Compression, Learning, and Self-Employment

Wage Compression, Learning, and Self-Employment Wage Compression, Learning, and Self-Employment Nikolaj Malchow-Møller Centre for Economic and Business Research (CEBR), and University of Southern Denmark James R. Markusen University of Colorado, Boulder,

More information

Solutions to Final Exam

Solutions to Final Exam Solutions to Final Exam AEC 504 - Summer 2007 Fundamentals of Economics c 2007 Alexander Barinov 1 Veni, vidi, vici (30 points) Two firms with constant marginal costs serve two markets for two different

More information

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility

Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Price Discrimination through Corporate Social Responsibility Suman Ghosh Kameshwari Shankar Abstract A common form of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) by firmsistoagreetodonatea fixed portion of private

More information

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search Maarten Janssen and Sandro Shelegia March 30, 2014 Abstract We analyze how the market power of firms in consumer search markets depends on how consumers form beliefs

More information

Creative Destruction and Unemployment in an Open Economy Model. by Ignat Stepanok

Creative Destruction and Unemployment in an Open Economy Model. by Ignat Stepanok Creative Destruction and Unemployment in an Open Economy Model by Ignat Stepanok No. 820 November 203 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Hindenburgufer 66, 2405 Kiel, Germany Kiel Working Paper No.

More information

EconS Third-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS Third-Degree Price Discrimination EconS 425 - Third-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41 Introduction

More information

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center

Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Journal of Logistics Management 017, 6(): 35-40 DOI: 10.593/j.logistics.017060.01 Marketing Strategy of Rent and Space Allocation for Dominant Retailer in Shopping Center Aika Monden Graduate School of

More information

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim Industrial Organization Markets and Strategies 2nd edition Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain Martin Peitz University of Mannheim CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents List offigures xiii

More information

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley 1 Overview of the Course This is a readings course. The lectures

More information

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Lisa Planer-Friedrich and Marco Sahm Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility Lisa Planer-Friedrich University of Bamberg Marco Sahm University of Bamberg and

More information

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit Modern Economy, 07, 8, 99-0 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 5-76 ISSN Print: 5-745 The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit Feifei Zheng

More information

No Wolfgang Briglauer, Georg Götz, and Anton Schwarz. Margin Squeeze in Fixed-Network Telephony Markets competitive or anticompetitive?

No Wolfgang Briglauer, Georg Götz, and Anton Schwarz. Margin Squeeze in Fixed-Network Telephony Markets competitive or anticompetitive? MAGKS Aachen Siegen Marburg Gießen Göttingen Kassel Joint Discussion Paper Series in Economics by the Universities of Aachen Gießen Göttingen Kassel Marburg Siegen ISSN 1867-3678 No. 27-2008 Wolfgang Briglauer,

More information

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited

Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Intra-industry trade, environmental policies and innovations: The Porter- Hypothesis revisited Gerhard Clemenz March 2012 Abstract: According to the Porter Hypothesis (PH) stricter environmental regulations

More information

Developing a Model. This chapter illustrates how a simulation model is developed for a business C H A P T E R 5

Developing a Model. This chapter illustrates how a simulation model is developed for a business C H A P T E R 5 C H A P T E R 5 Developing a Model This chapter illustrates how a simulation model is developed for a business process. Speci± cally, we develop and investigate a model for a simple productiondistribution

More information

Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Selection

Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Selection Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Selection By ANTONELLA NOCCO, GIANMARCO I.P. OTTAVIANO AND MATTEO SALTO Since the initial contribution by Melitz (23) monopolistically competitive models with

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Markets and Strategies 2nd edition Paul Belleflamme Université CatholiquedeLouvain Martin Peitz University of Mannheim University Printing House, Cambridge CB2 8BS, United Kingdom

More information

Market Segmentation With Nonlinear Pricing

Market Segmentation With Nonlinear Pricing Market Segmentation With Nonlinear Pricing Silvia Sonderegger Abstract This paper studies the e ect of captive consumers in a competitive model of nonlinear pricing. We focus on the bene ts and drawbacks

More information

The Macro-Economics of Superstars

The Macro-Economics of Superstars The Macro-Economics of Superstars Anton Korinek and Ding Xuan Ng Johns Hopkins University and NBER 5th IMF Statistical Forum, November 2017 Introduction Rosen (1981) rst described the Economics of Superstars:

More information

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3 1.5 Theory of the firm and its market structures - Monopoly Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3 Main idea 1 Monopoly: - Only one firm producing the product (Firm = industry) - Barriers to entry or exit exists,

More information

Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation

Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation Published as: Aghion, Philippe, Peter Howitt, and Susanne Prantl. 2013. Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation. In Advances in Economics and Econometrics (Tenth World

More information

Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation

Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation A. Banerji Delhi School of Economics, University of Delhi, Delhi 110007, India, (a.banerji@econdse.org) and Bhaskar Dutta Department of Economics,

More information